Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T06:43:24.744Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Creative accounting in the age of Philip II? Determining the ‘just’ rate of interest

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 February 2009

John A. Marino
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego

Abstract

Deficit financing, revenue projections and interest rates in Spanish Naples provide the context to reflect upon the exigencies of debt resolution, the illusions of mathematical certainty and the perils of temporizing in political decision-making. ‘Creative accounting’ explores the micro-history of an equation, which provided the mathematical rationale to lower Spanish interest rates to 3·3 per cent and to resolve the controversy over the ‘just’ rate of interest. In an attempt to generate revenues during the Spanish financial crisis of the 1570s that surrounded Philip II's second bankruptcy in Castile, Philip's Castilian accountants devised a proposal to suspend the hearth census in the Kingdom of Naples for fifteen years in exchange for a prepayment at discount. An analysis of the mathematics of the discount schedule raises questions about early modern economic realities. Changes in the significance of figures and quantitative relationships, like changes in the meaning of words, reveal the mental processes used to represent economic fact and to construct solutions to economic difficulties even in the midst of crises.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

* Earlier versions of this paper were delivered in 1986 at the Newberry Library and the American Historical Association meeting. My thanks to James Sandos for brainstorming through an early formulation of the problem. The advice and criticism of colleagues in economics and mathematics - Richard Carson, Carlo M. Cipolla, Alfred Manaster and David Weir – have saved me from making the same errors as the Castilian accountants. Suggestions from Michael Bernstein, Jack Greenstein, David Luft and Robert Westman have helped refine my arguments.

1 Miskimin, Harry A., The economy of early renaissance Europe, 1300–1460 (Cambridge, 1975), pp. 150–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Lovett, A. W., ‘The Castilian bankruptcy of 1575’, Historical Journal, XXIII, 4 (1980), 899911CrossRefGoogle Scholar and his Philip II and Mateo Vázquez de Leca: the government of Spain (1572–1592) (Geneva, 1977), pp. 59105Google Scholar. The standard reference work is Ulloa, Modesto, La hacienda real de Castila en el reinado de Felipe II (2nd edn, Madrid, 1977)Google Scholar. For an overview and bibliography of sixteenth-century Spain, Lovett, A. W., Early Habsburg Spain 1517–1598 (Oxford, 1986), esp. ch. 15Google Scholar, ‘The financial system of the Habsburg empire’.

3 Bernstein, Michael A., ‘Numerable knowledge and its discontents’, Reviews in American History, XVII (1990), 151–64CrossRefGoogle Scholar explores the ambiguities of numerical certainty in the social sciences in terms of establishing the operative assumptions for data collection and emphasizes the necessity of applying the social matrix which informs interpretation.

4 On Spanish economic history, Mackay, Angus, ‘Recent literature on Spanish economic history’, Economic History Review, XXXI, 1 (1978), 129–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Phillips, Carla Rahn, ‘Time and duration: a model for the economy of early modern Spain’, American History Review, XCII, 3 (06 1987), 531–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For comparative perspective on debts, resources and war over the long term of modern European history, see Kennedy, Paul, The rise and fall of the Great Powers. Economic change and military conflict from 1500 to 2000 (New York, 1987)Google Scholar.

5 Calabria, Antonio, The cost of empire. The finances of the Kingdom of Naples in the time of Spanish rule (Cambridge, 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Galasso, Giuseppe, ‘Momenti e problemi di storia napoletana nell'età di Carlo V’, in Mezzogiorno medievale e moderno (Turin, 1965), p. 178Google Scholar, now translated in Calabria, Antonio and Marino, John A., Good government in Spanish Naples (New York/Bern, 1990), p. 56Google Scholar.

7 Calabria, , Cost of empire, pp. 5667Google Scholar.

8 Zotta, Silvio, ‘Momenti e problemi di una crisi agraria in uno “stato” feudale napoletano (1585–1615)’, Mélanges de l'École Française de Rome, XC, 2 (1978), 715–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar, now translated in Calabria, and Marino, , Good government, pp. 127203Google Scholar. For the murder of the grain-provisioning officer Starace in Naples in 1585, see Villari, Rosario, La Rivolta antispagnolo a Napoli. I origini (1585–1647) (Bari, 1967), pp. 4252Google Scholar, with the episode translated in Cochrane, Eric, Late Renaissance Italy (New York, 1970), pp. 303–30Google Scholar.

9 Coniglio, Giuseppe, Aspetti della società meridionale nel secolo XVI (Naples, 1978), pp. 265–75Google Scholar.

10 Mira, Giuseppe, ‘Contributo per una storia dei prezzi in alcune provincie delle Puglie’, in Atti della IV e V riunione scientifica della Società Italiana di Statistica (Rome, 1942), pp. 168–9Google Scholar gives decade median prices for wheat at Bari for the 1550s at 41·3 grams of silver per quintal, the 1560s at 43·7, the 1570s at 48·4, the 1580s increasing to 59·8, the 1590s jumping to 90·1, and the 1600s slightly declining to 88·8.

