1. Introduction
Preconditioning is a management practice that prepares weaned cattle for feedlots. This practice can be performed by calf producers or by other actors in the beef supply chain, such as backgrounders, and generally requires 45 days in which the cattle undergo a health protocol, are castrated, dehorned, and placed in housing conditions similar to the feedlot. The health protocol consists of administering vaccines against BRDFootnote 1 and deworming. Preconditioned calves have better immune functionality to cope with the initial feedlot stress which minimizes weight loss (Griebel et al., Reference Griebel, Hill and Stookey2014) and have lower incidence of BRD than non-preconditioned calves (Thrift and Thrift, Reference Thrift and Thrift2011). They are less susceptible to severe infections, have lower morbidity and mortality (Avent et al., Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004; Dhuyvetter et al., Reference Dhuyvetter, Bryant and Blasi2005; Williams et al., Reference Williams, Raper, DeVuyst, Peel and McKinney2012), and experience less stress, especially during the shipping and receiving period, than non-preconditioned cattle (Lalman and Mourer, Reference Lalman and Mourer2014). Feedlot operators may apply a metaphylactic treatment of antibiotics on arrival to protect incoming cattle against BRD, especially lighter weight cattle, which is at a higher risk of BRD (USDA, 2019). When both preconditioned and non-preconditioned cattle comingle in the feedlot, feedlot operators may use antimicrobials in both groups as a precaution.
Beef production constitutes a major use of antimicrobials in the US, with an estimated 2.5 thousand metric tons of medically important antimicrobials marketed for cattle in 2020 (USFDA, 2021). Excessive use of antimicrobials in food production is linked to antimicrobial resistance bacteria (Tang et al., Reference Tang, Caffrey, Nóbrega, Cork, Ronksley, Barkema and Polachek2017). Practices, such as preconditioning of calves that enter feedlots, have the potential to be implemented and contribute to a more judicious use of antimicrobials in US beef production; however, the amount of antimicrobial reduction due to preconditioning has not been estimated (Lhermie et al., Reference Lhermie, Verteramo Chiu, Kaniyamattam, Tauer, Scott and Grohn2019). Adoption of preconditioning practices must be incentivized to the preconditioner.
Evidence suggests that preconditioned cattle are less likely to become affected by diseases requiring antimicrobials use (Edwards, Reference Edwards2010); thus, preconditioning can be a way to reduce antimicrobials use in the beef production system compared to shipping newly weaned cattle to feedlots (Ives and Richeson, Reference Ives and Richeson2015).Footnote 2 Given the ongoing trend of antibiotic-free food consumption, consumers may value beef produced with fewer antimicrobials more than traditionally produced beef (Lusk et al., Reference Lusk, Norwood and Pruitt2006), thereby paying a premium of which a share could be passed back to calf producers that perform preconditioning.
Preconditioners may follow an established preconditioning plan in order to obtain a preconditioning certification,Footnote 3 which allows them to receive a price premium for their cattle. Many preconditioning certification schemes in the US are administered by public and private entities (e.g., Oklahoma Quality Beef Network Vac-45 (OSU), Superior Livestock Vaccination Programs, and Iowa Cattlemen’s Association Preconditioning Programs). The magnitude of the price premium paid to preconditioners depends on the estimated benefits to feedlots of preconditioned versus non-preconditioned cattle, particularly due to lower morbidity and mortality rates
Studies on the benefits of preconditioning are numerous. Schumacher et al. (Reference Schumacher, Schroeder and Tonsor2012) estimated that an identified health program is worth $7.28/cwt to feedlots, and an extra $2.37/cwt is added to the benefits if the certification agency is the USDA. Third-party certifications in Iowa auctions generate $6.12/cwt in premium over $3.35/cwt for non-certified claims of preconditioning (Bulut and Lawrence, Reference Bulut and Lawrence2007). The average price premium received for preconditioning cattle has been estimated to range between $10.58 and $19.35/cwtFootnote 4 over the years 2011–2019. Despite the benefits to the feedlot of introducing preconditioned over non-preconditioned cattle, the practice of preconditioning is not the dominant technology in cattle production.Footnote 5
Preconditioned cattle can still experience disease, so the benefit of preconditioning is stochastic. We look at the return distributions that may occur, simulating the performance of preconditioned versus non-preconditioned cattle that enter feedlots, and use stochastic dominance techniques to determine feedlot operator preferences under different risk tolerances. The simulated cattle feedlot performance values were generated by fitting PERT distributions to published performance estimations.
