Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-14T16:55:15.730Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Choosing union: monetary politics and Maastricht

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Get access

Extract

At their Maastricht summit, heads of state of the European Community (EC) countries agreed to establish a single currency and a common central bank by the end of the century. For students of international political economy, the treaty on monetary union offers intriguing puzzles: Why did EC governments commit themselves to such a far-reaching sacrifice of sovereignty? Why did national political leaders in some cases outrun public opinion in their enthusiasm for monetary integration? This study seeks a political explanation of the choices that produced the late-1980s movement for monetary union in Europe. It examines the conversion to monetary discipline in several EC states during the 1980s, arguing that the shift toward anti-inflationary rigor was a necessary precondition for discussions on monetary union. The article outlines three general options for a European monetary regime, based variously on unilateral commitments, multilateral arrangements, and full integration. Treating national preference formation as endogenous and requiring explanation, the article weighs five propositions that explain the motives and preferences of national leaders.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. See, for example, Moravcsik, Andrew, “Negotiating the Single European Act: National Interests and Conventional Statecraft in the European Community”, International Organization 45 (Winter 1991), pp. 1956CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Cameron, David, “The 1992 Initiative: Causes and Consequences”, in Sbragia, Alberta M., ed., Euro-politics: Institutions and Policymaking in the ‘New’ European Community (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1992), pp. 2530.Google Scholar

2. For a cogent expression of the intergovernmentalist view, see Moravcsik, “Negotiating the Single European Act.”

3. See Koehane, Robert O. and Hoffmann, Stanley, “Institutional Change in Europe in the 1980s,” in Keohane, Robert O. and Hoffmann, Stanley, eds., The New European Community: Decisionmaking and Institutional Change (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1991), pp. 1015Google Scholar; and Cameron, , “The 1992 Initiative,” p. 30.Google Scholar

4. Sbragia, Alberta M. makes a similar point; see her “Introduction,” in Sbragia, , ed., Euro-politics, pp. 4 and 12.Google Scholar

5. I am not the first to argue that international institutions have an impact on how nations define their interests. Ernst Haas argued early on that membership in the EC would alter the way interest groups, and therefore governments, perceived their political interests; see Haas, Ernst B., The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958Google Scholar). For more recent arguments on the impact of international institutions on national interest definitions see Keohane, Robert O., After Hegemony (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), p. 63Google Scholar; and Nye, Joseph S. Jr, “Neorealism and Neoliberalism,” World Politics 40 (01 1988), p. 239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6. For a more extended and abstract argument that interests and identities are context-dependent, see Wendt, Alexander, “Anarchy is What States Make of It: The Social Construction of Power Politics,” International Organization 46 (Spring 1992), pp. 391425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7. I have argued elsewhere that EC institutions can provide leadership in promoting collective action in the EC. See Sandholtz, Wayne, “Institutions and Collective Action: The New Telecommunications in Western Europe,” World Politics 45 (01 1993CrossRefGoogle Scholar); and Sandholtz, Wayne, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992Google Scholar), chap. 2. Though the present article focuses on national preference formation, it would be worthwhile to investigate whether the EC Commission played a leadership role in the negotiations on EMU.

8. See Grieco, Joseph S., “Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism,” International Organization 42 (Summer 1988), pp. 485507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9. See Powell, Robert, “Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory,” American Political Science Review 85 (12 1991), pp. 1303–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Snidal, Duncan, “Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation,” American Political Science Review 85 (09 1991), pp. 701–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10. On the need to examine domestic politics, see Milner, Helen, “International Theories of Cooperation Among Nations: Strengths and Weaknesses,” World Politics 44 (04 1992), pp. 489–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

11. Lindberg, Leon N., “Models of the Inflation/Disinflation Process,” in Lindberg, Leon N. and Maier, Charles S., eds., The Politics of Inflation and Economic Stagnation (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1985), p. 25.Google Scholar

12. For more comprehensive accounts of French monetary and financial politics, see Goodman, John B., Monetary Sovereignty: The Politics of Central Banking in Western Europe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1992Google Scholar), chaps. 4 and 6; and Loriaux, Michael, France After Hegemony: International Change and Financial Reform (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991), chaps. 8 and 9.Google Scholar

13. Boisseiu, Christian de and Duprat, Marie-Hélène, “French Monetary Policy,” in Sherman, Heidemarie, Brown, Richard, Jacquet, Pierre, and Julius, DeAnne, eds., Monetary Implications of the 1992 Process (New York: St. Martin's, 1990), p. 81.Google Scholar

