Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-fscjk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T07:48:17.521Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Japan's New Regionalism: The Politics of Free Trade Talks with Mexico

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 March 2016

Extract

Since late 1998, Japan reversed its exclusive support for the multilateral trade regime and endorsed for the first time bilateral and preferential trade pacts, signing one with Singapore, negotiating another with Mexico, and announcing free trade talks with South Korea. The newfound Japanese interest in pursuing free trade agreements (FTAs) therefore represents one of the most significant departures in Japanese trade diplomacy of the past half-century. This article seeks to explain the birth of a preferential trading policy in a country that until recently had been a staunch multilateralist, and to analyze the reasons for the launch of FTA negotiations between Japan and Mexico. Indeed, one of the most remarkable aspects of Japan's new trade bilateralism is its cross-regional orientation, seeking preferential trade with a Latin American nation. Trade negotiations with Mexico are of great consequence to the development of Japan's FTA strategy for one more reason. Japan has embarked on this new regionalism to offset the negative effects of competing FTAs, but at the same time it has tried to minimize agricultural concessions to bilateral trade partners. Mexico is the first large agricultural exporter that Japan has approached for trade negotiations and is therefore an important test for the success of the Japanese FTA strategy.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © East Asia Institute 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Notes

I greatly benefited from the feedback offered by Ellis Krauss, Ed Lincoln, and Saadia Pekkanen to different versions of this work. Moreover, I was fortunate to receive exceptionally insightful and thorough comments from two anonymous reviewers. I am of course responsible for all remaining errors.Google Scholar

1. Panagariya, Arvind, Regionalism in Trade Policy: Essays on Preferential Trading (Singapore: World Scientific, 1999). Bhagwatti, Jagdish, “Regionalism and Multilateralism: An Overview,” in de Melo, Jaime and Panagariya, Arvind, eds., New Dimensions in Regional Integration (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993).Google Scholar

2. Ravenhill, John, “Competing Logics of Regionalism in the Asia-Pacific,” Journal of European Integration 18 (1995): 179199. Hatch, Walter and Yamamura, Kozo, Asia in Japan's Embrace: Building a Regional Production Alliance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).Google Scholar

3. Higgot, Richard and Stubbs, Richard, “Competing Conceptions of Economic Regionalism: APEC Versus EAEC in the Asia Pacific,” Review of International Political Economy 2, No. 3 1995): 516535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4. Section “Super 301” of the U.S. Trade Act allows the government to unilaterally impose retaliatory tariffs if it deems that a foreign country is engaging in unfair trading practices. Japan has been a frequent object of 301 investigations in products ranging from oranges to photographic film to auto parts. The United States has identified several structural barriers that hinder the access of U.S. products and firms. Examples of such barriers include the distribution system, collusive business practices, government procurement policies, and so on. For a good overview of U.S.-Japan trade negotiations on these matters see Schoppa, Len, Bargaining with Japan: What American Pressure Can and Cannot Do (New York: Columbia University Press, 1997).Google Scholar

5. Improvements of the dispute settlement mechanism include coverage and automaticity. In other words the dispute settlement machinery applies to all components of the WTO agreement, a fixed calendar for the dispute settlement process has been created to avoid excessive delays in the rulings, and the possibility of a single member vetoing the entire process has been eliminated since the consensus formula has been reversed and now all members would have to agree to stop the implementation of a panel ruling (including the complainant, which is of course a highly unlikely event). Pekkanen, Saadia M., “Sword and Shield: The WTO Dispute Settlement System and Japan,” in Schaede, Ulrike and Grimes, William, eds., Japan's Managed Globalization in the 21st Century (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 2002), pp. 79.Google Scholar

6. Krauss, Ellis S., “The U.S., Japan, and Trade Liberalization: From Bilateralism to Regional Multilateralism to Regionalism +,” paper presented at the conference titled “After the Cold War and Globalization: Changes in the Japanese International Political Economy,” Institute of Social Sciences, University of Tokyo, 2000.Google Scholar

7. In January 2001 MITI changed its name to Ministry of Economy, Trade, and Industry (METI).Google Scholar

8. In 1986, the United States and Japan signed a semiconductor agreement that for the first time specifically mentioned a 20 percent market share in Japan for U.S. companies to be achieved by the year 1991. Soon after signing the agreement, however, bitter disagreement ensued as to whether this specific figure represented a guarantee (the U.S. position) or merely a desirable target (the Japanese interpretation).Google Scholar