The purpose of this paper is to estimate the economic incentive which makes producing preconditioned cattle attractive for cow-calf operators with backgrounding capacity. We used stochastic dominance analysis on the distributions of net returns per head of preconditioned and non-preconditioned animals at the feedlot, to determine the choice of preconditioning status given feedlot operator’s risk appetite. We included the net return of preconditioned cattle with a price premium that covers the cost of preconditioning most of the time. Alternatively, using certainty equivalent analysis on the net return distributions, we estimated the price premium which would make feedlot operators indifferent between purchasing preconditioned and non-preconditioned cattle.
Our estimations can help determine the potential premium that might be passed back to cow-calf operators by feedlot managers from producing preconditioned calves under a heath protocol. Understanding this potential premium can shed light into the feasibility of efficient market-based mechanisms that decrease the susceptibility of BRD at feedlots.
2. Methods
2.1. Beef Production System Description
The cattle production system in the US is heterogeneous. It may involve few or many steps in the commercialization from birth to slaughter. Common beef production stages are cow-calf operation, backgrounder or stocker, and feedlot (Peel, Reference Peel2003). Backgrounder and stocker operations consist of raising post-weaned calves to a higher weight to develop animal frame and muscle (Peel, Reference Peel2003) before transfer to the feedlot.
Cow-calf operators can sell weaned cattle to backgrounders, sell directly to feedlots, or raise the weaned cattle to a higher weight and sell them to backgrounders or feedlots. Cow-calf operators can also retain ownership of their cattle when they are transferred to a backgrounder or a feedlot. Figure 1 shows the relevant US beef production system for this study, which depicts two possible paths, among many, for weaned cattle to feedlot: either weaned calves moving directly to a feedlot or first through a preconditioning program before movement to the feedlot.
Many weaned cattle go through a post-weaning growing program by a commercial backgrounder (Peel, Reference Peel2003). Backgrounders are an important link in the beef industry; they consolidate and prepare young cattle before entering feedlots by providing low-energy high-forage starter rations under confinement. This feedlot preparation is also called preconditioning if it includes a health protocol such as common vaccinations, deworming, castration, and dehorning. Some cow-calf operators perform backgrounding operations if they have the capacity. Stocker operations where weaned calves are first feed outside the finishing feedlot using various available forages may include health protocols as well, effectively producing preconditioned cattle. We do not consider the case of stocker operations in this articleFootnote 6 .
In feedlots, cattle from many sources are fed in a confined environment until they reach a finished weight ranging between 1100 and 1400 lb (Comerford, Kime, and Harper, Reference Comerford, Kime and Harper2013), before being sent to a slaughterhouse. Transportation, social mixing, confinement, and new diets consisting of high-protein feed stress cattle placed into feedlots, which makes them more prone to acquire infections from other cattle and the environment (Aich et al., Reference Aich, Potter and Griebel2009; Griebel et al., Reference Griebel, Hill and Stookey2014). Feedlots consider newly weaned and shipped cattle high-risk cattle, compared to preconditioned cattle which are considered low-risk cattle (Lalman and Mourer, Reference Lalman and Mourer2014). We refer to preconditioned cattle as low risk and non-preconditioned cattle that are weaned and shipped to feedlots as high risk.
Feedlot operators may be willing to pay premia for preconditioned cattle based on performance, such as higher average daily gain (ADG), and lower morbidity and mortality, which unfortunately is stochastic, and not known with certainty. If the premium is sufficiently high, cow-calf operators with backgrounding capacity, or backgrounders as a separate business entity, could be incentivized to precondition cattle. The return and thus the decision to precondition or not depends on many factors, including risk preference of the producer, preconditioning premium, cattle price and its price slide,Footnote 7 feed costs, and the benefits to feedlots. While the benefits to feedlots from introducing preconditioned cattle directly affects the premium offered to producers, the distribution of those benefits and the risk profile of the feedlot operator also plays an important role in determining the price premium offered to producers of preconditioned cattle.
2.2. Preconditioning Protocol
Many analyses of preconditioning benefits focus on 45-day preconditioning protocolsFootnote 8 (Hilton and Olynk, Reference Hilton and Olynk2011; McCollum and Gill, Reference McCollum and Gill2000). Cattle following a 45-day preconditioning program are sold to feedlots at a higher premium compared to shorter programs (Dhuyvetter et al., Reference Dhuyvetter, Bryant and Blasi2005; Dhuyvetter, Reference Dhuyvetter2004). Our analysis follows a 45-day program. These protocols require calves to be weaned for 45 days or longer before feedlot placement, be dehorned, castrated, and vaccinated. The protocol recommends deworming and feeding concentrate supplements for at least the last 7 days. During the 45-day period, calves are expected to gain about 1.50 lbs/day (Dhuyvetter et al., Reference Dhuyvetter, Bryant and Blasi2005; Donnell et al., Reference Donnell, Ward and Swigert2008).