14. For accounts of the Mitterrand turnaround, see Cohen, Stephen S., Halimi, Serge, and Zysman, John, “Institutions, Politics, and Industrial Policy in France,” in Barfield, Claude E. and Schambra, William A., eds., The Politics of Industrial Policy (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1986), pp. 106–27Google Scholar; Zysman, John, Governments, Markets, and Growth (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983), pp. 99169Google Scholar; McCarthy, Patrick, “France Faces Reality,” in Calleo, David P. and Morgenstern, Claudia, eds., Recasting Europe's Economies: National Strategies in the 1980s (Lanham, Md.: University Press of America, 1990), pp. 2578Google Scholar; Hall, Peter, Governing the Economy (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1986), pp. 192226Google Scholar; and Gourevitch, Peter, Politics in Hard Times (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press), pp. 185–92.Google Scholar

15. McCarthy, , “France Faces Reality,” pp. 3738.Google Scholar

16. For a detailed analysis of Italian monetary politics, see Goodman, , Monetary Sovereignty, chap. 5.Google Scholar

17. For a concise account, see Epstein, Gerald A. and Schor, Juliet B., “Divorce of the Bank of Italy and the Treasury,” in Lange, Peter and Regini, Marino, eds., State, Market, and Social Regulation: New Perspectives on Italy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), pp. 147–64.Google Scholar

18. Dini, Lamberto, “The Liberalization of Italian Foreign Exchange Controls: Constraints and Opportunities,” Italian Journal, vol. 5, no. 2, 1991, p. 49.Google Scholar

19. See Agence Europe, 30 July 1991; and Agence Europe, 16 November 1991.

20. See Hall, , Governing the Economy, pp. 7699Google Scholar; and Gourevitch, , Politics in Hard Times, pp. 192–99.Google Scholar

21. International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics, electronic database, Washington, D.C.

22. See Rood, Jan Q. Th., “The Position of the Netherlands,” in Sherman et al., Monetary Implications of the 1992 Process, p. 131.Google Scholar

23. See ibid., p. 132; and Weber, Axel, “Reputation and Credibility in the European Monetary System,” Economic Policy 12 (04 1991), p. 86.Google Scholar

24. Weber, , “Reputation and Credibility in the European Monetary System,” pp. 8687.Google Scholar

25. For a sample of the arguments, see Cecco, Marcello de and Giovannini, Alberto, eds., A European Central Bank? Perspectives on Monetary Union After Ten Years of the EMS (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989CrossRefGoogle Scholar); Giavazzi, Francesco, Micossi, Stefano, and Miller, Marcus, eds., The European Monetary System (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988CrossRefGoogle Scholar); and Wood, Geoffrey E., “One Money for Europe? A Review Essay,” Journal of Monetary Economics 25 (03 1990), pp. 313–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

26. See Banaian, King, Laney, Leroy O., and Willett, Thomas D., “Central Bank Independence: An International Comparison,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas (Dallas, TX: 03 1983), pp. 113Google Scholar; Alesina, Alberto, “Politics and Business Cycles in Industrial Democracies,” Economic Policy 8 (04 1989), pp. 5598CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Goodman, John, “The Politics of Central Bank Independence,” Comparative Politics 23 (04 1991), pp. 329–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Burdekin, Richard and Willett, Thomas D., “Central Bank Reform: The Federal Reserve in International Perspective,” Public Budgeting and Financial Management, vol. 3, no. 3, 1991, pp. 619–49.Google Scholar

27. Goodman, , “The Politics of Central Bank Independence,” p. 338.Google Scholar

28. Wise Men from the South,” The Economist, 2 01 1991, p. 77.Google Scholar

29. See Eduard Hochreiter and Ake Törnqvist, “Austria's Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy: Some Comparative Remarks with Respect to Sweden,” paper prepared for the CEPIME seminar, Brussels, 27 April 1990.

30. See Giovannini, Alberto, The Transition to European Monetary Union, Essays in International Finance, no. 178 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Department of Economics, 1990) pp. 46.Google Scholar

31. See Ludlow, Peter, The Making of the European Monetary System (London: Butterworths, 1982).Google Scholar

32. See Wihlborg, Clas and Willett, Thomas D., “Optimal Currency Areas Revisited,” in Wihlborg, Clas, Fratianni, Michele, and Willett, Thomas D., eds., Financial Regulation and Monetary Arrangements After 1992 (Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar, forthcoming); and Eichengreen, Barry, “Currency Union: One Money for Europe? Lessons from the U.S. Currency Union,” Economic Policy 10 (04 1990), pp. 117–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

33. Commission of the European Communities, One Market, One Money,” special issue, European Economy 44 (10 1990), pp. 6364Google Scholar, 87, 136–37, and 178–79.