11 Burke, Peter, ‘Southern Italy in the 1590s: hard times or crisis?’, in The European crisis of the 1590s. Essays in comparative history, ed. Clark, Peter (London, 1985), pp. 177208Google Scholar.

12 Calabria, , Cost of empire, pp. 5963Google Scholar.

13 Ibid. pp. 83–6.

14 Ibid. pp. 87–8 documents naval and military demobilization after Lepanto. See Aymard, Maurice, ‘Chiourmes et galères dans la Méditerranèe du XVIe siècle’, in Mélanges en l'honneur de Fernand Braudel. Histoire économique du monde méditerranéen 1450–1650 (Toulouse, 1973), pp. 4964Google Scholar and for information on the state of the Neapolitan galleys from 1574, Archive General de Simancas [AGS], Visitas d'Italia, leg. 71, 72, 74.

15 Muto, Giovanni, ‘La economía del Mezzogiorno continental de la segunda mitad del Cinquecento a la crisis de los años cuarenta del siglo XVII’, Cuadernos de investigacíon histórica, I (1977), pp. 191213, reviews the bibliographyGoogle Scholar.

16 AGS, Estado, Nápoles, leg. 1079, f. 32 (11 ii 1579), transcribed in Goniglio, Giuseppe, II Viceregno di Napoli e la lotta tra spagnoli e turchi nel Mediterraneo, 2 vols. (Naples, 1987), II, 552–4Google Scholar.

17 Lovett, A. W., ‘Juan de Ovando and the Council of Finance (1573–1575)’, Historical Journal, XV, 1 (1972), 8Google Scholar.

18 Biblioteca Nazionale, Napoli [BNN], MS XV.B.11, ‘Lettere Regie’, cc. 293–294 (24 vi 1573).

19 On the theory and practice of hearth tax injustices, Calabria, Antonio, Cost of empire, pp. 3940Google Scholar with a fuller account in Calabria, Antonio, ‘State finance in the Kingdom of Naples in the age of Philip II’ (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Berkeley, 1977), p. 40Google Scholar. On the question of frauds in early modern public life, see Waquet, Jean-Claude, De la corruption. Morale et pouvoir à Florence aux XVIIe et XVIIIe siècles (Paris, 1984)Google Scholar.

20 Parker, Geoffrey, Philip II (Boston–Toronto, 1978), p. 58Google Scholar remarks upon biographers' anecdotes emphasizing the ‘king's anxiety not to wrong anyone’ and his legendary devotion to fairness and justice popularized after his death. , Lovett, Early Habsburg Spain, p. 121Google Scholar demonstrates this ‘commendable’ quality by citing an attributed quotation: ‘Law courts should not be like spider's webs which [catch] the fly while allowing the lizard to pass through’.

21 AGS, Estado, Ndpoles, leg. 1066, f. 88 and f. 89 (1575).

22 See , Lovett, ‘Juan de Ovando’, pp. 1314Google Scholar for details on the personnel in the finance ministry.

23 BNN, MS Branc. V.B.5, ‘Parlamenti e gratie della Città di Napoli’, cc. 190r–113r (22 iv '575)

24 Ibid. pp. 8–17 summarizes two important reform documents prepared by Ovando for Phillip II: ‘an enormous relatíon’ dated 16 January 1574, and the ‘great memorial on the state of royal finance’ dated 11 April 1574.

25 , Calabria, Cost of empire, p. 78Google Scholar gives actual expenses for conducting the delayed census in 1595 as 120,000 ducats.

26 See n. 23. On the Neapolitan parliament, D'Agostino, Guido, Parlamento e società nel Regno di Napoli (Naples, 1979)Google Scholar.

27 Lovett, Albert, ‘The general settlement of 1577: an aspect of Spanish finance in the early modern period’, Historical Journal, XXV, 1 (1982), 122CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 Bianchini, Ludovico, Storia delle finanze delle due Sicilie (3rd edn, 1859; ed. De Rosa, Luigi, Naples, 1971), p. 252Google Scholar.

29 AGS, Estado, Nápoles, leg. 1079, f. 32 (11 ii 1579). This consulta describes the Neapolitan state budget of 1575: ‘said balance of the referred to year remain to be paid by merchants, and the money is consigned to them above and beyond the donativo of 1575’.