2.3. Data
2.3.1. Cost of Calf Production
In our model, the cow-calf operator produces calves and weans them at 550 lb. At that point, the calves are either sold to a feedlot or grown from 550 to 618 lb in 45 days following a preconditioning protocol and then sold to a feedlot. At the feedlot, calves are fed until they reach 1400 lb and then sold to a slaughterhouse.
Costs of production are estimated for weaned, and backgrounded calves, and finished cattle from Kansas State University (KSU) KFMA Enterprise ReportsFootnote 9 2019 (2014–2018 average). We obtained the expenses per pound for weaned calves (Beef Cows-Calves Report), backgrounded calves (Beef-Backgrounding Report), and finishing animals (Beef-Backgrounding/Finishing Report). All values are Kansas State averages. This location was selected because it is a major cattle-producing region. The costs of production include feed and pasture costs and other direct expenses, indirect expenses, and fixed costs. We included extra costs for preconditioning in the backgrounding budget. Preconditioning costs are additional to the backgrounding costs; it is an added process. Similar budget analyses include Brooks and Eirich (Reference Brooks and Eirich2014), Dhuyvetter et al. (Reference Dhuyvetter, Bryant and Blasi2005), and Donnell et al. (Reference Donnell, Ward and Swigert2008).
We estimated the market prices for the specific cattle weights in the analysis using linear interpolation between the purchasing and selling prices of cattle from the Beef-Backgrounding Report. The finished price of cattle was obtained from the selling price of the Beef-Backgrounding/Finishing Report of the KFMA Enterprise Reports (2014–2018 average).
Preconditioning costs, which includes labor, facilities and equipment, vaccines, and marketing, are obtained from Dhuyvetter et al. (Reference Dhuyvetter, Bryant and Blasi2005). Preconditioning expenses per head include vaccinations (Donnell et al., Reference Donnell, Ward and Swigert2008), labor and equipment (Dhuyvetter et al., Reference Dhuyvetter, Bryant and Blasi2005), deworming (Dhuyvetter et al., Reference Dhuyvetter, Bryant and Blasi2005), and marketing. Mortality losses were included in the analysis.
Gallo and Berg (Reference Gallo and Berg1995) found a reduction in morbidity in cattle treated with antimicrobials in feedlots of 25%. Nickell and White (Reference Nickell and White2010) estimate a reduction of morbidity risk of metaphylaxis treatment of 50% compared to not administering metaphylaxisFootnote 10 . The cost of treating a sick animal is estimated at $30.82 USDA (2013a).
The parameter values for the budget analysis are summarized in Table 1. These values are the baseline to estimate the benefits of preconditioning in the system.
a Non-preconditioned cattle.
b Preconditioned cattle.
c Kansas State University (KSU) KFMA Enterprise Reports 2019 (2014–2018 average) (KSU, 2019). Adjusted for CPI Inflation to 2019 (https://www.bls.gov/data/inflation_calculator.htm).
Original values for treatment: $23.60; vaccinations: $10; labor, equip. and facil.: $6.75; dewormer: $0.50; marketing costs: $3. Marketing costs include preconditioning tags.
The ADG is used to estimate the number of days spent in the feedlot by each animal type. Differences in the ADG will have an impact on feedlot costs, captured in non-feed costs per day. The weight produced in the feedlot are 872 lb and 797 lb for non-preconditioned and preconditioned cattle, respectively. These weights include shrinkage of 4 and 2.5%, respectively. At the expected daily gain of 2.56 and 2.93 lb, the expected days in feed are 332 and 264, for non-preconditioned and preconditioned cattle. With an estimated non-feed costs of $31.29/cwt of gain,Footnote 11 the non-feed cost per day at the feedlot are $0.81 and $0.92, for non-preconditioned and preconditioned cattle. To be conservative in our estimates, we assume a daily non-feed cost of $0.92 for both types of cattle.
2.3.2. Partial Budget Analysis
We present budget analyses based on Table 1 for the three types of operations, one for the cow-calf operation (no preconditioning), the preconditioning operation, and the third for the feedlot operation, who can buy either preconditioned or non-preconditioned calves. Table 2 contains the analysis of the cow-calf operation which sells a newly weaned calves to a feedlot (or to a backgrounder) without preconditioning. This operation loses $40 per calf sold given the budget parameters used; however, negative net returns in cattle production often occur and depends greatly on market conditions.