9. Ravenhill, John, APEC and the Construction of Pacific Rim Regionalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001), pp. 8485.Google Scholar

10. Krauss, , “The U.S., Japan, and Trade Liberalization,” pp. 16, 20, 30.Google Scholar

11. As Krauss reminds us, the current FTA policy is not a complete break from the past. There are important continuities in the preferences of Japanese policymakers (the desire to preserve the relationship with the United States, support the global trading system, and play a leadership role in Asia). My argument, however, is that the embrace of preferential trading does represent in other ways a major departure since discriminatory liberalization is a first for Japan, as well as the experimentation with shallow or deep integration with selected trading partners. Krauss, Ellis S., “The U.S. and Japan in APEC's EVSL Negotiations: Regional Multilateralism and Trade,” in Krauss, Ellis S. and Pempel, T. J., eds., Beyond Bilateralism: The U.S.-Japan Relationship in the New Asia-Pacific (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, forthcoming).Google Scholar

12. Scollay, Robert and Gilbert, John P., New Regional Trading Arrangements in the Asia Pacific? (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 2001), pp. 34.Google Scholar

13. Munetaka, Naoko, “Evolution of Japan's Policy Toward Economic Integration,” Working Paper, Center for Northeast Asian Policy Studies, Brookings Institution, 2001, pp. 67, 11.Google Scholar

14. Hook, Glenn, “Japan's Role in the East Asian Political Economy: From Crisis to Bloc?Asian Business and Management 1 (2002): 32.Google Scholar

15. Krauss, , “The U.S. and Japan in APEC's EVSL Negotiations,” p. 6.Google Scholar

16. Ibid., pp. 911.Google Scholar

17. AFR, November 2, 1998, quoted in Ravenhill, APEC and the Construction of Pacific Rim Regionalism, p. 103.Google Scholar

18. Krauss, , “The U.S. and Japan in APEC's EVSL Negotiations,” p. 22.Google Scholar

19. Ravenhill, , APEC and the Construction of Pacific Rim Regionalism, pp. 93103.Google Scholar

20. It is important to note that the trade-diversion effects vary in each individual economic bloc. Examples of discriminatory FTAs are those that embrace complex rules of origin specifically designed to keep foreign producers out of the regional market, or that shield uncompetitive sectors from the liberalization process.Google Scholar

21. Baldwin, Richard E., “The Causes of Regionalism,” World Economy 20, No. 7 1997): 865888.Google Scholar

22. Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanan, “The Politics of Free-Trade Agreements,” in Bhagwati, Jagdish, Krishna, Pravin, and Panagariya, Arvind, eds., Trading Blocs: Alternative Approaches to Analyzing Preferential Trade Agreements (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1999).Google Scholar

23. Keidanren, , “Urgent Call for Active Promotion of Free Trade Agreements. Toward a New Dimension in Trade Policy,” http://www.keidanren.or.jp/english/policy/2000/033/proposal.html (2000), pp. 23.Google Scholar

24. Ibid., pp. 3, 9.Google Scholar

25. Ibid., p. 6.Google Scholar

26. “Dumping” refers to the predatory practice of selling goods in the international market for below the domestic price or normal value with the aim of driving competitors out of business. The GATT and now the WTO have authorized members to impose higher duties when cases of dumping are confirmed. However, antidumping cases are very controversial because it is not easy always to determine objectively the normal value of a good, and because national dumping laws can exhibit a bias against foreign producers. The concern that antidumping proceedings have been captured by protectionist interests is widespread among trade experts. See Palmetter, David, “A Commentary on the WTO Anti-Dumping Code,” Journal of World Trade 30, No. 4 August 1996): 4369.Google Scholar

27. Pekkanen, Saadia, “At Play in the Legal Realm: The WTO and the Changing Nature of U.S.-Japanese Antidumping Disputes,” in Krauss, Ellis S. and Pempel, T. J., eds., Beyond Bilateralism: The U.S.-Japan Relationship in the New Asia-Pacific (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, forthcoming).Google Scholar

28. I am thankful to Saadia Pekkanen for pointing this out to me.Google Scholar

29. MITI, “MITI List of Major Concerns Raised by the 2000 Report on WTO Consistency of Trade Policies,” http://www.meti.go.jp/english/report/data/gCT0004e.html (2000).Google Scholar

