Published online by Cambridge University Press: 16 December 2008
When nineteenth-century liberals searched for reasons not to enfranchise the lower orders, they most often hit upon the argument that, once given the vote, workers would use it to elect governments pledged to redistribution and welfare at the expense of property. A cursory look at the political history of the twentieth century suggests they were not entirely deluded. Indeed, the most salient facts about political development since 1900 surely are related: The democratization of the political system allowed for the emergence of the working class as a distinct claimant to political power, and its presence within the polity somehow or another stimulated the enormous extension of the social and economic role of the state.
1. See Stephens, John, The Transition from Capitalism to Socialism (London, 1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Shalev, Michael, “The Social Democratic Model and Beyond: Two Generations of Comparative Research on the Welfare State”, Comparative Social Research 6 (1983):315–51Google Scholar; Esping-Anderson, Gosta, Politics Against Markets (Princeton, 1985)Google Scholar; and, for a more critical stance, Baldwin, Peter, “The Politics of Social Solidarity and the Bourgeois Origins of the European Welfare State, 1875–1975” (Ph.D diss., Harvard University, 1987).Google Scholar
2. See, among others, Weir, Margaret, Orloff, Ann, and Skocpol, Theda, eds,, The Politics of Social Policy in the United States (Princeton, 1988)Google Scholar and Pampel, Fred and Williamson, John, “Explaining Social Welfare Spending in Advanced Industrial Democracies, 1950–1980”, American Journal of Sociology 93 (1988):1424–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
3. Pelling, Henry, “The Working Class and the Welfare State”, in Popular Politics and Society in Victorian Britain (London, 1968) represents the beginning of the debate.Google Scholar For more current views, see Thane, Pat, “The Working Class and State ‘Welfare’in Britain”, Historical Journal 32(1984)Google Scholar and idem“The Labour Party and State ‘Welfare’”, in The First Labour Party, 1906–1914, ed. Brown, K. D., London, 1985).Google Scholar
4. There is a substantial literature on both issues. See Brown, K. D., Labour and Unemployment, 1900–1914 (Newton Abbot, 1971)Google Scholar; Harris, José, Unemployment and Politics: A Study in English Social Policy, 1886–4914 (Oxford, 1972)Google Scholar; Gilbert, Bentley B., The Evolution of National Insurance in Great Britain (London, 1966)Google Scholar; Thane, Pat, “Contributory versus Non-Contributory Old Age Pensions, 1978–1908”, in The Origins of British Social Policy, ed. Thane, Pat (London, 1978).Google Scholar
5. The quotation comes from Reynolds, S. et al. , Seems So! A Working Class View of Politics (London, 1911), quoted in Thane, “The Working Class and State ‘Welfare’”, 894.Google Scholar
6. Davin, Anna, “Imperialism and Motherhood”, History Workshop 5 (Spring 1978):9–65.Google Scholar
7. This Section is based largely on an unpublished paper by Pat Thane on Labour and local government before World War I.
8. MacDonald, J. Ramsay, Socialism (London, 1907), 123Google Scholar, cited in ibid.; Wald, Kenneth, “Advance by Retreat? The Formation of British Labour's Electoral Strategy”, Journal of British Studies 27 (July, 1988): 283–314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
9. MacDonald, J. Ramsay, May 29, 1911, quoted in Thane, “The Labour Party and State ‘Welfare’”, 186.Google Scholar
10. Hollis, Patricia, Ladies Elect: Women in English Local Government, 1865–1914 (Oxford, 1987)Google Scholar: Harrison, Brian, “Class and Gender in Modern British Labour History”, Past and Present 124 (08 1989): 128, 131–32Google Scholar; Holton, Sandra S., Feminism and Democracy: Women's Suffrage and Reform Politics in Britain, 1900–1918 (Cambridge, 1986).Google Scholar
