Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-14T22:16:46.361Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Performing Public Credit at the Eighteenth-Century Bank of England

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 March 2019

Abstract

Much is known about the negotiation of personal credit relationships during the eighteenth century. It has been noted how direct contact and observation allowed individuals to assess the creditworthiness of those with whom they had financial connections and to whom they might lend money. Much less is known about one of the most important credit relationships of the long eighteenth century: that between the state and its creditors. This article shows that investors could experience the performance of public credit at the Bank of England. By 1760 the Bank was the manager of nearly three-quarters of the state's debt and housed the main secondary market in that debt. Thus, it provided a place for public creditors, both current and potential, to attend and scrutinize the performance of the state's promises. The article demonstrates how the Bank acted to embody public credit through its architecture, internal structures, and imagery and through the very visible actions of its clerks and the technologies that they used to record ownership and transfer of the national debt. The Bank of England, by those means, allowed creditors to interrogate the financial stability and reputation of the state in the same ways that they could interrogate the integrity of a private debtor.

Type
Original Manuscript
Copyright
Copyright © The North American Conference on British Studies 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 For example, see Anderson, B. L., “Money and the Structure of the Credit in the Eighteenth Century,” Business History 12, no. 2 (July 1970): 85101CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Finn, Margot, The Character of Credit: Personal Debt in English Culture, 1740–1914 (Cambridge, 2003)Google Scholar; Muldrew, Craig, The Economy of Obligation: The Culture of Credit and Social Relations in Early Modern England (London, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Paul, Tawny, “Credit, Reputation, and Masculinity in British Urban Commerce : Edinburgh, c. 1710–70,” Economic History Review 66, no. 1 (February 2013), 226–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Shepard, Alexandra, Accounting for Oneself: Worth, Status, and the Social Order in Early Modern England (Oxford, 2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. With regard to public credit, see Carey, Daniel and Finlay, Christopher J., The Empire of Credit: The Financial Revolution in the British Atlantic World (Dublin, 2011)Google Scholar; Cox, Gary W., Marketing Sovereign Promises: Monopoly Brokerage and the Growth of the English State (Cambridge, 2016)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dickson, P. G. M., The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit, 1688–1756 (London, 1967)Google Scholar; Stasavage, David, States of Credit: Size, Power, and the Development of European Polities (Princeton, 2011)Google Scholar.

2 Muldrew, Economy of Obligation; Finn, Character of Credit. For a detailed comparison of the two standpoints, see Tawny Paul, “Credit and Social Relations amongst Artisans and Tradesmen in Edinburgh and Philadelphia” (PhD diss., University of Edinburgh, 2011).

3 Defoe, Daniel, The Compleat English Tradesman (London, 1726), 119Google Scholar.

4 The True Briton, 26 July 1723, quoted in Hoppit, Julian, “Attitudes to Credit in Britain, 1680–1790,” Historical Journal 33, no. 2 (June 1990): 305–22, at 319CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 North, Douglas C. and Weingast, Barry R., “‘Constitutions and Commitment’: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England,” Journal of Economic History 49, no. 4 (December 1989): 803–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Clark, Gregory, “The Political Foundations of Modern Economic Growth: England, 1540–1800,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 26, no. 4 (April 1996): 563–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cox, Marketing Sovereign Promises; Murphy, Anne L., “Demanding Credible Commitment: Public Reactions to the Failures of the Early Financial Revolution,” Economic History Review 66, no. 1 (February 2013): 178–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sussman, Nathan and Yafeh, Yishay, “Institutional Reforms, Financial Development and Sovereign Debt: Britain, 1690–1790,” Journal of Economic History 66, no. 4 (December 2006): 906–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 The most comprehensive summary of these arguments can be found in Dincecco, Mark, Political Transformations and Public Finances: Europe, 1650–1913 (Cambridge, 2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A., Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (London, 2013)Google Scholar.

7 Binney, J. E. D., British Finance and Public Administration, 1774–1792 (Oxford, 1958)Google Scholar; Cooper, Richard, “William Pitt, Taxation and the Needs of War,” Journal of British Studies 22, no. 1 (October 1982): 94103CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dickson, Financial Revolution, 157–248.