Rounding errors may be present. Estimates were obtained from 2019 Kansas Farm Management Association, Annual ProfitLink Summary, Beef Cows-Calves (2014–2018). Shrink assumed at 4%. Newly weaned calf weight is 549 lb.
Table 3 shows the net return of the backgrounding operation following the preconditioning protocol.
Rounding errors may be present. Preconditioning is assumed to be conducted in cow-calf operations that have backgrounding capacity. Preconditioned calves are sold at 618 lb. The number of lb produced in the preconditioning operation is 68. Shrink is 2.5% and death loss is 1%. Gross income in $/cwt is for weight produced. Estimates were obtained from 2019 Kansas Farm Management Association, Annual ProfitLink Summary, Beef-Backgrounding (2014–2018).
Similar to selling newly weaned calves, selling backgrounded calves under a 45-day preconditioning protocol does not generate positive net results under the assumption that the producer does not receive a price premium for preconditioning. In this estimation, net returns become positive if the price premium is about 1% of the market price, or $1.86/cwt.
Next, we estimate the benefits to the feedlot when it introduces non-preconditioned or preconditioned calves based on the performance estimates from Table 1. This estimation does not include the stochastic analysis of feedlot performance, but only point estimates. The price premium, if any, that the feedlot can offer to purchase low-risk cattle given expected performance, prices and costs can be estimated from Table 4.
Rounding errors may be present. Cost of animal includes shrink. Non-preconditioned calves enter the feedlot at 550 lb. Preconditioned calves enter the feedlot at 618 lb. Fed animals are finished at 1400 lb. Feedlot performance parameters for non-preconditioned and preconditioned cattle were obtained from the average values of Avent et al. (Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004).
Under the baseline parameter values and no stochastic feedlot performance, preconditioned cattle return $46.19/head more than non-preconditioned cattle. This benefit translates to a maximum premium per head that the feedlot can pay for a low-risk animal of $7.26/cwt. This estimate is within the range of $6.98 and $10.97/cwt as estimated by Dhuyvetter et al. (Reference Dhuyvetter, Bryant and Blasi2005).
2.4. Stochastic Performance Parameters of Preconditioning
The stochastic benefits of preconditioned cattle to feedlots were estimated from data from Avent et al. (Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004) surveys to feedlot managers. We focus on differences in morbidity, mortality, and ADG between preconditioned and non-preconditioned cattle.
The equation used to simulate net returns per animal at the feedlot is
where π is net revenue per animal at the feedlot, P is price per cwt of fed cattle, W is the weight of fed cattle sold (14 cwt), C is the cost of the animal purchased from the cow-calf producer, $\widetilde{{\rm DR}}$ is the simulated death rate of the animal, F is the feed cost per cwt, WG is the expected weight gain of the animal in the feedlot, $\widetilde{{\rm SR}}$ is the simulated sick rate of the animal, TR is the average treatment cost of a sick animal, $\widetilde{D}$ is the simulated days in feedlot, which is a function, $\widetilde{D}_{h}={\rm WeightGained}_{h}/\widetilde{{\rm ADG}}_{h}$ , of ${\rm WeightGained}$ (expected weight gained at feedlot) and $\widetilde{{\rm ADG}}$ , simulated average daily weight gain of the animal, and DC is the non-feed feedlot daily costs per animal. The subscript h refers to the health status of the animals: preconditioned or non-preconditioned, y is an indicator of the year, or period, when prices are observed. $\widetilde{{\rm DR}}_{h,y}, {\rm SR}_{h},$ and $\widetilde{{\rm ADG}}_{h}$ are the simulated PERT random variables, which depend on h.
From the parameter estimates of Avent, Ward, and Lalman (Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004) (mean, minimum, maximum, and standard deviation), we fitted a PERT distribution to each variable to incorporate a stochastic component into the analysis. These parameter estimates were used because they compare the performance of preconditioned and non-preconditioned cattle at various feedlots during the same period. Although there are many studies that estimate performance of preconditioned and non-preconditioned cattle at the feedlot, most parameter estimations are point estimates (Lalman and Mourer, Reference Lalman and Mourer2014; Lalman and Ward, Reference Lalman and Ward2005, Mathis et al., Reference Mathis, Löest and Carter2008). Fitting a PERT distribution is pragmatic when there is limited information about stochastic outcomes since it only requires three data points: minimum, maximum, and mode. PERT is similar to a triangular distribution but with more weight around its mode compared to its extreme values. Using a normal distribution may not be appropriate in this case because of the small sample size (n = 16 feedlots sampled) and because its unboundedness may create outliers. Fitting the PERT distributions in this analysis required the estimation of the mode of the distribution and the shape parameter, Lambda, to match the PERT mean with the observed mean by Avent et al.