11. Gilbert, Evolution of National Insurance, 314.
12. Cronin, James E., “The British State and the Structure of Political Opportunity”, Journal of British Studies 27:3 (1988):199–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
13. MacDonald, J. Ramsay, A Policy for the Labour Party (London, 1920), 87.Google Scholar
14. Commission of Enquiry into Industrial Unrest, Summary of the Reports, Cmnd. 8696, Parliamentary Papers (1917–18), 15.Google Scholar
15. Reid, Alastair, “Dilution, Trade Unionism and the State in Britain during the First World War”, in Shop-Floor Bargaining and the State, ed. Tolliday, S. and Zeitlin, J., (Cambridge, 1985), 46–74.Google Scholar
16. See Bush, Julia, Behind the Lines: East London Labour, 1914–1919 (London, 1984)Google Scholar; Schneer, Jonathan, “The War, the State and the Workplace: British Dockers during 1914–1918”, in Social Conflict and the Political Order in Modern Britain, ed. Cronin, J. and Schneer, J. (New Brunswick, 1982), 101.Google Scholar
17. Bain, G. S. and Price, R., Profiles of Union Growth (Oxford, 1980), 37–38.Google Scholar The war also brought tangible gains in terms of working-class living standards and mortality rates. See Winter, J. M., The Great War and the British People (Cambridge, 1986).Google Scholar
18. Bevin, Ernest, “The Reconstruction of Industry”, The Athenaeum, May 1917, 227–30. and Bevin's remarks in the Record, March 1936, 172.Google Scholar
19. See McKibbin, Ross, The Evolution of the Labour Party, 1910–1924 (Oxford, 1974)Google Scholar; Winter, J. M., Socialism and the Challenge of War (London, 1974)Google Scholar; Harrison, Royden, “The War Emergency Workers' National Committee, 1914–1920”, in Essays in Labour History, 1886–1923, ed. Briggs, A. and Saville, J. (London, 1971), 211–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Beer, Samuel, British Politics in the Collectivist Age, 2d ed. (New York, 1969)Google Scholar; Wolfe, Joel, Workers, Participation and Democracy: Internal Politics in the British Union Movement (London, 1985)Google Scholar; and Waites, Bernard, A Class Society at War: England, 1914–1918 (Leamington Spa, 1987).Google Scholar
20. Whiteside, Noel, “Concession, Coercion or Cooperation? State Policy and Industrial Unrest in Britain, 1916–20”, Annali (forthcoming, 1992); and “Welfare Legislation and the Unions during the First World War”, Historical Journal 23 1980): 857–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
21. MacDonald, , A Policy for the Labour Party, chapters 6–8.Google Scholar
22. Ministry of Reconstruction, Report of the Machinery of Government Committee, Cmnd. 9230, Parliamentary Papers (1918), 12.Google Scholar
23. In many ways, they encouraged the antiwaste mentality. MacDonald, for example. argued in 1920 that the control of expenditure might well give a Labour chancellor real difficulties and that “he may have cause to regret that his immediate predecessors have departed from the sound maxim that the Chancellor of the Exchequer is a financial watchdog of other Departments. His first business to-day would be to cut down Whitehall expenditure and to lop off many of the tentacles which it has thrust out over the country”. See MacDonald, A Policy for the Labour Party, 156.
24. Whiteside, Noel, “Social Welfare and Industrial Relations, 1914–1939”, in A History of British Industrial Relations, Vol. II: 1914–1939, ed. Wrigley, Chris (Brighton, 1987), 219.Google Scholar
25. Labour Party Annual Conference, Report, 1925, 100. The Board would be allocated £10,000,000 annually with which to build up a reserve fund for public works in a depression. The scheme resembled Lloyd George's prewar plan for a Development Commission. On this, see Harris, J., Unemployment and Politics: A Study in English Social Policy, 1886–1914 (Oxford, 1972), 340–6, 357–9.Google Scholar
26. Ryan, P. A., “Poplarism, 1894–1930”, in The Origins of British Social Policy, ed. Thane, Pat (London, 1978), 70–80.Google Scholar
27. Labour Party Annual Conference, Report, 1925, 102. 244ff. The resolution was defeted by 2,587,000 to 512,000 votes.
28. Clay, Harold, “The Industrial Upheaval: Its Effects and Lessons”, Conference of General Officers, February 19–21, 1927, Bevin Papers, Warwick University, Mss/126/EB/TG/6/18.Google Scholar
29. Citrine, Walter, Men and Work: An Autobiography (London, 1964), 238.Google Scholar
30. “Currency and banking policy pursued by the Treasury and the Bank of England ought in future to be framed in such a way that the special interests of industry are safeguarded and furthered”, the conference concluded.