8 Cooper, “William Pitt,” 95.

9 Brantlinger, Patrick, Fictions of State: Culture and Credit in Britain, 1694–1994 (Ithaca, 1996), 4849Google Scholar; Dickson, Financial Revolution in England.

10 Pocock, J. G. A., Virtue, Commerce and History: Essays on Political Thought and History, Chiefly in the Eighteenth Century (Cambridge, 1985), 112CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 Brantlinger, Fictions of State, 20.

12 Quoted in O'Brien, John F., “The Character of Credit: Defoe's ‘Lady Credit,’ The Fortunate Mistress, and the Resources of Inconsistency in Early Eighteenth-Century Britain,” English Language History 63, no. 3 (Fall 1996): 603631, at 612CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

13 O'Brien, “The Character of Credit,” 613.

14 Dickson, Financial Revolution, 249.

15 Dickson, 282, 301–2.

16 Macdonald, James, A Free Nation Deep in Debt: The Financial Roots of Democracy (Princeton, 2003), 471–72Google Scholar.

17 Mitchell, B. R. and Deane, Phyllis, Abstract of British Historical Statistics (Cambridge, 1962), 401–2Google Scholar.

18 Dickson, Financial Revolution, 285; Michie, Ranald, The Global Securities Market: A History (Oxford, 2006), 53CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

19 Amounts rounded to the nearest £1.

20 Defoe, Daniel, A Tour Thro’ the Whole Island of Great Britain, new ed. (1968; repr. London, 1724), 338Google Scholar.

21 A Letter to a Friend concerning Credit, and how it may be restor'd to the Bank of England (London, 1697), 1Google Scholar.

22 Backscheider, Paula R., “Defoe's Lady Credit,” Huntington Library Quarterly 44, no. 2 (Spring 1981): 89100, at 96CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

23 Quoted in Clapham, J. H., The Bank of England: A History, 2 vols. (Cambridge, 1966), 1:181Google Scholar.

24 Broz, J. Lawrence and Grossman, Richard S., “Paying for Privilege: The Political Economy of Bank of England Charters, 1694–1844,” Explorations in Economic History 41, no. 1 (January 2004): 4872CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 Roxburgh, Natalie, Representing Public Credit: Credible Commitment, Fiction and the Rise of the Fictional Subject (London, 2016), 41Google Scholar.

26 Bank of England Archive (hereafter BEA), M5/213, Minutes of the Committee of Inspection, fols. 178–79.

27 Paul, “Credit and Social Relations,” 250.

28 Finn, Character of Credit, 21.

29 Paul, “Credit and Social Relations,” 136.

30 Hudson, Pat, “Correspondence and Commitment: British Traders” Letters in the Long Eighteenth Century,” Cultural and Social History 11, no. 4 (December 2014): 527–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

31 Hudson, “Correspondence and Commitment,” 535–37.

32 Daniel Defoe, quoted in Abramson, Daniel M., Building the Bank of England: Money, Architecture, Society, 1694–1942 (New Haven, 2004), 9Google Scholar.

33 Abramson, Building the Bank of England, 34.

34 Abramson, 34.

35 Abramson, 54.

36 Walter, Ryan, “The Economy and Pocock's Political Economy,” History of European Ideas 34, no. 3 (September 2008): 334–44, at 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

37 Fielding, John, A Brief Description of the Cities of London and Westminster (London, 1776), 3Google Scholar.

38 North and Weingast, “Constitutions and Commitment.”

39 Abramson, Building the Bank, 57.

40 See, for example, The Ambulator; or the Stranger's Companion in a tour round London (London, 1774), ixGoogle Scholar; Malton, Thomas, A Picturesque Tour through the Cities of London and Westminster (London, 1792–1801)Google Scholar.