30 AGS, Estado, Nápoles, leg. 1066, f. 98 (8 xi 1575).

31 BNN, MS XV.B.11, c. 367 (18 xi 1575).

32 , Lovett, ‘Juan de Ovando’, p. 13Google Scholar.

33 AGS, Estado, Nápoles, leg. 1072, f. 145 (1576), transcribed, but misdated, in , Coniglio, Il Viceregno, II, 519–21Google Scholar.

34 BNN, MS XV.B.II, c. 374 (24 iii 1576).

35 Marino, John A., Pastoral economics in the Kingdom of Naples (Baltimore, 1988), p. 311, n. 79Google Scholar.

36 Martín, Felipe Ruiz, ‘Un expediente financiero entre 1560 y 1575. La Hacienda de Fellip II y la Casa de la Contratación de Sevilla’, Moneda y Crédito, XCII (1965): 358Google Scholar explains the innovation of guaranteeing American treasure shipments as collateral from about 1552.

37 Villani, Pasquale, Numerazioni dei fuochi e problemi demografici del Mezzogiomo in età modera (Naples, 1973)Google Scholar.

38 Beloch, Karl J., Bevölkerungsgeschichte Italiens (3 vols., Berlin, 1937, 1961), III, 215Google Scholar.

39 AGS, Visitas d'Italia, Nápoles, leg. 23:3, cc. 61v–62V.

40 Braudel, Fernand, The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean world in the age of Philip II, trans. Reynolds, Siâ;n (New York, 1972), I, 584–5Google Scholar cites Bibliothèque Nationale, Paris, MS Esp. 127, fo. 52.

41 Ruiz Marín, pp. 6–7, 13–14 gives interest rates of 12–15 per cent between 1525 and 1530, 7–12 per cent between 1535 and 1540, 10–13 per cent between 1528 and 1548, 43 per cent in 1554; and for juros, rates of 6·25 per cent between 1545 and 1550, 6·09 per cent in 1552, 6·78 per cent in 1560, 5·81 per cent in 1594, and 5·79 per cent in 1598.

42 , Calabria, ‘State finances’, pp. 197–9, 299–300Google Scholar. The mode rate in four sample years was 10 per cent in 1560, 9 per cent in 1574, 8 per cent in 1583, and 7 per cent in 1600.

43 From the inflation information in note 9, nominal interest rates in Naples would have been about 9 per cent in the 1560s, 7 per cent in the 1570s, 4 per cent in the 1580s, and just below zero by 1600 – albeit prices would still have remained at the high levels of the 1590s.

44 Cipolla, Carlo M., ‘Note sulla storia del saggio d'interesse. Corso, dividendi e sconto dei dividendi del banco di S. Giorgio nel sec. XVI’, Economia Internationale, V, 1 (1952), 255–74Google Scholar.

45 , Calabria, Cost of empire, p. 106Google Scholar cites Tracy, James D., A financial revolution in the Habsburg Netherlands. Renten and Renteniers in the county of Holland, 1515–1565 (Berkeley, 1985), pp. 60, 92, 207Google Scholar.

46 , Lovett, ‘The Castilian bankruptcy’, pp. 904–5Google Scholar. de Roover, Raymond, ‘Monopoly theory prior to Adam Smith: a revision’, in Business, banking, and economic thought in late medieval and early modern Europe, ed. Kirshner, Julius (Chicago, 1974), pp. 273305, esp. 277–8Google Scholar, traces the long-enduring scholastic understanding of the ‘just price’. The ‘just price’ was either the legal (fixed) price set by public authorities or the market (competitive) price agreed upon through the ‘common estimation’ of buyers and sellers who were sensitive to ‘the interplay of the forces of demand and supply’. See also de Roover's, classic article, ‘The concept of the just price: theory and economic policy’, Journal of Economic History, XVIII (1958), 418–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47 , Lovett, ‘The general settlement’, p. 19Google Scholar.

48 Trenchant, Jean, L'Arithmetique, departie en trois livres (3rd edn, Lyons, 1571), pp. 292311Google Scholar defines and demonstrates merite simple and merite à chef de terme, and disconte simple and disconte à chef de terme.

49 Smith, D. E., History of mathematics (2 vols., New York, 1958), II, 565–6Google Scholar. On Trenchant, see Davis, Natalie Zemon, ‘Sixteenth-century French arithmetics on the business life’, Journal of the History of Ideas, XXI, (0103 1960), 37Google Scholar. On the teaching of business math, see Swetz, Frank J., Capitalism and arithmetic. The new math of the 15th century (La Salle, Ill., 1987)Google Scholar and Grendler, Paul F., Schooling in Renaissance Italy: literacy and leaning, 1300–1600 (Baltimore, 1989)Google Scholar.