31. See the Parliamentary report in Labour Party Annual Conference, Report. 1922, 6–8; and, on family allowances, see Land, Hilary, “The Introduction of Family Allowances”, in Change, Choice and Conflict in Social Policy, ed. Hall, Phoebe et al. , (London, 1975), 157–230Google Scholar; Macnicol, John, The Movement for Family Allowances, 1918–1945: A Study in Social Policy Development (London, 1980)Google Scholar: and Pedersen, Susan, “The Failure of Feminism in the Making of the British Welfare State”, Radical History Review 43 (Winter 1989):86–110.Google Scholar
32. Mosley, Oswald, Revolution by Reason (London, 1925)Google Scholar; Brailsford, H. N. et al. , The Living Wage (London, 1926)Google Scholar; “Labour's Appeal to the Nation” (1929). in British General Election Manifesros, 1900–1974, ed. Craig, F. W. S. (London, 1975), 82.Google Scholar
33. Britain's Industrial Future, being the Report of the Liberal Industrial Inquiry (London, 1928)Google Scholar; We Can Conquer Unemployment: Mr. Lloyd George's Pledge (London, 1929).Google Scholar For a critical discussion of the strengths and weaknesses of Lloyd George's plans. see Pack, Booth. Employment, Capital and Economic Policy. 35–54.Google Scholar
34. The Treasury's desire to keep the Economic Advisory Committee from becoming a serious rival to the Treasury in the provision of economic counsel is revealed in the discussions surrounding its establishment in CAB58/15, especially Warren Fisher's memo, “Economic General Staff”, December 3, 1929. See also the discussion in Howson, Susan and Winch, Donald, The Economic Advisory Council, 1930–1939 (Cambridge, 1977), 17–29.CrossRefGoogle ScholarThe Treasury's response to the proposals of Mosley and the EAC is discussed in Skidelsky, R., Politicians and the Slump (London. 1967), 169–82. 203–20Google Scholar; Clarke, P. F., The Keynesian Revolution in the Making (Oxford, 1988), 158Google Scholar; idem, Oswald Moslev (1975), chap.10. On setting up the Macmillan committee, see T172/1652. The evidence and report are in T171/295. The best accounts are Booth and Pack, Employment, Capital and Economic Policy, 169–77, and Clarke, Keynesian Revolution, 103–61.
35. The Treasury and the Bank of England closely coordinated their testimony throughout the deliberations of the Macmillan committee. See, for example, Harvey to Leith-Ross, March 20, 1931, in T188/275.
36. Clarke, , Keynesian Revolution, 119, 148–56; for an example of the Treasury's reasoning, see “National Deselopment and State Borrowing”. July 1930, reprinted in Skidelsky, Politicians and the Slump. 409–13.Google Scholar
37. See Middleton, Roger. “The Treasury in the 1930s: Political and Administrative Constraints to Acceptance of the ‘New’ Economics”, Oxford Economic Papers, NS 34 (1982):48–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar; idem, Towards the Managed Economy (London, 1985)Google Scholar; and, for an earlier formulation, McKibbin, Ross, “The Economic Policy of the Second Labour Government”, Past and Present 68 (08, 1975): 95–123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
38. For an indication of how far Labour had come toward a viable reformism by 1939, see “Labour's Home Policy”, adopted in late 1939 and reprinted in Report of the National Executive to the Labour Party Conference. May 1940, 95–99; and Harris, José, “Political Ideas and the Debate on State Welfare”, in War and Social Change: British Society in the Second World War, ed. Smith, Harold (Manchester, 1986). 250–52.Google Scholar
39. See, for example, the speeches given to the Fabian Society and reprinted in Where Stands Socialism To-Day? (London, 1933).Google Scholar On the effect of the 1929–1931 experience, see Weir, Margaret and Skocpol, Theda, “State Structures and the Possibilities for ‘Keynesian’ Responses to the Great Depression in Sweden, Britain and the United States”, in Bringing the State Back In, ed. Evans, Peter et al. , (Cambridge, 1985), 129Google Scholar; and Gourevitch, Peter, Politics in Hard Times (Ithaca, 1987), 135–40.Google Scholar
40. Cripps, Stafford, “Preface”, in Addison, C. et al. , Problems of a Socialist Government (London, 1933), 16Google Scholar; and idem, “Can Socialism Come by Constitutional Methods?” in ibid., 35–66.