34. The Meaning of Madrid,” The Economist, 1 07 1989, p. 37.Google Scholar

35. In Rome, Lions are an Endangered Species,” The Economist, 3 11 1990, p. 55.Google Scholar

36. Commission of the European Communities, Economic and Monetary Union (Brussels, Commission of the European Communities, 21 08 1990).Google Scholar

37. See the following publications of the Committee of Governors of the Central Banks of the Member States of the European Economic Community (EEC): Introductory Report on the Draft Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank (Brussels: Committee of Governors of the Central Banks of Member States of the EEC, 27 11 1990Google Scholar); and Draft Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank (Brussels, Committee of Governors of the Central Banks of Member States of the EEC: 27 11 1990).Google Scholar

38. See Hill, Andrew, “Dutch Under Fire over Stance on EMU Progress,” Financial Times, 11 09 1991, p. 3Google Scholar; and Buchan, David, “Three-point Consensus Ends Two-speed Europe,” Financial Times, 23 09 1991, p. 4.Google Scholar

39. See Ecofin Ministers Hold Informal Meeting on EMU,” Agence Europe, 14 05 1991Google Scholar; and Buchan, David, “UK Unhappy with EC Political Union,” Financial Times, 19 09 1991, p. 1.Google Scholar

40. For the summary that follows I have relied on the following sources: “Amendments to the EEC Treaty—Economic and Monetary Union—as Agreed in the European Council of Maastricht on 10 December 1991,” mimeograph (Brussels: Commission of the European Communities [CEC], nd); “Mapping the Road to Monetary Union,” Financial Times, 12 12 1991, p. 5Google Scholar; David Buchan, “ ‘Fast Forwards’ Relish Their Victory in Battle over EMU Timetable,” Financial Times, 11 12 1991, p. 2Google Scholar; and David Buchan and David Marsh, “Currency Union Likely to be a Tier-full Affair,” Financial Times, 10 12 1991, p. 2.Google Scholar

41. The seminal work was Haas, Ernst B., The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958).Google Scholar

42. See Schmitter, Philippe C., “A Revised Theory of Regional Integration,” International Organization 24 (Autumn 1970), pp. 836–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Lindberg, Leon and Scheingold, Stuart A., Europe's Would-be Polity (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1970).Google Scholar

43. Buchan, David, “Delors Presses for Monetary Union,” Financial Times, 24 06 1988, p. 3.Google Scholar

44. CEC, Economic and Monetary Union, p. 5.Google Scholar

45. ibid., p. 11.

46. CEC, One Market, One Money, p. 17.Google Scholar

47. ibid., p. 18.

48. Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso, “The European Monetary System: A Long-term View,” in Giavazzi, , Micossi, , and Miller, , eds., The European Monetary System, pp. 373–76.Google Scholar

49. For a sample of the debates among economists, see de Cecco and Giovannini, eds., A European Central Bank?; Giovazzi, Micossi, and Miller, eds., The European Monetary System; and Wood, “One Money for Europe?”

50. Calculated from Commission of the European Communities, Eurobarometer, no. 33, 06 1990, pp. 15 and 17.Google Scholar

51. Dalton, Russell J. and Eichenberg, Richard, “A People's Europe: Citizen Support for the 1992 Project and Beyond,” in Smith, Dale and Ray, James, eds., The 1992 Project and the Future of Integration in Europe (New York: M.E. Sharpe, 1992), Table 3.Google Scholar

a. The question asked in the Eurobarometer surveys is, “Generally speaking, do you think that (your country's) membership of the Common Market is a good thing, a bad thing, or neither good nor bad?” The numbers in this table represent the percentage of respondents answering “a good thing” minus the percentage of respondents answering “a bad thing.” Eurobarometer surveys are normally carried out twice per year, once in spring and once in autumn. Data in this table come from the spring surveys.

b. Results from the autumn survey are included for Germany because of the large disparity with the spring results.

c. joined the Community in 1981.

d. joined the Community in 1986.

e. lncludes Greece from 1981 and Portugal and Spain from 1986.

Sources. Commission of the European Communities (CEC), Eurobarometer. Trends 1974–1990 (Brussels, CEC, 1991), pp. 6987Google Scholar; CEC, Eurobarometer No. 36 (Brussels, CEC, 1991). p. A21.Google Scholar

52. Commission of the European Communities, Target 92 10 (11/12 1990), suppl., p. 2.Google Scholar The phrase “where national central banks would be represented” may give the suggested outcome a less radical appearance, thus increasing the positive response.

