1 Introduction
During the past decade, benefit-cost analysis (BCA) has increasingly been used to evaluate criminal justice policies and programs. This growth has, in part, been “demand driven,” as cash-strapped states have turned to BCA to examine how they can most effectively spend their over-extended budgets. Between 2008 and 2011, the number of state governments conducting BCA increased from 25 to 37, and the number of studies produced by these states increased by 79%, from 62 to 111 (The Pew Charitable Trusts, 2013; White & VanLandingham, Reference White and VanLandingham2015).
Foundations and governments have also shown increased interest in criminal justice BCA. The Pew/MacArthur Results First Initiative, which works with states and counties to replicate the Washington State Cost–Benefit Model, was founded in 2011 through the Pew Charitable Trusts and the MacArthur Foundation, and the U.S. Department of Justice, Bureau of Justice Assistance funded the Vera Institute of Justice’s Cost Benefit Knowledge Bank for Criminal Justice between 2009 and 2013. Furthermore, the U.S. National Institute of Justice has been encouraging grant applicants to consider the use of BCA, sometimes giving preference to applications that use BCA (U.S. National Institute of Justice, 2013, 2016).
2 Benefit-Cost Analysis and Policing
The use of BCA to evaluate policing practices, however, has been scant, despite a decade-long effort to proliferate the use of criminal justice BCA. There is perhaps no better evidence of this gap than the limited number of policing studies in the expansive portfolio of justice BCA conducted by the Washington Institute for Public Policy (WSIPP). Only four of the 49 adult criminal justice investments examined by the WSIPP are for policing programs and policies, and none of the 30 juvenile justice investments they examined pertain to policing.Footnote 1
The paucity of BCA in policing is conspicuous considering the amount spent on policing in the United States. Nationwide, nearly as much money is spent on policing ($121 billion) as corrections ($81 billion) and the judiciary system ($55 billion) combined (U.S. Bureau of Justice Statistics, 2013). Furthermore, the relative merits and drawbacks of emerging policing technologies – such as body-worn and dashboard cameras, predictive policing software, computer-aided dispatch systems – and practices – such as proactive patrolling, and stop and frisk – are debated without any concrete data on the benefits and costs. Rather, based on our observations, decision-making seems to be generally shaped by the available budgetary resources, the police agency’s preference, procurement rules, and occasionally by anecdotal accounts of the costs and benefits.
When BCA of policing is formally conducted, frequently, the costs considered are limited strictly to the budgetary costs of implementation. A meta-analysis by Horowitz and Zedlewski (Reference Horowitz and Zedlewski2006) of all law enforcement evaluations commissioned by the National Institute of Justice between 1994 and 2004 found that less than one third of reported evaluations “contained the minimal data necessary to support cost-benefit analyses” (p. 55). A more recent meta-analysis of crime prevention programs by Welsh, Farrington and Gowar (Reference Welsh, Farrington and Gowar2015) concluded that “benefit-cost analysis continues to be underused in the study of crime prevention,” but that the quality of the analysis is rapidly improving (p. 448). Both of these reviews, however, highlight a narrow focus on costs, limiting them principally to operational expenses. This narrow focus is expanding in more recent cost-of-crime literature, with Donohue (Reference Donohue, Raphael and Stoll2009), for example, discussing but not estimating a broader set of social costs and benefits. This view must expand further, and especially into the cost side of the analysis.
3 The Social Costs of Policing
The lack of BCA in policing is not only strange; it is disconcerting. Policing has historically been analyzed by considering its benefits, placing the greatest weight on the welfare gains associated with the incapacitation of dangerous offenders and the deterrence of future criminal activity (Becker, Reference Becker1968; Shavell, Reference Shavell1987; Polinsky & Shavell, Reference Polinsky and Shavell2007). The major costs generally considered have primarily been the public budgetary expenditures (Polinsky & Shavell, Reference Polinsky and Shavell2007). While these benefits and costs are fundamental components to consider when determining the optimal level of any police practice, this perspective fails to take into account many significant costs of enforcement. First-order costs of policing refer to the costs incurred by the government should an individual be stopped, arrested, tried, and convicted for a crime; pretrial proceedings and prison expenses are included. First-order costs also include the costs incurred by innocent individuals who are stopped in traffic or on the street (Cohen Reference Cohen2017, this issue). Second-order costs, although more difficult to quantify, are equally important considerations. These types of costs include family instability, diminished job prospects, dignitary harms from wrongful incarceration, loss of income, and a host of other considerations that result from enforcement. These second-order costs accrue both directly to those ultimately arrested, tried, and convicted of a crime (e.g. diminished job prospects) and also to those who may never make direct contact with the police (e.g. family instability).