30. Keidanren, , “Urgent Call for Active Promotion of Free Trade Agreements,” p. 6.Google Scholar

31. Ravenhill, , APEC and the Construction of Pacific Rim Regionalism, pp. 2829.Google Scholar

32. Krauss, , “The U.S., Japan, and Trade Liberalization”; Munetaka, , “Evolution of Japan's Policy Toward Economic Integration.” Google Scholar

33. Munetaka, Naoko, “How Trade Agreements Can Reform Japan,” The Globalist http://www.theglobalist.com/DBWeb/StoryId.aspx?StoryId=2560 (2002); Hiranuma, Noboru, “Japan's New Regional Trade Policy—Which Country Comes Next After Singapore?” http://www.iie.com/papers/hatakeyama0302.html (2002), p. 5.Google Scholar

34. Munetaka, , “How Trade Agreements Can Reform Japan,” p. 3.Google Scholar

35. The insightful observations of the two anonymous reviewers and of Ed Lincoln greatly influenced my thinking on this matter.Google Scholar

36. Stiglitz, Joseph E., Globalization and Its Discontents (New York: W. W. Norton, 2002).Google Scholar

37. Okita, Yoichi, “Japan Needs More Free Trade Agreements.” Glocom Platform, http://www.glocom.org/opinions/essays/200203_okita_japan/ (2002).Google Scholar

38. Keidanren, , “Urgent Call for Active Promotion of Free Trade Agreements,” p. 5.Google Scholar

39. Rajan, Ramkishen S. and Sen, Rahul, “The Japan-Singapore ‘New Age’ Economic Partnership Agreement: Background, Motivation, and Implications,” Discussion Paper no. 0208, Centre for International Economic Studies, Adelaide University, March 2002, pp. 89.Google Scholar

40. Japan-Mexico Joint Study Group on the Strengthening of Bilateral Economic Relations, “Final Report,” www.mofa.go.jp/region/Iatin/mexico/relation0207 (2002).Google Scholar

41. It is important to acknowledge that the specific mix of motives for the selection of each individual FTA partner is different. For example, there are political and security considerations in negotiating with Korea that are not present in other Japanese bilateral trade negotiations. Given that Korea itself has recently embraced preferential trading, an FTA affords both countries the opportunity to improve diplomatic relations, and to further involve Japan in the peninsula at a time of high uncertainty due to the reactivation of North Korea's nuclear program.Google Scholar

42. Mattli, Walter, The Logic of Regional Integration: Europe and Beyond (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999). Baldwin, , “The Causes of Regionalism.” Google Scholar

43. Solís, Mireya, “Sharing the Spoils of Economic Integration? Japanese Direct Investment in North America,” in Whiting, Van R. Jr., ed., Regionalization in the World Economy: NAFTA, the Americas, and Asia Pacific (Delhi: Macmillan India, 1996), p. 29. Toru Yanagihara and Koji Serita, “Strengthening Japanese-Mexican Ties Through FDI,” manuscript, 1996, p. 17.Google Scholar

44. Japanese Embassy in Mexico, JETRO, and Japanese Chamber of Commerce and Industry in Mexico, 7998 Mekishiko Nikkei Kigyô Shinshutsu Ichiran [A glance at Japanese companies in Mexico], 1998, p. ii.Google Scholar

45. These observations notwithstanding, it is important to note that FDI data underestimate the real scale of Japanese investment in Mexico. A significant amount of Japanese investment takes place through the U.S. subsidiaries of Japanese companies and, therefore, is registered as U.S. investment. The latest survey of Japanese firms in Mexico shows that 35 percent of their capital was supplied by the U.S. subsidiary of a Japanese company. In the case of maquiladoras the weight of U.S. subsidiaries is even greater: they provided 63 percent of the capital of the company established in Mexico. Ibid., p. iv.Google Scholar

46. With rollup, a component's origin is attributed to the country of majority content, so that a part with 51 percent of U.S. content is considered 100 percent American when it crosses the Canadian border, for example. De Remes, Alain, Fitzpatrick, Timothy, and Ortiz, Antonio. “NAFTA and the Automotive Industry,” in Whiting, Van R. Jr., ed., Regionalization in the World Economy, p. 125.Google Scholar

47. Magnusson, Paul and Treece, James B., “Honda: Is It an American Car?Business Week (November 18, 1991), p. 112.Google Scholar