41 Malton, Picturesque Tour, 76.

42 Quoted in Booker, John, Temples of Mammon: The Architecture of Banking (Edinburgh, 1990), 5Google Scholar.

43 Black, Iain S., “Spaces of Capital: Bank Office Building in the City of London, 1830–1870,” Journal of Historical Geography 26, no. 3 (July 2000): 351–75, at 357CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

44 For example, see BEA, G4/23, fol. 167.

45 Acres, W. Marston, The Bank of England from Within, 2 vols. (London, 1931), 1:191Google Scholar.

46 Quoted in Clare Walcot, “Figuring Finance: London's New Financial World and the Iconography of Speculation, circa 1689–1763” (PhD diss., University of Warwick, 2003), 103.

47 Defoe, Daniel, A Tour thro the Whole Island of Great Britain (London, 1724), 135Google Scholar, quoted in Walcot, “Figuring Finance,” 88.

48 North, Roger, Of Building (London [1695–96?])Google Scholar, quoted in Walcot, “Figuring Finance,” 93.

49 BEA, M6/19, Memorandum on the introduction of the King's Guard.

50 Abramson, Building the Bank, 86.

51 Mortimer, Thomas, Every Man His Own Broker, or a Guide to Exchange Alley (London, 1785), 133Google Scholar.

52 The Bank of England's Vade Mecum: Or Sure Guide (London, 1782).

53 BEA, M5/607, Old Book, Orders for Porters, fols. 6–7.

54 Quoted in Roxburgh, Representing Public Credit, 87.

55 Abramson, Building the Bank, 11.

56 Murphy, Anne L., “Learning the Business of Banking: The Recruitment and Training of the Bank of England's First Tellers,” Business History 52, no. 1 (February 2010): 150–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Giuseppi, John, Bank of England: A History from Its Foundation in 1694 (London, 1966), 56Google Scholar; Kynaston, David, The City of London, vol. 1, A World of Its Own (London, 1995), 30Google Scholar.

57 Bowen, H. V., The Business of Empire: The East India Company and Imperial Britain, 1756–1833 (Cambridge, 2006), 139Google Scholar; Boot, H. M., “Real Incomes of the British Middle Class, 1760–1850: The Experience of Clerks at the East India Company,” Economic History Review 52, no. 4 (November 1999): 638–68, at 639CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The East India Company employed a total staff of more than seventeen hundred, if warehouse laborers and dock workers are included in the count. Supple, Barry, The Royal Exchange Assurance: A History of British Insurance, 1720–1970 (Cambridge, 1970), 70Google Scholar.

58 BEA, M5/213. Mortimer also explains the process in his Every Man His Own Broker, 137–45.

59 BEA, M5/213, fols. 60–61.

60 BEA, M5/212, Minutes of the Committee of Inspection; BEA M5/213.

61 Defoe, A Tour Thro’ the Whole Island of Great Britain, 342.

62 Cobbett, William, ed., The Parliamentary History of England, from the Earliest Times to the Year 1803, 36 vols. (London, 1806–20), 22:517–20Google Scholar.

63 The Kentish Companion: Or useful Memorandum and Accompt Book (Canterbury, 1775), 8Google Scholar.

64 BEA, M5/212; M5/213.

65 BEA, M5/213, fol. 61.

66 I am indebted to Natalie Roxburgh for discussions about the transparency of the functions of the Bank of England, especially bookkeeping, and their value in demonstrating the integrity of public credit. Natalie Roxburgh, “The Rise of Public Credit and the Eighteenth-Century English Novel” (PhD diss., Rutgers University, 2011).