53. Frieden, Jeffry A., “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance,” International Organization 45 (Autumn 1991), pp. 425–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar The quotation is drawn from p. 441.

54. Monnaie unique rime avec marché unique” (Single currency rhymes with single market), Le Monde, 28 04 1989, p. 40.Google Scholar

55. Melloan, George, “German Banks Flex Their ‘European’ Muscles,” Wall Street Journal, 17 01 1989, p. A21.Google Scholar

56. Agence Europe, 7 June 1991.

57. See Peel, Quentin, “EMS Founders Refire Faith in Full Unity,” Financial Times, 19 12 1986, p. 3Google Scholar; and Thatcher to Stand Firm Against EC Bank Plan,” Financial Times, 27 06 1988, p. 1.Google Scholar

58. See Agence Europe, 31 March 1991; and Agence Europe, 16 June 1990.

59. Commission of the European Communities, Eurecom 3 (04 1991), p. 3.Google Scholar

60. “La grande majorité des chefs d'entreprise sont favorables à une monnaie commune” (The great majority of company heads are favorable to a common currency), Le Monde, 29 09 1989, p. 12.Google Scholar

61. Commission of the European Communities, One Market, One Money, pp. 9–10.

a. The survey results depicted in this table are not strictly comparable from year to year. The 1976 survey asked subjects if they would be for or against it if their national currency were replaced by a European currency. The 1985 survey added a third possible response: “Would you be for, against or not mind either way if your national currency were replaced by a European currency?” The “not mind” option almost certainly diminished the size of the favorable response. The 1990 and 1991 surveys, after briefly describing the EC negotiations on the creation of an Economic and Monetary Union, asked subjects if they were “in favour or not” of “a single common currency replacing the different national currencies of the Member States in five or six years' time.”

b. Dashes = no data.

c. the former German Democratic Republic in 1990 and 1991.

d. Excludes Northern Ireland in 1985.

Sources. Commission of the European Community (CEC), Euro-barometre No. 23 (Brussels, CEC, 06 1985), pp. 1718Google Scholar; CEC, Eurobarometer No. 35 (Brussels, CEC, 06 1991), p. A23Google Scholar; and CEC, Eurobarometer No. 36 (Brussels, CEC, 12 1991), p. A37.Google Scholar

62. Milner, , “International Theories of Cooperation Among Nations,” p. 493.Google Scholar

63. Marshall, Tyler and Havemann, Joel, “Ecu, Brute!Los Angeles Times, 9 06 1992, p. H1.Google Scholar

64. Hirschman, Albert O., Exit, Voice, and Loyalty (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970).Google Scholar

65. Renard, Francois, “M. Balladur veut accelerer la construction de l'Europe monetaire” (Mr. Balladur wants to accelerate the building of monetary Europe), Le Monde, 8 01 1988, p. 1.Google Scholar

66. See ibid.; Lemaitre, Philippe, “M. Balladur preconise une strategie de renforcement” (Mr. Balladur recommends a reinforcement strategy), Le Monde, 15 01 1988, p. 28Google Scholar; Davidson, Ian, “Chirac Endorses Call to Set Up EC Central Bank,” Financial Times, 8 01 1988, p. 2Google Scholar; and Greenhouse, Steven, “Central Bank is Urged for Europe,” New York Times, 18 01 1988, p. D1.Google Scholar

67. See Greenhouse, Steven, “Concept of a Central Bank Gains Support in Europe,” New York Times, 13 06 1988, p. D1Google Scholar; Wylee, John, “Italy Voices Concern About Development of Monetary System,” Financial Times, 25 02 1988, p. 2Google Scholar; and Marsh, David, Buchan, David, and Dawkins, William, “European Leaders Inch Towards Closer Monetary Cooperation,” Financial Times, 28 06 1988, p. 1.Google Scholar

68. Dickson, Tim, “Genscher Call for Closer European Monetary Links,” Financial Times, 21 01 1988, p. 2.Google Scholar

69. See Torday, Peter, “European Central Bank is Years Away Despite Some New Interest in the Idea,” Wall Street Journal, 7 03 1988, p. 24Google Scholar; and German Bank Chief Offers Universal Currency Terms,” Wall Street Journal, 6 05 1988, p. 43.Google Scholar