48. Fujita, Masahisa and Ishii, Ryoichi, “Global Location Behavior and Organization Dynamics of Japanese Electronics and Their Impact on Regional Economies,” Discussion Paper Series no. 423, Kyoto Institute of Economic Research, 1995, p. 234.Google Scholar

49. Interview by the author with managers from JVC Industrial de Mexico, Tijuana, November 1996.Google Scholar

50. Solís, , “Sharing the Spoils of Economic Integration?” p. 210.Google Scholar

51. Mexico now exempts the payment of the lower of two import duties: the one paid for the import of inputs into Mexico, and the one paid for the import of the final product in the United States. For example, if the tariff in Mexico for the import of component X is 9 percent and the tariff on the import of the final product Y in the United States is 2 percent, the tariff to be paid in Mexico is 7 percent.Google Scholar

52. The “twin plant system” refers to the practice among some Japanese companies of operating plants on both sides of the U.S.-Mexico border that closely coordinate their production strategies.Google Scholar

53. Keidanren, , “Report on the Possible Effects of a Japan-Mexico Free Trade Agreement on Japanese Industry,” http://www.keidanren.or.jp/english/policy/pol099.html (1999), p. 6.Google Scholar

54. JETRO, “Report of the Committee for Closer Economic Relations Between Japan and Mexico,” http:www.jetro.org.mx/JetroMXJPFTAFullEng.doc (1999). Solís, Mireya, “Mexico and Japan: The Opportunities of Free Trade,” report commissioned by Mexico's Ministry of Trade and Industry, http:www.economia-snci.gob.mx/sphp_pages/publicaciones/mexjapesp.pdf (1999).Google Scholar

55. Solís, , “Mexico and Japan.Google Scholar

56. Ibid.Google Scholar

57. In addition to NAFTA, Mexico has signed trade agreements with numerous Latin American countries: Chile, (1992), Venezuela, and Colombia, (1995), Rica, Costa (1995), Bolivia, (1995), Nicaragua, (1998), El Salvador, , and Guatemala, and Honduras, (2001). Outside the continent, Mexico has an FTA with the European Union and one with Israel (both became effective in 2000).Google Scholar

58. Japan International Cooperation Agency (JICA), “Master Plan for Promotion of Supporting Industries in Mexico” (JICA internal document, 1996), pp. 2, 49.Google Scholar

59. JETRO, “Report of the Committee for Closer Economic Relations Between Japan and Mexico,” p. 22.Google Scholar

60. In the 1990s, these bilateral investment treaties greatly proliferated as developing countries sought to promote foreign investment into their economies. Although there is a great deal of variation in the hundreds of BITs signed to date, some of the most noteworthy components include the most-favored-nation and national-treatment principles (i.e., that multinational corporations [MNCs] from a nation party to the BIT will not suffer discrimination vis-à-vis other multinationals or domestic enterprises); elimination of some performance requirements previously imposed by the host government on MNCs; the principle of prompt and adequate compensation in case of nationalization; and MNC access to international arbitration panels in case of a dispute with the host government. Graham, Edward M., Fighting the Wrong Enemy: Antiglobal Activists and Multinational Enterprises (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 2000).Google Scholar

61. Interview with officials from Mexico's Ministry of the Economy, Mexico City, June 2002.Google Scholar

62. Japan-Mexico Joint Study Group, “Final Report,” p. 14.Google Scholar

63. The Japanese business community has some novel ideas on rules of origin for trade in parts. It is widely understood that a Japan-Mexico FTA would not completely solve the problem for Japanese enterprises that import substantial amounts of components from Asia and other third countries. Therefore, Keidanren has circulated the idea that rules of origin in a Japan-Mexico FTA should allow parts made in Asia with some value added in Japan to enjoy zero tariff concessions in Mexico. Whether Mexico will agree or not to such rules is not clear yet. Keidanren, , “Report on the Possible Effects of a Japan-Mexico Free Trade Agreement on Japanese Industry,” p. 9.Google Scholar

64. Keep in mind that NAFTA's investment chapter is unprecedented: For the first time Mexico allowed foreign investment disputes to be heard in binding international arbitration panels (and not in national courts); and it grants for the first time private foreign investors legal standing in that they can directly initiate a dispute settlement proceeding when they believe host state policy is in violation of the NAFTA treaty.Google Scholar

65. Japan-Mexico Joint Study Group, “Final Report,” pp. 18, 22.Google Scholar