To capture some of the variability in the performance measures of preconditioned and non-preconditioned animals in the feedlot, we simulated 1,000 observations of death rate, sick rate, and ADG using PERT distributions with parameters from Table 5. Each performance variable was independently drawn from each other using the function rpert from the library mc2d in R. From the results of the performance simulation, we obtained distributions of net returns per head at the feedlot for each type of cattle using equation (1).
Average, minimum, and maximum were obtained from Avent et al. (Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004). Mode and Lambda were calibrated to fit each PERT distribution to the values estimated by Avent et al. Standard deviation (SD) is the result of the PERT distribution estimated. See the Appendix for more information on the distribution estimation process.
2.5. Stochastic Dominance
Stochastic dominance is a decision criterion used when the variable of interest is stochastic and decision-makers are expected utility maximizers. Implementing this method requires only the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of the competing choices. Although the 1,000 simulations produce normally distributed results, and the mean and variance could therefore be used in the stochastic dominance analysis, we elect to use the entire distribution for analysis. Stochastic dominance rules provide a visual comparison of the competing outcomes, including a qualitatively assessment of risk preferences in choosing competing outcomes when neither dominates the other. Graphically, when the CDF of a choice lies to the right of another competing choice without crossing, the CDF at the right is said to stochastically dominate the other distribution in first order, and it will be preferred over the dominated choice regardless of the risk preferences of the decision-maker. If the CDF of the choice that starts on the left eventually crosses the CDF of the other choice, while having a larger area under the CDF, the CDF of the choice that started on the right is said to second-order stochastically dominate the other choice, and the dominant choice will be preferred by a risk-averse decision-maker. A risk-seeking decision-maker, however, may prefer a choice that is second-order stochastically dominated.
2.6. Certainty Equivalence
The minimum amount of money a decision-maker is willing to pay in order to avoid a gamble, or stochastic outcome, with a potential higher expected value is the certainty equivalent (CE) to the gamble. The CE is a way to place a sole monetary value on the utility of a stochastic choice. A decision-maker will select the choice, among many stochastic choices, that generates the highest CE. The CE provides the same utility to the decision-maker than the gamble: $U\left({\rm CE}\right)=E\left[U\left(\tilde{x}\right)\right]$ , where U() is a utility function, E[] is the expectation operator, and $\tilde{x}$ is a stochastic variable representing the gamble. Utility functions are monotonically increasing (more is preferred to less) and for risk-averse individuals, concave, indicating decreasing marginal utility. The CE of a gamble depends on the decision-maker’s risk preferences. Risk preferences are captured by the Arrow–Pratt risk aversion coefficient, which measures the shape of the individual’s utility function, more specifically, its curvature. The Arrow–Pratt risk aversion coefficient is the negative of the ratio of the second derivative of the utility function to its first derivative: $\displaystyle r = - {{{U''\left( \; \right)} \over {U'\left( \; \right)}}}$ . A commonly used utility function is the exponential utility function: U(x) = e −rx . The formula of the CE for this function is $\displaystyle{\rm CE}\left(x\right)=E\left[\tilde{x}\right]-{r\sigma ^{2} \over 2}$ , where E $[\tilde{x}]$ is the expected value of the random outcome and σ 2 is the variance of the random outcome. The CE formula is valid under normality assumptions. Our simulated net returns are assumed to have a normal distribution due to the large number of iterations (n = 1,000). When r = 0, the decision-maker is risk-neutral and the only decision criteria is the expected value of the stochastic outcome. Higher values of r, assuming σ 2 > 0, would lower the CE value, indicating that the decision-maker is more risk-averse.
With the simulated net returns per head of preconditioned and non-preconditioned animal in the feedlot, we can estimate their CEs: ${\rm CE}\left({\rm prec}\right)$ and ${\rm CE}\left({\rm non-prec}\right)$ . The difference is an estimate of the preconditioning premium that the feedlot operator is willing to pay, depending on the operator’s risk aversion.
In the following section, we present the results of the stochastic performance of cattle at the feedlot and the resulting preconditioning price premia obtained from cost analysis to the producer and from using certainty equivalent on the feedlot operation.