67 BEA, M5/213, fol. 68.

68 Roxburgh, Representing Public Credit, 91.

69 BEA, AC4/5, An outline of the history and working of the inscribed stock system, fol. 2.

70 BEA, AC$/5, fol. 3. So efficient was this system that it remained in place until the late nineteenth century.

71 BEA, M5/213, fol. 32.

72 BEA, M5/212, fol. 148.

73 BEA, M5/213, fol. 23.

74 Acres, Bank from Within, 132.

75 Acres, 133.

76 Acres, 179.

77 Defoe, Compleat English Tradesman, 324.

78 Major, Emma, Madam Britannia: Women, Church, and Nation, 1712–1812 (Oxford, 2012), 1Google Scholar.

79 Abramson, Building the Bank, 54.

80 Cited in Mulcaire, T., “Public Credit: Or the Feminization of Virtue in the Marketplace,” PMLA 114, no. 5 (October 1999): 1029–42, at 1031CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

81 Mulcaire, “Public Credit,” 1033.

82 Sherman, Sandra, Finance and Fictionality in the Early Eighteenth Century: Accounting for Defoe (Cambridge, 1996), 157CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

83 The South-Sea Scheme Detected (London, 1720)Google Scholar quoted in Sherman, Finance and Fictionality, 53.

84 Quoted in Walcot, “Figuring Finance,” 82.

85 Quoted in Walcot, 82.

86 North and Weingast, “Constitutions and Commitment.”

87 Dome, Takuo, The Political Economy of Public Finance in Britain, 1767–1873 (Abingdon, 2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

88 Reitan, Earl A., Politics, Finance, and the People: Economical Reform in England in the Age of the American Revolution, 1770–92 (Basingstoke, 2007), 134CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

89 Dickson, Financial Revolution, 228–41.

90 Dickson, 157–98.

91 Hoppit, Julian, “Compulsion, Compensation and Property Rights in Britain, 1688–1833,” Past and Present, no. 210 (February 2011): 93128, at 125CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

92 Cope, S. R., “The Stock Exchange Revisited: A New Look at the Market in Securities in London in the Eighteenth Century,” Economica 45, no. 177 (February 1978): 121, at 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

93 Abramson, Building the Bank, 70.

94 Quoted in Abramson, 70.

95 BEA, M5/607, fols. 2–3.

96 BEA, M5/213, fol. 120.

97 BEA, M5/213, fol. 120.

98 Trial of John Davis (T17831029-41), 29 October 1783, Old Bailey Proceedings Online, https://www.oldbaileyonline.org/browse.jsp?div=t17831029-41 access date 27 December 2018.

99 Borsay, Peter, “A Room with a View: Visualising the Seaside, c. 1750–1914,” Transactions of the Royal Historical Society 23 (December 2013): 175201, at 181CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

100 Abramson, Building the Bank.

101 Abramson, 74.

102 Leemans, Inger, “Verse Weavers and Paper Traders: Financial Speculation in Dutch Theater,” in The Great Mirror of Folly: Finance, Culture and the Crash of 1720, ed. Goetzmann, William N. et al. (New Haven, 2013), 182Google Scholar.

103 Defoe, Daniel, The Anatomy of Exchange Alley: or, a System of Stock-Jobbing (London, 1719), 23Google Scholar.

104 Mortimer, Every Man His Own Broker, 122.

105 BEA, M5/607, Order Books for Porters, fols. 2–3.

106 BEA, M5/213, fol. 64.

107 Ibid, fols. 154, 173.

108 Ibid, fols. 67, 84–85.

109 Ibid, fol. 96.

110 BEA M5/451, Samuel Beachcroft Governor's diary, 1775–1777, fol. 76.

111 Carlos, A. M. and Neal, L., “The Micro-Foundations of the Early London Capital Market: Bank of England Shareholders during and after the South Sea Bubble, 1720–25,” Economic History Review 59, no. 3 (August 2006): 498538CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Murphy, Anne L., “Demanding ‘Credible Commitment’: Public Reactions to the Failures of the Early Financial Revolution,” Economic History Review 66, no. 1 (February 2013): 178–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

112 Reasons Humbly Offered to the Members of the Honourable House of Commons (London, [1756?]) quoted in Banner, Stuart, Anglo-American Securities Regulation: Cultural and Political Roots, 1690–1860 (Cambridge, 1998), 97CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Some Considerations on Public Credit and the Nature of Its Circulation (London, 1733)Google Scholar quoted in Banner, Anglo-American Securities Regulation, 103.

113 Pocock, Virtue, Commerce and History, 112.