Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T09:23:41.448Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Role of Marketing and Procurement Systems in the Control of Agriculture*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2015

V. James Rhodes*
Affiliation:
University of Missouri

Extract

Issues ancient and modern in the structural organization of agriculture are newly being legitimized. As one evidence, hundreds of extension meetings this winter will utilize a new set of leaflets entitled, “Who Will Control Agriculture?”. In popular articles, speeches, and research reports various aspects of the question are being examined. Even Secretary of Agriculture Earl Butz, himself an agricultural economist, has proclaimed the relevance of the subject, not to mention his chief economist, Don Paarlberg, who has addressed the same subject frequently.

Among these several sources the focus varies: optimal size of farm or feedlot; tax issues; the comparative advantage of the corporate and other forms of organization; economies of vertical coordination; the nature of contractual integration; and bargaining power for farmers and farm workers.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Southern Agricultural Economics Association 1973

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

Missouri Agricultural Experiment Station Journal Series No. 6840

References

[1]Ball, A. Gordon and Heady, Earl O., eds., Size, Structure and Future of Farms, Ames, Ia., Iowa State Univ. Press, 1972.Google Scholar
[2]Breimyer, Harold F., ed., Bargaining in Agriculture – Potentials and Pitfalls in Collective Action, North Central Regional Ext. Pub. 30, Univ. of Mo., June 1971.Google Scholar
[3]Butz, Earl L., “The Battle for Control,” Address to FS Services Annual Meeting, Chicago, Ill., Sept. 22, 1972.Google Scholar
[4]Collins, Norman R., “Changing Role of Price in Agricultural Marketing,Journal of Farm Economics, 41: 528534, Aug. 1959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[5]Dean, Gerald W. and Carter, Harold O., “Some Effects of Income Taxes on Large-Scale Agriculture,Journal of Farm Economics, 44: 745768, Aug. 1962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6]Dovring, Folke, “Variants and Invariants in Comparative Agricultural Systems,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 51: 12631273, Dec. 1969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7]Ginzel, J. A., Kehrberg, E. W. and Irwin, G. D., “The Middle Sized Farming Operation: A Goods-and-Services Firm?Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics, Volume 3, Number 1, pp. 123128, Dec. 1971.Google Scholar
[8]Guither, Harold, ed., Who Will Control U.S. Agriculture? North Central Regional Ext. Pub. 32-1 through 32-6. Univ. of Ill., March 1973.Google Scholar
[9]Harris, Marshall and Massey, Dean T., Vertical Coordination Via Contract Farming, USDA Misc. Pub. 1073, March 1968.Google Scholar
[10]Harrison, Virden L. and Fred Woods, W., “Nonfarm Investors and Beef Breeding Herds – Incentives and Consequences,Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics, Volume 4, Number 1, pp. 165170, July 1972.Google Scholar
[11]Henry, William R. and Seagraves, James A., “Economic Aspects of Broiler Production Density,Journal of Farm Economics, 42: 117, Feb. 1960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[12]Jesse, Edward and Aaron C., Johnson Jr., “An Analysis of Vegetable Contracts,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 52: 545554, Nov. 1970.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[13]Krause, Kenneth and Kyle, Leonard R., Midwestern Corn Farms: Economic Status and the Potential for Large and Family-Sized Units, USDA, ERS, Ag. Econ. Rep. 216, Nov. 1971.Google Scholar
[14]Madden, J. Patrick, Economies of Size in Farming, USDA, ERS Ag. Econ. Rep. 107, Feb. 1967.Google Scholar
[15]Manley, William T. and Reimund, Donn A., “Interrelations in Our Food System,USDA, ERS Marketing Economics Division paper at 1973 National Agricultural Outlook Conference, Feb. 21, 1973.Google Scholar
[16]McCarthy, E. Jerome, Basic Marketing: A Managerial Approach, Homewood, Illinois, R. D. Irwin, 4th edition, 1971, p. 19.Google Scholar
[17]Mighell, Ronald L. and Jones, Lawrence A., Vertical Coordination in Agriculture, USDA, ERS Ag. Econ. Rep. 19, Feb. 1963.Google Scholar
[18]National Commission on Food Marketing, Food From Farmer to Consumer and related Technical Studies, Washington, D.C., June 1966.Google Scholar
[19]Paarlberg, Don, “Farm Policy Implications and Alternatives,” USDA, paper at 1973 National Agricultural Outlook Conference, Feb. 21, 1973.Google Scholar
[20]Raup, Philip M., “Economies and Diseconomies of Large-Scale Agriculture,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 51: 12741283, Dec. 1969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[21]Raup, Philip M., “Corporate Farming in the United States,The Journal of Economic History, 33: 274290, March 1973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[22]Rogers, George B. and Voss, Leonard A., Readings on Egg Pricing, Univ. of Mo. College of Agriculture, Dec. 1971.Google Scholar
[23]Ruttan, Vernon W., Waldo, Arley D., and Houck, James P., eds., Agricultural Policy in an Affluent Society, New York, W. W. Norton, 1969 (Part Four includes four papers by Donald Turner, Don Paarlberg, Varden Fuller, and the National Advisory Commission on Food and Fiber).Google Scholar
[24]Singer, E. M., Anti-Trust Economics, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, Prentice-Hall, 1968, Ch. 18.Google Scholar
[25]Thompson, Donald N., ed., Contractual Marketing Systems, Lexington, Mass., Heath Lexington Books, 1971.Google Scholar
[26]Williamson, O. E., “The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations,” American Economic Review, 61: 112123, May 1971.Google Scholar