70. See “German Bank Chief Offers Universal Currency Terms”; Karl Otto Pohl, A Vision of a European Central Bank,” Wall Street Journal, 15 07 1988, p. 14Google Scholar; Campbell, Katherine, “Pöhl Warns of Danger in Rapid Moves to EMU,” Financial Times, 4 09 1990, p. 1Google Scholar; Marsh, David, “Bonn Supports Bundesbank on EMU, Warns of Rate Tensions,” Financial Times, 21 09 1990, p. 10Google Scholar; “IGC Session on EMU Described as ‘Extremely Useful’,” Agence Europe, 27 January 1991; and Peel, Quentin, “Bundesbank Deputy Calls for Tough Line on Emu,” Financial Times, 19 09 1991, p. 3.Google Scholar

71. Dickson, Tim, “Genscher Call for Closer European Monetary Links,” Financial Times, 21 01 1988, p. 2.Google Scholar

72. See Steven Greenhouse, “Concept of a Central Bank Gains Support in Europe”; and Marsh, David, “Stoltenberg Calls for EC to End All Capital Controls,” Financial Times, 18 03 1988, p. 2.Google Scholar

73. Brittan, Samuel, “A Single Currency for the EC,” Financial Times, 23 06 1988, p. 25.Google Scholar

74. Buchan, David and Fisher, Andrew, “Curbs on Capital Flows will Test Finance Ministers,” Financial Times, 13 06 1988, p. 1.Google Scholar

75. For a similar conclusion, see Heidemarie Sherman, “Central Banking in Germany,” in Sherman et al., Monetary Implications of the 1992 Process, p. 41.

76. Buchan, David, “Mitterrand Urges Early Talks on EC Monetary Integration,” Financial Times, 26 10 1989, p. 1Google Scholar; Raun, Laura, “Dutch Back Mitterrand's Plan to Accelerate EMU,” Financial Times, 21 11 1989, p. 2Google Scholar; “M. Rocard confirme la détermination de la France de réaliser l'union monétaire européenne” (Mr. Rocard affirms French determination to achieve European monetary union), Le Monde, 11 11 1989, p. 31Google Scholar; and Dumas Suggests Moving Up Monetary Union Talks,” Foreign Broadcast Information Service, 20 03 1990, p. 12.Google Scholar

77. Marsh, David, “Dutch Fearful of Germany Going Its Own Way,” Financial Times, 28 11 1991, p. 2.Google Scholar

78. See Hold on a Minute,” The Economist, 4 11 1989, p. 58Google Scholar; and Kellaway, Lucy, “Kohl Backs Mitterrand in Support for Union,” Financial Times, 23 11 1989, p. 2.Google Scholar

79. Valance, George, “L'engrenage européen” (Europe gears up), L'Express, 19 10 1990, p. 19.Google Scholar

80. Norman, Peter, “Bundesbank Opposes Control of Reserves,” Financial Times, 2 12 1991, p. 3.Google Scholar

81. For an introduction to the literature, see Blackburn, Keith and Christensen, Michael, “Monetary Policy and Policy Credibility: Theories and Evidence,” Journal of Economic Literature 27 (03 1989), pp. 145Google Scholar; Rogoff, Kenneth, “The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. C, no. 403, 11 1985, pp. 1172–73Google Scholar; and Weber, “Reputation and Credibility in the European Monetary System.” For an application of theories of credibility to the European Monetary System, see Woolley, John T., “Policy Credibility and European Monetary Institutions,” in Sbragia, ed., Euro-Politics, pp. 157–90.Google Scholar

82. See the contributions in Willett, Thomas D., ed., Political Business Cycles (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1988).Google Scholar

83. As Clas Wihlborg and Thomas Willett point out, it is important for this argument that there be a single currency. As long as countries retain their own currencies, there is at least the possibility of altering exchange rates to accommodate inflation differentials. During economic shocks, national authorities would be tempted to take advantage of this possibility. See Wihlborg and Willett, “Optimal Currency Areas Revisited.”

84. On the notion of tying one's hands, see Giavazzi, Francesco and Pagano, Marco, “The Advantages of Tying One's Hands: EMS Discipline and Central Bank Credibility,” European Monetary Review 32 (1988), pp. 1055–75.Google Scholar

85. Burdekin, Richard C. K., Wihlborg, Clas, and Willett, Thomas D., “A Monetary Constitution Case for an Independent European Central Bank,” World Economy 15 (03 1992), pp.231–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

86. Agence Europe, 31 January 1992.

87. Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union, Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the European Community [Delors Report] (Brussels: Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union, 12 04 1989), p. 2.Google Scholar