3. Results and Discussion
Since preconditioned cattle produce greater benefits than non-preconditioned cattle to the feedlot, the question is why introducing preconditioned cattle in a feedlot is not the dominant practice? After all, the mechanisms exist for feedlots to incentivize cow-calf operators to follow a preconditioning protocol by offering a price premium. Preconditioning protocols can be certified by third parties to provide assurance to the buyer. To answer that question, we perform stochastic analysis on the distribution of returns from preconditioning and non-preconditioning. According to Lalman and Mourer (Reference Lalman and Mourer2014), 27.2% of all cattle lots sold through Superior Livestock Video Auction in 2012 were preconditioned certified (VAC-45). However, for the market to operate efficiently, all information related to potential benefits of preconditioning and the health status of incoming animals to the feedlot should be available to all market participants. Preconditioned cattle, when placed in a pen along non-preconditioned, high-risk cattle, may have morbidity and mortality rates like the high-risk cattle (Hilton, Reference Hilton2014). Feedlots have significant risk in accepting cattle as preconditioned if there is no perfect information on the distribution of preconditioned cattle performance and net return per head. Moreover, feedlots can treat incoming cattle with a metaphylaxis treatment to minimize losses from incoming high-risk cattle.
To incentivize producers to precondition post-weaned cattle, the price premium received by producers should compensate the costs and the risks associated to preconditioning, given their risk preferences. In this analysis, using equation(1), we set a price premium that covers the health protocol costs of preconditioning. This value is calculated at $25.60/head (from Table 1) and is assumed to be the minimum amount for a preconditioning premium. Net returns per year for each scenario are shown in Table 6.
a Average of these years.
The average maximum premium per head and the 95% confidence interval for the sample period are $60.55 (52.49, 68.61), which corresponds to a maximum premium per cwt of preconditioned cattle of $9.79 (8.49, 11.10). The maximum premium represents the net total benefits to the feedlot from purchasing preconditioned cattle without any precondition price premium. The average net benefit of preconditioning ($60.55) per head in our estimation is about the same expected net benefit of using a metaphylaxis treatment with "lower-tier" antimicrobials,Footnote 12 $58.05, while the average net benefit of using an "upper-tier" antimicrobials is estimated at $109.31 (Dennis et al., Reference Dennis, Schroeder and Renter2020). Dennis et al. do not consider random variation in feedlot performance for preconditioned and non-preconditioned cattle as we have done.
The CDFs of net returns per preconditioned animal, with and without a price premium, and non-preconditioned animal at the feedlot is shown in Figure 2.
When no price premium is paid for preconditioned animals, the net returns of preconditioned cattle stochastically dominate by first degree the returns of non-preconditioned cattle at the feedlot. However, under a scenario in which feedlots pay a price premium that covers the cost of the health protocol in the preconditioning operation, the CDFs of the net returns of preconditioned with premium and non-preconditioned cattle to the feedlot cross once. In this case, no distribution stochastically dominates in the first degree, but net returns from preconditioned cattle with premium second-order stochastically dominate net returns of non-preconditioned cattle. These results imply that risk-neutral feedlot operations would select preconditioning under the specified price premium and assumptions. A feedlot operator with sufficiently high risk-seeking preferences may prefer non-preconditioned cattle, since they provide a small probability of higher net returns. However, this conclusion would be sensitive to expected preconditioning premium, which incentivizes the cow-calf operator to precondition, and parameters of the stochastic event, discussed next.
The differences in prices between weaned and fed cattle, as well as the cost of production, also contribute to the feedlot expected benefits of purchasing preconditioned cattle. We compared the benefits of preconditioned and non-preconditioned cattle at the feedlot for the years 2014 and 2010, which corresponds to a year where the ratio of prices of fed cattle to weaned cattle was at its lowest (0.656) and highest (0.849) of our sample, respectively. The ratio of total costs for fed cattle to weaned cattle was also lowest in 2014 (0.64), while in 2010 was the second highest (0.77).
The CDFs for years 2014 (Figure 3) and 2010 (Figure 4) are similar to that of years 2014–2018. Preconditioned cattle with premium paid continue to dominate stochastically non-preconditioned cattle net returns at the feedlot (second order in 2014 and first order in 2010). Similar to Figure 2, non-preconditioned cattle have a small probability of generating higher net returns than preconditioned cattle, and thus a risk-seeking feedlot manager may prefer non-preconditioned cattle.
The preference for preconditioned cattle at the feedlot will be affected by the expected price premium, but this price premium is dependent on the expected net benefits at the feedlot over non-preconditioned cattle. In all the sample years analyzed, net benefits of preconditioning to the feedlot, without a price premium, were always positive. Preconditioning generates additional net benefits to the beef production system analyzed in this study. Benefits to the feedlot after paying a preconditioning price premium of $25.60/head result in $22.55 higher net return over non-preconditioned cattle for the average of 2014–2018 prices.
The summary statistics of the net returns for each of the three time periods are presented in Table 7.