41. Bevin, Ernest and Clark, Colin, “Reorganisation of Government Departments and Ministerial Functions”, January 22, 1932, in Fabian Society Papers, J38/2, Nuffield College.Google Scholar
42. Attlee's Memorandum on “The Reorganization of Government” was written sometime in 1932 and is reprinted as Appendix 3 in Harris, Kenneth, Attlee (New York, 1983), 589–95.Google Scholar
43. The activities of the Labour Left in the 1930s are carefully reviewed in Pimlott, Ben, Labour and the Left in the 1930s (Cambridge, 1977).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
44. Newman, Michael, “Democracy versus Dictatorship: Labour's Role in the Struggle against British Fascism, 1933–1936”, History Workshop 5 (Spring 1978):67–88.Google Scholar
45. Compare, for example, Cripps's arguments in 1933 with those in Democracy Up-To-Date (London, 1939)Google Scholar; see also Laski, Harold, “Government in Wartime”, in Society, Fabian, Where Stands Democracy? (London, 1940), 1–42.Google Scholar
46. Cronin, James, Labour and Society in Britain, 1918–1979 (London, 1984), 102–4.Google Scholar
47. Durbin, Elizabeth, New Jerusalems: The Labour Party and the Economics of Democratic Socialism (London, 1985), 92–115.Google Scholar
48. Nationalization was played down even as the form it would take, modeled on what Herbert Morrison had done with London Transport, was made less threatening. On the Morrison model, see Jones, Barry and Keating, Michael, Labour and the British State (Oxford, 1985), 60–61Google Scholar: and Morgan, Kenneth, “The Rise and Fall of Public Ownership in Britain”, in The Political Culture of Modern Britain, ed. Bean, J. W. M. (London, 1987), 279–80.Google Scholar
49. Booth, and Pack, , Employment, Capital and Economic Policy, 145; Durbin, New Jerusalems, 245–8, 260–1.Google Scholar The lack of clarity on the issue of planning was especially significant, in part because there had been a good deal of theoretical work on planning during the 1930s. See, for example, Cole, G. D. H., Principles of Economic Planning (London, 1935)Google Scholar; idem, The Machinery of Socialist Planning (London, 1938Google Scholar: and Durbin, E. F M., Problems of Economic Planning (London, 1949).Google Scholar
50. With some justice, Geoffrey Foote has labelled this evolving program “corporate socialism”. See Foote, , The Labour Party's Political Thought: A History (London, 1985), 149–88.Google Scholar
51. “Labour's Home Policy”, 95–99.
52. Labour's specific contribution to the postwar settlement was thus considerably more important than some recent writings would suggest. See, for example, Stedman, Gareth Jones's description of the reforms of the postwar Labour government as “the last and most glorious flowering of late Victorian Liberal philanthropy”, in Languages of Class: Studies in English Working-Class History (Cambridge, 1984), 246.Google Scholar
53. On political and intellectual change in wartime, see Addison, Paul, The Road to 1945 (London, 1975), and Harris, “Political Ideas and the Debate on State Welfare”Google Scholar.
54. On the relatively smooth translation of program into policy after 1945, see Morgan, Kenneth, Labour in Power, 1945–1951 (Oxford, 1984).Google Scholar For some of the contention, see Schneer, Jonathan, Labour's Conscience: The Labour Left, 1945–1951 (London, 1988).Google Scholar