50 For a similar inversion from contemporary economic notation in Naples, see the language employed in the ‘free-bidding’ of pasture (the system used to replace the direct numeration of sheep) in the Foggian sheep customhouse. See, Marino, John A., ‘Professazione voluntaria e pecore in aerea: ragione economica e meccanismi di mercato nella dogana di Foggia nel secolo sedicesimo’, Rivista Storica Italiana, XCIV, 1 (1982), 30–2Google Scholar: ‘In our contemporary market language, price quotations are expressed in changing monetary values while the quantity of the commodity remains constant. We sell land, for example, for an amount of money per acre because “selling price” (we don't call it “buying price”) is expressed in seller, not buyer notation. Doganal logic operated inversely. It was a system based upon a buyer's budget. Because of the inelasticity of the sheepowner's profit margin, the monetary value (1000 sheep at 132 ducats) remained constant and the commodity (10 to 14 carra of pasture) fluctuated. The principles of economic reasoning are not overturned in the least. But such a different verbalization of the processes of economic thought reflected the official relationship between shepherd buyers and state middlemen in the establishment of a fixed price for fodder expenditures.’

51 Febvre, Lucien, Le problème de l'incroyance au XVIe siècle. La religion de Rabelais (Paris, 1942)Google Scholar. For a recent review, Wootton, David, ‘Lucien Febvre and the problem of unbelief in the early modern period’, Journal of Modern History, LX, 4 (12 1988), 695730CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

52 Cipolla, Carlo M., Before the Industrial Revolution. European society and economy, 1000–1700 (2nd edn, New York, 1980)Google Scholar.

53 Wilcox, Donald J., The measure of times past: pre-Newtonian chronologies and the rhetoric of relative time (Chicago, 1987), pp. 222–3Google Scholar summarizes his distinction between relative and absolute time, which is roughly analogous to the distinctions I see between the sixteenth-century accountants' simple discount and the modern compound discount equation.

54 , Lovett, ‘Juan de Ovando’, p. 7, n. 31Google Scholar cites Instituto Valencia de Don Juan, Madrid [IVDJ], Envío 53, fo. 97 (12-ix-1574).

55 , Lovett, Philip II and Mateo Vázquez de Leca, p. 89Google Scholar for information on factional rivalries and an opinion on the financial manipulations of Auñon and Garnica by Juan Fernández de Espinosa, a rival in the Spanish financial councils: ‘I think that Auñon uses Garnica…and that the former has the same intention of confounding and obscuring all items of business’.

56 During the second half of the sixteenth century, neo-Thomistic moral theologians grappled with these problems. See, Schumpeter, Joseph A., History of economic analysis, ed. Schumpeter, Elizabeth Boody (New York, 1954), pp. 103–7 and 327–9Google Scholar. See also, Grice-Hutchinson, Marjorie, The School of Salamanca. Readings in Spanish monetary theory, 1544–1601) (Oxford, 1952)Google Scholar and Early economic thought in Spain, 1177–1740 (London, 1978)Google Scholar.

57 In a similar discussion over royal defaults in the seventeenth century, Elliott, J. H., The Count-Duke of Olivares (New Haven, 1986), p. 77Google Scholar cites a 1621 argument that ‘for the Crown to tamper with interest rates was to default on its moral obligation’.

58 , Lovett, Philip II and Mateo Vázquez de Leca, p. 66, n. 35Google Scholar cites, IVDJ, Envío 51, fo. 32 (1574).

59 , Lovett, ‘The general settlement’, pp. 36Google Scholar.

60 Braudel, Fernand, Civilization and capitalism, 15th–18th century, Vol III, The perspective of the world, trans. Reynolds, Siân (New York, 1984), p. 168Google Scholar.

61 , Lovett, ‘Juan de Ovando’, p. 12Google Scholar. See also, , Calabria, Cost of empire, App. II, pp. 5669Google Scholar discusses an accounting dispute between Naples and Madrid over state budgets in the 1590s, which clearly demonstrates Neapolitan sophistication over their Spanish auditors.

62 Trenchant, pp. 299–300 gives the example of a 1555 loan of Henry III at compound interest in favour of the merchants, ‘4 per cent per fair, i.e., 16 per cent per year.’

63 For an examination of the power of rhetoric in economics, McCloskey, Donald, The rhetoric of economics (Madison, Wis., 1985)Google Scholar.

64 , Marino, ‘Professazione voluntaria e Pecore in aerea’, pp. 543Google Scholar.

65 AGS, Visitas d'Italia, Náoles. leg. 23:3, cc. 285r–289V.

66 , Lovett, ‘The Castilian bankruptcy’, p. 911Google Scholar summarizes the debate.

67 Elliott, J. H., Spain and its world, 1500–1700: selected essays (New Haven, 1989)Google Scholar.