Our current analyses do not consider a positive net return for the operator that sells preconditioned cattle, rather an expected breakeven net return for preconditioning cattle. The extent of the excess net return for the preconditioner depends on local market conditions, like market power of the feedlot over producers, information asymmetries, and the net benefits of performing metaphylaxis treatment on arrival to all incoming cattle. From the net benefits of metaphylaxis from Dennis et al. (Reference Dennis, Schroeder and Renter2020), even using a "lower-tier" antimicrobials treatment result in similar expected benefits than purchasing preconditioned animals in feedlots without paying a price premium. When a conservative price premium is paid, that allows preconditioners to have zero net returns from preconditioning, the net benefits of preconditioning fall below from that of metaphylactic treatment.
3.1. Premium Estimate Using Certainty Equivalent Analysis
Once the CDFs of the net returns per preconditioned and non-preconditioned animal at the feedlot are simulated from the PERT distribution estimations, we can calculate the CE of each net return distribution. Under a normality assumption, only the mean and variance of the net return distribution are needed to estimate the CE, as well as a value of r. Babcock et al. (Reference Babcock, Choi and Feinerman1993) provide a review of estimates of r. We use four scenarios of risk preference of the feedlot operator: 0, 0.01, 0.02, and 0.04. These represent risk neutrality, low, moderate, and high risk aversion. These estimations are the CDF estimates correspond to the average prices of 2014–2018. The mean and variance of the net returns of non-preconditioned cattle are −158.51 and 2911.28, respectively, while those from preconditioned cattle are −108.49 and 902.27, respectively. The estimated CE and price premium at different levels of risk aversion are shown in Table 8.
For a risk-neutral feedlot operator, the price premium willing to pay for preconditioned cattle is $50.02/head, essentially the difference of the expected net returns. This figure is higher than the of $25.60/head premium calculated in the stochastic dominance example, since that value represents an amount to cover the health protocol expenses of preconditioning and is not related to actual feedlot net benefits. As the risk aversion of the feedlot operator increases, the CE decreases (the utility from a random outcome decreases) and the price premium for preconditioned cattle increases, indicating a desire to decrease net revenue risk. At higher levels of risk aversion, for instance 0.04, the price premium for preconditioned cattle is $90.19/head.
Hilton and Olynk (Reference Hilton and Olynk2011) estimated the yearly preconditioning premium from years 1999 to 2009 in Indiana to range from −$3.51 to $11.34/cwt, with net return to preconditioning ranging from $26.04 to $116.48/head. Thrift and Thrift (Reference Thrift and Thrift2011) summarized the results from various studies and found that preconditioning price premia range between $1.40 and $6.12/cwt, but the net profit per head ranged from −$89.92 to $53.71. Qian (Reference Qian2014) estimated the preconditioning premium at cattle auctions in NY State to be $3.11/cwt. Lalman and Mourer (Reference Lalman and Mourer2014) found that VAC-45 certified cattle had a premium of $12.06/cwt in 2012 at the Superior Livestock Video Auctions. Schumacher, Schroeder, and Tonsor (Reference Schumacher, Schroeder and Tonsor2012) estimated that the value to feedlots in Kansas for cattle with a certified health program is between $6.98 to $11.97/cwt. Williams et al. (Reference Williams, Raper, DeVuyst, Peel and McKinney2012) estimated that The Oklahoma Quality Beef Network certification program adds $3.40 to $5.71/cwt in price premium. The benefits of preconditioning depend on market conditions as well as on its increase performance over non-preconditioned cattle and managerial practices of feedlot operators. Garber et al. (Reference Garber, Alwang, Norton and Bovay2022) conclude that even when preconditioning (Virginia Quality Assured certification) does not have a large price effect, it still has a positive effect on producer profitability.
4. Conclusion
We estimated the net return distribution of fed cattle under a preconditioning program and non-preconditioned cattle following a metaphylaxis treatment on arrival to the feedlot. We found that preconditioned cattle generate net returns of about $48.15/head to the feedlot over weaned cattle. This extra benefit to the feedlot represents the maximum amount that a feedlot is able to pay for preconditioned cattle, which translates to a maximum price premium of $7.79/cwt for a 618 lb animal. Our results indicate that introducing preconditioned cattle to a feedlot, with a price premium that generates nonnegative returns to cow-calf operators with preconditioning capacity, is the stochastic dominant strategy for feedlots. The use of preconditioning of cattle would also reduce the use of medically important antimicrobials in beef production, which has been estimated to be 2.5 thousand metric tons (USFDA, 2021).
The transfer of part of the maximum price premium back to the backgrounder is contingent on the preconditioning information available to feedlot managers, the cost of preconditioning, and the risk preferences of feedlot operators. If there is perfect information on the preconditioning status and performance of preconditioned animals across the beef value chain, we should expect all preconditioned animals to receive a price premium sufficiently high to incentivize preconditioning.