We provide two arguments for why arrest, incarceration, and second-order costs should be included in any BCA of policing. First, an analysis can be conducted from the point of view of at least three entities: (1) the police department, (2) the local government, or (3) society broadly defined. We argue that BCA from society’s perspective is the most appropriate for facilitating – only society’s perspective is conceptually valid. This perspective incorporates all costs of policing and provides the most complete picture of the consequences produced.Footnote 2
Second, inclusion of these costs helps to overcome the social planner’s dilemma inherent in policing. The process around policing decisions is normally quite one-sided, with tough-on-crime rhetoric being the consistent theme (Dripps, Reference Dripps1993; Stuntz, Reference Stuntz2001; Barkow, Reference Barkow2005; Friedman & Ponomarenko, Reference Friedman and Ponomarenko2015), although we should note that the discussion has been beginning to shift in the last few years (Bauer, Reference Bauer2014; Malcolm, Reference Malcolm2015). The problem with such an approach, however, is that it ignores the very real tangible and intangible costs of policing, especially to the minority population that is most impacted by its negative consequences. Not surprisingly, this group is often the most politically weak in a community, and has little opportunity to offset the inequities in discussions about policing (Harmon, Reference Harmon2015). Harmon (Reference Harmon2015), for example, states that because only a small percentage of the population is searched, arrested, or really has any interaction with the police, there is a “decoupling between the population that experiences the benefits of policing – which are widely distributed – and the population that pays its costs, which are concentrated on a smaller, politically weak minority, including criminal suspects” (p. 941). Incorporation of the arrest, incarceration, and collateral costs of a police practice, therefore, will provide a voice to those who have been excluded from decisions surrounding policing programs.
To begin the discussion on whether the arrest, incarceration, and other potential social costs should be included in a BCA on policing, we must first decide the point of view from which the BCA is being conducted. We argue that use of the perspective of the police department or local government is not a sufficient perspective for a BCA in policing. Instead, a BCA of policing should include all members of a society. “Society” does not necessarily mean the whole world. In many circumstances, it makes sense to conduct a BCA restricting society to all members of a neighborhood, city, town, state, or country. Instead, we are distinguishing the police department or local government’s parochial or budgetary interests from the interests of all individuals overseen by the police or government.
As agents of the state, police departments and governments have no intrinsic perspective.Footnote 3 To see this, we simply have to ask what the goals of the department (or the government) are for policing – chiefly, to identify and apprehend individuals guilty of committing crimes and to deter others from committing crimes. These objectives are imposed on the department and government because members of society incur substantial costs from crime and because society values prosecution for violating its laws, and wants to deter future crimes (Posner, Reference Posner1985; Alschuler, Reference Alschuler2003). Thus, the institutions only pursue such goals because society as a whole places great weight on them.
Conducting a BCA of policing from the perspective of all members of society, on the other hand, provides a more complete and objective picture of the full range of consequences of such a program, and allows society to make the most informed estimation of whether the police practice improves social welfare. Accordingly, a BCA should include not just the direct, financial costs incurred by the state for arrest and incarceration, but also the other social costs and benefits felt by an individual’s family, friends, and employer (“second-order effects”) Cohen (Reference Cohen2017). Removing a loving father from a family, for example, potentially eliminates a major source of stability and income, which may have long-term ramifications for his partner and children.Footnote 4
There is evidence of intergenerational punishment costs. Andersen and Wildeman (Reference Andersen and Wildeman2014) document the rise in foster care rates directly caused by parental incarceration, controlling for factors such as family finances or divorce. Parental incarceration hurts children’s health and school attendance (Geller, Cooper, Garfinkel, Schwartz-Soicher & Mincy, Reference Geller, Cooper, Garfinkel, Schwartz-Soicher and Mincy2012; Turney, Reference Turney2014; Porter & King, Reference Porter and King2015). Evidence exists that parental incarceration has led to increases in children’s future criminality, a direct long-term cost to society (Andersen, Reference Andersen2016).
