Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T09:19:27.747Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

DEMOCRAZIA E COMMERCIO: IL CASO DELLE GRANDI POTENZE TRA IL 1980 E IL 1998

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 July 2018

Introduzione

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Sin dall'Ottocento, l'economia politica dei classici ha prodotto modelli del commercio internazionale per spiegare tanto i vantaggi derivanti dall'apertura agli scambi, quanto la struttura dei flussi commerciali tra i diversi paesi. A tutt'oggi, gli assunti avanzati dal modello ricardiano del commercio internazionale e dal modello Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson, che spiegano i flussi di scambi commerciali rispettivamente basandosi sui concetti di vantaggio comparato e di dotazione di risorse, forniscono strumenti ampiamente utilizzati nella spiegazione dell'insorgenza e del mantenimento di rapporti commerciali tra stati. A differenza della letteratura economica, che si è concentrata in buona misura sulle cause dell'apertura commerciale e sulla spiegazione delle direzioni dei flussi di scambio, spesso limitandosi a individuare i fattori costanti nelle politiche protezioniste o liberiste degli stati, la letteratura politologica ha puntato il proprio interesse sulla spiegazione delle variazioni nella scelta degli stati di promuovere, oppure limitare, il grado di apertura agli scambi con l'estero.

Summary

Summary

Starting from the origins of the Liberal tradition of political thought, this article tracks back the roots of the link between trade and democracy. They are to be found in the idea of «economic commerce» from the writings of Montesquieu and Olson's political economy work on the nexus between regime representativeness and fiscal policy choices to the most recent empirical literature on the «democratic difference». The assumption that, for causes of both fiscal optimization and policy constraints exerted by a protectionist legislative on the executive, democracies are more prone towards free trade than non democracies. This study proves that domestic political regimes have an impact on the level of bilateral trade among great powers, while also endowing with robust empirical evidence the proposition according to which pairs of democratic states tend to trade more with each other than mixed pairs (e.g. pairs composed by a democracy and an autocracy) do. Furthermore, this research stands as the first empirical test of the relevance of the difference for trade made by democracy after the end of the Cold War and the democratization of Russia.

