Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T19:21:35.854Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Banking on the King: The Evolution of the Royal Revenue Farms in Old Regime France

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 November 2006

Noel D. Johnson
Affiliation:
Assistant Professor, Economics Department, California State University, 1250 Bellflower Blvd., Long Beach, CA 90840-4607. E-mail: njohnso3@csulb.edu.

Abstract

The writing and allocation of French tax farm contracts changed dramatically after the Fronde (1648–1653): they were gradually transformed from small, competitively auctioned, units into a large cartel known as the Company of General Farms. Surprisingly, the crown's revenues increased. I present a transaction cost argument to explain the behavior of tax farm lease prices as tax farming changed during the seventeenth century. Cartelization of tax farms lowered costs faced by the crown. The tax farm system's evolution offers insights into how organizations evolve to protect their property rights in the absence of well functioning representative institutions.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2006 The Economic History Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bayard Françoise. 1988. Le Monde des Financiers au xvii siècle. Paris: Flamarrion.
Bayard Françoise and Philippe Guignet. 1991. L’économie française aux XVI, XVII et XVIII siècles. Gap, France: Ophrys.
Bien David. 1987. “Offices, Corps, and a System of State Credit: The Use of Privilege under the Ancien Regime.” In The French Revolution and the Creation of Modern Political Cutlure, edited by Keith Baker, vol. 1, 89114. Oxford: Pergamon Press.
Bonney R. J. (1979): “The Failure of the French Revenue Farms, 1600–60.” Economic History Review 32, no. 1 1132.Google Scholar
Brewer John. 1989. The Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English State, 1688–1783. London: Unwin Hyman.
Briggs Robin. 1998. Early Modern France, 1560–1715. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Clamageran Jean Jules. 1867. Histoire de l’impôt en France. Paris: Guillaumin et cie.
Colbert Jean Baptiste. 1861–70. Lettres, instructions et mémoires de Colbert, publiés d’après les ordres de l’empereur, sur la proposition de Son Excellence M. Magne, ministre secrétaire d’état des finances, vol. 2. Paris: Imprimerie impériale.
Cole Charles Woolsey. 1939. Colbert and a Century of French Mercantilism. New York: Columbia University Press.
Dessert Daniel. (1975): “Finances et société au xxi siècle: à propos de la chambre de justice de 1661.” Annales ECS 29, 84781.Google Scholar
Dessert Daniel. 1984. Argent, pouvoir et société au Grand Siècle. Paris: Fayard.
Dessert Daniel, and J. L. Journet. (1975): “Le Lobby Colbert: Un Royaume, ou une affaire de famille?.” Annales ECS 30 130336.Google Scholar
Durand Yves. 1971. Les fermiers généraux au XVIII siècle. Paris: Presses universitaires de France.
Ferguson Niall. 2001. The Cash Nexus: Money and Power in the Modern World, 1700–2000. New York: Basic Books.
Forbonnais François Véron Duverger de. 1758. Recherches et considérations sur les finances de France. Basle: Frères Cramer.
France. Archives Nationales de France, KK335.
Goldberg Victor P. (1990): “Aversion to Risk Aversion in the New Institutional Economics.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146, no. 1 21622.Google Scholar
Goubert Pierre. 1960. Beauvais et le Beauvaisis de 1600 à 1730. Paris: S.E.V.P.E.N.
Greif Avner, Paul Milgrom, and Barry R. Weingast. (1994) “Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild.” Journal of Political Economy 102, no. 4: 74576.Google Scholar
Heumann P. 1938. “Un traitant sous Louis XIII: Antoine Feydeau.” In Études sur l’histoire administrative et sociale de l’ancien régime, edited by George Pagès, 18589. Paris: Librairie Félix Alcan.
Hoffman Philip T.Taxes and Agrarian Life in Early Modern France: Land Sales, 1550–1730.” This Journal 46, no. 1 (1986): 3755.Google Scholar
Hoffman Philip T.. 1996. Growth in a Traditional Society: the French Countryside, 1450–1815. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Johnson Noel D. (2006): “The Cost of Credibility: The Company of General Farms and Fiscal Stagnation in Eighteenth Century France.” Essays in Economic and Business History 24 1628.Google Scholar
Jourdan Decrusy, Isambert Armet, and A. H. Taillandier. 1822. Recueil général des anciennes lois françaises, depuis l’an 420 jusqu’à la révolution de 1789. Paris: Belin-Le-Prieur Verdiere.
Kaiser Thomas. (1991): “Money, Despotism, and Public Opinion in Early Eighteenth-Century France: John Law and the Debate on Royal Credit.” The Journal of Modern History 63, no. 1 128.Google Scholar
Krishna Vijay. 2002. Auction Theory. San Diego, CA: Academic Press.
Le Roy Ladurie Emmanuel. 1966. Les Paysans de Languedoc. Paris: Mouton.
Le Roy Ladurie Emmanuel. 1993. “Les Masses Profondes: La Paysannerie.” In Histoire Économique et Sociale de la France, edited by Fernand Braudel and Ernest Labrousse, vol. 1, 483860. Paris: Quadrige.
Le Roy Ladurie Emmanuel. 1996. The Ancien Régime: A History of France, 1610–1774. Oxford: Blackwell.
Lévy-Bruhl Henry. “Les Différentes espèces de sociétés de commerce en France au XVII et XVIII siècles.” Revue historique de droit français et étranger 4th Series.
Marion Marcel. 1914–1931. Histoire financière de la France depuis 1715. Paris: Rousseau.
Marion Marcel. 1999. Dictionnaire des institutions de la France aux XVII et XVIII siècles. Paris: Picard.
Matthews George Tennyson. 1958. The Royal General Farms in Eighteenth-Century France. New York: Columbia University Press.
Mollien François Nicolas, and Charles Gomel. 1898. Mémoires d’un ministre du trésor public 1780–1815. Paris: Guillaumin et cie.
North Douglass C., and Barry R. Weingast. (1989): “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” This Journal 49, no. 4 80332.Google Scholar
Pasquier Jean. 1905. L’Impôt des Gabelles en France aux XVII et XVIII Siècles. Geneva: Slatkine.
Riley, (June 1987): “French Finances, 1727–1768.” Journal of Modern History 59, no. 2 20943.Google Scholar
Root Hilton L. (1989): “Tying the King’s Hands: Royal Fiscal Policy during the Old Regime.” Rationality and Society 1 24059.Google Scholar
Rousselot de Surgy, Jacques-Philibert. 1784. Finances. Paris: Pancoucke.
Roux Pierre. 1916. Les fermes d’impôts sous l’ancien régime. Paris: Rousseau et cie.
Schama Simon. 1989. Citizens: A Chronicle of the French Revolution. New York: Knopf.
Shleifer Andrei and Robert Vishny. (1993): “Corruption.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, no. 3 599617.Google Scholar
Smith Adam. 1937. The Wealth of Nations. New York: Modern Library.
Varian Hal R. (1990): “Monitoring Agents with Other Agents.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146, no. 1 15374.Google Scholar
Velde François R. “Government Equity and Money: John Law’s System in 1720 France.” Chicago Federal Reserve Working Paper Series No. 2003-31, 2003.
Webber Carolyn, and Aaron B. Wildavsky. 1986. A History of Taxation and Expenditure in the Western World. New York: Simon and Schuster.
White Eugene. 1998France and the Failure to Modernize Macroeconomic Institutions.” Paper presented at the 12th International Economic History Conference, Madrid: Spain.
Wolfe Martin. 1972. The Fiscal System of Renaissance France. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.