Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T00:47:17.017Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Revolution of Ideas: Widespread Patenting and Invention During the English Industrial Revolution

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Richard J. Sullivan
Affiliation:
The author is Assistant Professor of Economics at the College of the Holy Cross, Worcester, MA 01610.

Abstract

Sectors of the English economy recognized as technological leaders have records of accelerated patent activity soon after 1760. But the patent record also reveals considerable inventive activity during the same period in industries not normally associated with advancing technology. It is therefore unlikely that there was a “leading technological sector.” The widespread increase in patenting is consistent with macroeconomic causes of accelerated invention.

Type
Papers Presented at the Forty-Ninth Annual Meeting of the Economic History Association
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1990

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

He thanks Jeremy Atack, David Wishart, Carolyn Cooper, Leslie Sullivan, Julian Simon, Tim Sullivan, Jack Powelson, Thomas Hughes, and Paul Hohenberg for their helpful comments.Google Scholar

1 Crafts, N. F. R., British Economic Growth During the Industrial Revolution (Oxford, 1985), p. 82. The productivity measure is total factor productivity, a ratio of total output to a weighted average of inputs.Google Scholar

2 Landes, David, The Unbound Prometheus (Cambridge, MA, 1969), p. 78, 41.Google ScholarSee also Mathias, Peter, The First Industrial Nation (New York, 1969), p. 134Google Scholar; Hartwell, R. M., “The Causes of the Industrial Revolution” in Hartwell, R. M., ed., The Causes of the Industrial Revolution in England (London, 1967), p. 79Google Scholar; and Crafts, British Economic Growth, pp. 85–88.Google Scholar

3 McCloskey, Donald N., “The Industrial Revolution 1780–1860: A Survey,” in Floud, Roderick and McCloskey, Donald N., eds., The Economic History of Britain Since 1700 (Cambridge, 1981), p. 109.Google Scholar

4 Crafts, British Economic Growth, pp. 86–87.Google Scholar

5 Woodcroft, Bennet, Subject Matter Index of Patens of Invention (London, 1857).Google ScholarDates have been corrected using Gomme, A. A., “Date Corrections of English Patents, 1617–1752,” Transactions of the Newcomen Society 33 (1932/1933), pp. 159–64,CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Jamieson, D. R., “Introduction,” in Woodcroft, Bennet, Alphabetical Index of Patentees of Inventions (London, 1857/1969), pp. v–xv. Definitions of the patent groups are in the Appendix. Additional detail about the source and of patent procedures is available upon request from the author.Google Scholar

6 I use the industry as a basis for classification because most writing about eighteenth-century English invention focuses on industrial sectors. In his discussion of this paper, Thomas Hughes noted that classification based on productive systems (for example, motive power or machine tools) might be more appropriate.Google Scholar

7 Schmookler, Jacob, Invention and Economic Growth (Cambridge, MA, 1966), p. 20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 See Pakes, Ariel and Simpson, Margaret, “Patent Renewal Data,” in Baily, M. N. and Winston, C., eds., Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1989 (Washington, 1989), p. 365.Google Scholar

9 Scherer, F. M., “The Propensity to Patent,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, I (03. 1983), pp. 107–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10 Kenneth Sokoloff analyzes early U.S. invention using patent data. See Sokoloff, Kenneth, “Inventive Activity in Early Industrial America: Evidence from Patent Records, 1790–1846,” this JOURNAL, 48 (09. 1988), pp. 813–50.Google Scholar

11 Deane, Phyllis and Cole, W. A., British Economic Growth, 1688–1959 (Cambridge, 1967), pp. 156, 166.Google Scholar

12 Both Christine MacLeod and Harold Dutton have argued that chemical inventions were easy to keep secret, so there was less incentive to patent. On the other hand, A. E. Musson and Eric Robinson's account of invention in the alkali industry shows that there was a keen interest in the protection afforded by patents. See MacLeod, Christine, Inventing the Industrial Revolution (Cambridge, 1988), pp. 106–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dutton, Harold I., The Patent System and Inventive Activity during the Industrial Revolution, 1750–1852 (Manchester, 1984), p. 119Google Scholar; Musson, A. E. and Robinson, Eric, Science and Technology in the Industrial Revolution (Manchester, 1969), pp. 352–71.Google Scholar

13 Employment data from Wood, G. H., The History of Wages in the Cotton Trade (London, 1910), pp. 127–28.Google Scholar

14 Landes, Unbound Prometheus, p. 40.Google Scholar

15 von Tunzelmann, G. N., “Technical Progress during the Industrial Revolution,” in Floud, and McCloskey, , eds., The Economic History of Britain Since 1700, vol. 1, pp. 143–62.Google Scholar

16 I will refer to the collective industrial, production machine, and steam engine groups of Tables 1 and 3 as the narrow set of technologically progressive sectors.Google Scholar

17 Dutton, Patent System, p. 208.Google Scholar

18 To avoid double-counting, any single patent is counted only once in the aggregated groups of Table 4. Since the groups of patents in Tables 1 and 3 are not mutually exclusive, the sum of their patents do not equal the totals in column 2 of Table 4.Google Scholar

19 Clow, Archibald and Clow, N. L., The Chemical Revolution (London, 1952), p. 91.Google Scholar Paul Hohenberg noted the same interrelated nature of chemical and other technologies in a later period; see Hohenberg, Paul, Chemicals in Western Europe: 1850–1914 (Chicago, 1967), pp. 30, 108–9, and chap. 6.Google Scholar

20 Usher, A. P., A History of Mechanical Inventions (Cambridge, 1954), p. 355.Google Scholar

21 Clow and Clow, Chemical Revolution, pp. 251–54.Google Scholar

22 “Trigger” is Mathias's term. Mathias, First Industrial Nation, p. 9.Google Scholar

23 Bowden, Witt, Industrial Society in England Towards the End of the Eighteenth Century (New York, 1925), pp. 5455.Google Scholar

24 Coleman, D. C., The Economy of England, 1450–1750 (London, 1977), pp. 155–56.Google Scholar

25 Musson and Robinson, Science and Technology in the Industrial Revolution.Google Scholar

26 For example, Ashton, T. S., The Industrial Revolution (London, 1948), pp. 1416Google Scholar; see also Musson, A. E., Growth of British Industry (London, 1978), p. 75.Google Scholar

27 MacLeod, Inventing the Industrial Revolution, chap. 11.Google Scholar

28 Ashton, T. S., “Some Statistics of the Industrial Revolution in Britain,” The Manchester School, 16 (05 1948), pp. 217–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

29 The model is very simple, making log of total patents a function of population, an index for time, a dummy variable for periods of war, and interest rates.Google Scholar

30 MacLeod, Inventing the Industrial Revolution, chap. 9.Google Scholar

31 Von Tunzelmann, “Technical Progress,” pp. 144–46.Google Scholar

32 Cole, W. A., “Eighteenth Century Growth Revisited” Explorations in Economic History, 10 (Summer 1973), pp. 327–48.Google Scholar

33 Simon, Julian and Sullivan, Richard, “Population Size, Knowledge, Stock, and Other Determinants of Agricultural Publication and Patenting: England, 1541–1850,” Explorations in Economic History, 26 (01. 1989), pp. 2145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

34 Musson, Growth of British Industry, p. 141.Google Scholar

35 McCloskey, “Industrial Revolution,” p. 114.Google ScholarCrafts (British Economic Growth, p. 86) attributes 73 percent of growth of total factor productivity to these industries, indicating an even wider gulf between invention and innovation.Google Scholar

36 Ashton, Industrial Revolution, p. 16.Google Scholar