Type
Ricerche
Copyright
Copyright © 2003 by Società editrice il Mulino, Bologna 

References

Riferimenti bibliografici

Aitken, N.D. (1973), The Effect of the EEC and EFTA on European Trade: A Temporal Cross Section Analysis, in «American Economic Review», n. 63, 1973, pp. 881892.Google Scholar
Anderson, J.E. (1979), A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation, in «American Economic Review», n. 69, pp. 6116.Google Scholar
Bhagwati, J. (1993), Regionalism and Multilateralism, An Overview, in De Melo, J. e Panagariya, A. (a cura di), New Dimensions in Regional Integration, New York, Cambridge University Press, pp. 2254.Google Scholar
Blissett, H. e Russett, B. (1998), Democratic Trading Partners: The Liberal Connection, in «Journal of Politics», n. 60, pp. 1126–47.Google Scholar
Dai, X. (2002), Political Regimes and International trade: the Democratic Differences Revisited, in «American Political Science Review», n. 96, pp. 159–65.Google Scholar
Deardorff, A.V. (1998), Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World?, in Frankel, J.A. (a cura di), The Regionalization of the World Economy, Chicago and London, The University of Chicago Press, pp. 731.Google Scholar
Dixon, W.J. e Moon, B.M. (1993), Political Similarity and American Foreign Trade Patterns, in «Political Research Quarterly», n. 46, pp. 525.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1958), An Economic Theory of Democracy, Washington, Brookings.Google Scholar
Doyle, M. (1986), Liberalism and World Politics, in «American Political Science Review», n. 80, pp. 11511169.Google Scholar
Doyle, M. (1996), Kant, Liberal Legacies and Foreign Affairs, in M.E. Brown, S.M. Lynn-Jones e Steven Miller, Debating the Democratic Peace, Cambridge (Mass)., The MIT Press, pp. 357.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. e Irwin, D.A. (1998), The Role of History in Bilateral Trade Flows in J.A. Frankel (a cura di), The Regionalization of the World Economy, Chicago and London, The University of Chicago Press, pp. 3362.Google Scholar
Gilpin, R. (1975), U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation, New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar
Gilpin, R. (1987), The Political Economy of International Relations, Princeton, Princeton University Press; trad. it. (1990), Politica ed Economia delle Relazioni Internazionali, Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Gourevitch, P. (1986), Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises, Ithaca and New York, Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Gowa, J. (1995), Democratic States and International Disputes, in «Democratic States and International Disputes», vol. 49, n. 3, pp. 511522.Google Scholar
Gowa, J. e Mansfield, E.D. (1993), Power Politics And International Trade, in «American Political Science Review», n. 87, pp. 408420.Google Scholar
Gurr, T., Jaggers, K. e Moore, W.H. (1989), Polity II Codebook, Center for Comparative Politics, Department of Political Science, University of Colorado, Boulder, CO.Google Scholar
Gurr, T., Jaggers, K. e Moore, W.H. (2000), Database Polity IV al sito web: www.bsos.umd.edu/cidcm/polity.Google Scholar
Haas, M. (1974), International Conflict, Indianapolis, Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Halvorsen, R. e Palmquist, R. (1980), The Interpretation of Dummy Variables in Semilogarithmic Equations, in «American Economic Review», n. 70, pp. 474475.Google Scholar
Hughes, H. (1986), The Political Economy of Protection in 11 Industrial Countries, in Snape, R.H. (a cura di), Issues in World Trade Policies, New York, St. Martin's Press, cap. 11.Google Scholar
Kant, I. (1795), Per la pace perpetua, traduzione di R. Bordiga, Milano, Feltrinelli, 2002, ottava edizione.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Ch. (1973), The World in Depression, 1929-1939, Berkeley, CA, University of California Press.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Ch. (1981), Dominance and Leadership in the International Economy: Exploitation, Public Goods and Free Riders, in «International Studies Quarterly», n. 25, pp. 242254.Google Scholar
Kuznets, S. (1930), Saecular Movements in Production and Prices, Boston and New York, Houghton Mifflin Company.Google Scholar
Lobell, S.E. (1999), Second Image Reversed Politics: Britain's Choice of Freer Trade or Imperial Preferences, 1903-1906, 1917-1923, 1930-1932, in «International Studies Quarterly», n. 43, pp. 671694.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (1982), Phases of Capitalist Development, Oxford-New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Magee, S.P. (1980), Three Simple Tests of the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem in P. Oppenheimer (a cura di), Issues in International Economics, London, Oriel Press, pp. 138153.Google Scholar
Mansfield, E.D. e Bronson, R. (1997), The Political Economy of Major-Power Trade Flows, in Mansfield, E.D. e Milner, H.V. (a cura di), The Political Economy of Regionalism, New York, Columbia University Press, pp. 188208.Google Scholar
Montesquieu, C.L. de Sécondat de, Lo spirito delle leggi, (1748), traduzione di B. Boffito Serra, Milano, Rizzoli, 1999.Google Scholar
Morrow, J., Siverson, R. e Tabares, T. (1998), The Political Determinants of International Trade: The Major Powers, 1907-1990, in «American Political Science Review», n. 92, pp. 649661.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action, Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, M. e McGuire, M. (1996), The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule: the Invisible Hand and the Use of Force, in «Journal of Economic Literature», n. 34, pp. 7296.Google Scholar
Parikh, A. (1986), The Estimation and Forecasting of Trade Shares, Development papers No. 5, Bangkok, Economic and Social Commission for Asia and Pacific, UN Publication.Google Scholar
Pelzman, J. (1977), Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in The Council of Mutual Economic Assistance, in «American Economic Review», n. 67, pp. 713722.Google Scholar
Putnam, D. (1988), Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two Level Games, in «Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two Level Games», vol. 42, n. 3, pp. 427–60.Google Scholar
Ricardo, D. (1963), The Principles of Political Economy [1817], Homewood, IL, Irwin.Google Scholar
Rogowski, R. (1989), Commerce and Coalitions, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Russett, B. (1993), Can a Democratic Peace Be Built?, in «International Interactions», n. 18, pp. 277282.Google Scholar
Russett, B. (1997), Grasping the Democratic Peace: Principles for a Post-Cold War World, Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. (1948), International Trade and the Equalisation of Factor Prices, in «Economic Journal», n. 58, pp. 163164.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. (1949), International Factor Price Equalisation Once Again, in «Economic Journal», n. 59, pp. 181196.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J.A. (1919), The Sociology of Imperialism, in Imperialism and Social Classes, Cleveland, World Publishing Co., 1955.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J.A. (1961), The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest and the Business Cycle, New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Small, M. e Singer, D. (1969), Formal Alliances, 1816-1965: An Extension of the Basic Data, in Journal of Peace Research, n. 6, pp. 257282.Google Scholar
Small, M. e Singer, D. (1994), Correlates of War Project: International and Civil Wars Data, 1816-1992, Ann Arbor, ICPSR, n. 9905, La versione aggiornata del database è disponibile al sito www.umich.edu/cowproj.Google Scholar
Snyder, G. (1997), Alliance Politics, Ithaca and London, Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Viner, J. (1950), The Customs Union Issue, New York, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.Google Scholar