There is also a substantial literature discussing the criminogenic nature of incarceration; that is, that the act of incarcerating itself causes an individual to commit more future crimes.Footnote 5 These costs, too, must be incorporated into a BCA, as they represent predictable expected costs to society. For example, suppose that there was a police department that developed technology to perfectly detect whether there were illegal drugs in someone’s car. If the punishment for drug possession is some incarceration, and we assume that the evidence of criminogenic effects is accurate, then an arrest and incarceration for drug possession today will produce more crimes per person in the future (Heaton, Mayson & Stevenson, Reference Heaton, Mayson and Stevenson2017). Therefore, a BCA of deploying this new technology should include the criminogenic effects as a cost of the program, and must be compared with the counterfactual effects of not arresting for illegal drugs but potentially only issuing a summons.Footnote 6 As discussed more extensively by Heaton et al. (Reference Heaton, Mayson and Stevenson2017), the BCA should be careful to present the uncertainty about long-term consequences to incarceration, but presenting uncertainty should not mean ignoring situations with any uncertainty.
In addition to the second-order effects felt by friends, family, and the employer, certain police practices have potentially enormous “third-order” effects to unrelated parties. Expansion of the use of a policing practice may impose psychological costs on members of society who have not directly interacted with the police themselves (Geller, Fagan, Tyler & Link, Reference Geller, Fagan, Tyler and Link2014). These psychological costs, in turn, reduce the legitimacy of the police force as a whole, which, in turn, reduces police efficiency (Cohen, Reference Cohen2017). Interestingly, as discussed more extensively by Geller (Reference Geller2017), these costs are not necessarily inherent to a police practice, but depend on how the police comport themselves. For example, a traffic stop may impose substantially different psychological costs depending on whether the officer is aggressive or calm during the interaction.
The outstanding question is whether we should include the second-order costs – such as loss of income and dignitary harms – experienced by the “rightfully” arrested and incarcerated individual himself (“first-order effects”). These costs are fundamentally different from the arrest and incarceration costs of those who are not guilty of any offense, of which there are many (Cohen, Reference Cohen2017),Footnote 7 and from the indirect costs felt by the rest of society, and as such, we see two main ways to think about them.
First, a straightforward application of rational agent economic theory would likely make a revealed preference argument that a criminal rationally weighs all of the costs and benefits to crime. The criminal incorporates all costs the individual may experience from committing the crime into his or her analysis and still decides that the potential benefits of crime outweigh the potential costs. Therefore, we can ignore the criminal’s expected costs because they are inherently balanced by the criminal’s expected benefit from committing the crime. Second, unlike all other costs being discussed, these costs could be understood as an intentional punishment for the crime committed. This punishment benefits society not just through a pursuit of justice, but as the mechanism of deterrence. Insofar as punishment acts as a deterrent, the costs incurred by the arrested individual should be included and ideally balanced by the benefit society derives from the deterrence (for a meta-analysis of the existing literature on deterrence, see Braga and Weisburd Reference Braga and Weisburd2011).
Aside from these questionable second-order costs, we think that the first-order costs to individuals who are not guilty of any offense should be included in a BCA of policing. Although it is difficult to pinpoint a precise approximation of how many individuals are wrongfully arrested and convicted every year, it is clear that these two events do occur, and with some frequency.Footnote 8 For example, Gross, O’Brien, Hu and Kennedy (Reference Gross, O’Brien, Hu and Kennedy2014) estimate that 4.1% of death sentences in the United States are a result of wrongful convictions. Because the arrest and incarceration of innocent individuals represents an undeserved punishment that is not countered by society’s desire for justice or deterrence, a BCA on a police practice should include these direct social costs of those wrongfully arrested and convicted. It would also be useful to include expected legal costs of wrongful arrest and incarceration, which can rise to millions of taxpayer dollars.Footnote 9
Ideally, every one of the above discussion’s costs and benefits should be estimated and included in any BCA of policing, but it is fundamentally infeasible to measure everything. The choice of what costs and benefits to include in a BCA must be made ex ante in anticipation of the potential magnitudes, and must be tailored to the specific policy in question. Difficulty of measurement, however, is no excuse. Incorporation of BCA in policing practices is essential to understanding, and improving, law enforcement in the United States. If we do not consider the totality of the consequences of a policing program, it is impossible to determine whether policing is actually doing what it is supposed to do – efficiently maximizing public safety and the welfare of society. Inclusion of both the benefits all members of society will receive by increased public safety as well as the direct and indirect costs that they will incur is the only way to provide useful information about what works and what does not when it comes to policing, and to find the best policy option out of the available alternatives.