A caveat of this study is our assumption on the performance of preconditioned and non-preconditioned cattle at the feedlot. We assume perfect stochastic information in the system: health status and preconditioning benefits. More studies are required to have a better understanding of the feedlot performance; despite the current estimations available, there is much uncertainty in the outcome to help decision-makers.
Reliable certification programs or reputation of the backgrounder are ways to inform feedlot managers on the preconditioning status of the cattle. Performance may also vary by backgrounder and would have to be ascertained by feedlot production records. It is estimated that 25.9% of managers of feedlots with capacity of 8,000 head or more have pre-arrival processing information of the cattle all the time (USDA, 2013b).
Metaphylactic use of antibiotics on arrival conditional on Veterinarian approval is a low-cost strategy to feedlots, which may decrease the desirability for purchasing preconditioned cattle. The net return of metaphylactic use of antibiotics to the U.S. feeder industry is at least $532 million (Dennis et al., Reference Dennis, Schroeder, Renter and Pendell2018). The status quo does not allow market mechanisms to fully adopt preconditioning practices in the beef system. Further analysis on the net benefits of metaphylaxis on arrival versus preconditioning is needed to assess the sustainability of preconditioning programs in the US.
Author contributions
Conceptualization, L.J.V.C., L.W.T., and Y.T.G.; Methodology, L.J.V.C., L.W.T., K.K., G.L., and Y.T.G.; Formal Analysis, L.J.V.C.; Data Curation, L.J.V.C.; Writing—Original Draft, L.J.V.C. Writing—Review and Editing, L.W.T., and Y.T.G.; Supervision, L.W.T., and Y.T.G.; Funding Acquisition, L.W.T., and Y.T.G.
Financial support
This work was supported by the USDA, National Institute of Food and Agriculture, Agriculture and Food Research Initiative Competitive Grant no. 2016-68003-24607, and NIFA-USDA, NC-1206, NYC-121856, “Evaluating options to decrease antimicrobial use in cattle production.”
Conflict of interest
The authors report there are no competing interests to declare.
Data availability statement
The data that support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author, L. V., upon reasonable request.
Appendix A
PERT Distribution
PERT fitting are often used when only expert opinion about stochastic outcomes is available. The PERT distribution is similar to a triangular distribution, which is bounded (min and max) and unimodal. PERT distribution is parameterized by a minimum and maximum possible values, the mode (most likely value), and a shape parameter Lambda. PERT distributions are used when limited information is available to construct a distribution of a random variable. From Avent et al. (Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004), we used the minimum and maximum values as input of the estimated PERT distributions. The PERT mean was estimated from ${\rm mean}={\max+\min+{\rm mode*}\lambda \over (2+\lambda )}$ , and the PERT variance from $={(\max-\min-{\rm mode*}\lambda )(\max+{\rm mode*}\lambda -\min \left(1+\lambda \right)) \over \left(2+\lambda \right)^{2}(3+\lambda )}$ . We estimated the values of mode and λ such that our estimates of mean and var were similar to those reported by Avent et al. (Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004). As a reference, the mean and SD reported by Avent et al. (Reference Avent, Ward and Lalman2004) were as follows: ADG Prec., 2.94 (0.337); ADG Non-Prec. 2.57 (0.375); % Sick Prec., 9.235 (6.4); % Sick Non-Prec., 36.44 (18.64); % Dead Prec., 1.5 (0.816); and % Dead Non-Prec., 4.269 (1.886).
Net Returns to Feedlot by Purchasing Backgrounded Cattle Without Health Protocol
For completeness in our analysis, in addition to our net return estimations to the feedlot by purchasing preconditioned (backgrounded and a health protocol) and non-preconditioned (weaned calves), we also included the scenario of backgrounded calves without any health protocol sold to a feedlot. Because feedlot performance estimates are not available for each possible management scenario of calves produced by cow-calves operators, which is the objective of our study, we assumed that the feedlot performance estimate of backgrounded calves but without administered a preconditioning health protocol is the same as weaned calves at feedlot.
This management strategy generates higher income to the cow-calf operator in general due to the weight gain of the calves, but the net benefits to the feedlot are similar than purchasing weaned calves, depending on relative prices the difference in net returns may become larger. The following figure shows the CDF of the net returns per animal at the feedlot for the average prices of 2014–2018.
The mean and standard deviation of the net returns shown in Figure A1 are the following: non-preconditioned: −158.51, 53.95; non-preconditioned but backgrounded: −184.40, 50.44; and preconditioned: −108.49, 30.04.