Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T05:52:14.775Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Unemployment in Interwar Germany: An Analysis of the Labor Market, 1927–1936

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 September 2006

NICHOLAS H. DIMSDALE
Affiliation:
Emeritus Fellow in Economics, The Queen's College, Oxford, UK. E-mail: nicholas.dimsdale@queens.ox.ac.uk.
NICHOLAS HORSEWOOD
Affiliation:
University Lecturer in Economics, University of Birmingham, Birmingham, UK. E-mail: n.j.horsewood@bham.ac.uk.
ARTHUR VAN RIEL
Affiliation:
Strategic Policy Coordinator for the European Union, Ministry of Finance, The Netherlands. E-mail: a.riel@minfin.nL..

Abstract

This article contributes to the debate on the causes of unemployment in interwar Germany. It applies the Layard-Nickell model of the labor market to interwar data. The results indicate that demand shocks, combined with nominal inertia in the labor market, were important in explaining unemployment. Real wage pressures due to procedures for wage determination were a major influence on unemployment, but were partly offset by movements in other supply-side variables, such as the replacement ratio and the pricing policy of cartels. Demand- and supply-side variables were mutually reinforcing in the Great Depression and in the recovery under the Nazis.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2006 The Economic History Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Balderston Theo. (1977): “The German Business Cycle in the 1920s: A Comment.” Economic History Review 30, no. 1 15961.Google Scholar
Balderston Theo. 1993. The Origins and Course of the German Economic Crisis, 1923–1932. Berlin: Haude and Spener,
Bårdsen Gunnar, Øyvind Eitrheim, Eiler. S. Jansen, and Ragnar Nymoen. 2005. The Econometrics of Macroeconomic Modelling. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
Borchardt Knut. 1991. “Constraints and Room for Manoeuvre in the Great Depression of the Early Thirties: Towards a Revision of the Received Historical Picture.” In Perspectives on Modern German Economic History and Policy, edited by Knut Borchardt, 14360. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
Borchardt Knut. 1991. “Economic Causes of the Collapse of the Weimar Republic.” In Perspectives on Modern German Economic History and Policy, edited by Knut Borchardt, 16184. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Borchardt Knut. 1990. “A Decade of Debate about Brüning's Economic Policy.” In Economic Crisis and Political Collapse: The Weimar Republic 1924–1933, edited by Jürgen von Kreudener, 99155.Oxford: Berg
Borchardt Knut, and Albrecht Ritschl. (1992): “Could Brüning Have Done It? A Keynesian Model of Interwar Germany, 1925–1938.” European Economic Review 36 695701.Google Scholar
Bracher Karl. D. 1954. Die Auflösung der Weimarer Republik. Zum Problem des Machtverfalls in der Demokratie. Villingen: Ring-Verlag,
Broadberry Stephen N., and Albrecht Ritschl. (1995): “Real Wages, Productivity and Unemployment in Britain and Germany during the 1920s.” Explorations in Economic History 32, no. 3 32749.Google Scholar
Br uml;ning, Heinrich. 1970. Memoiren 1918–1934. Stuttgart: Deutsche Ring-Verlag,
Bry Gerhard. 1960. Wages in Germany 1871–1945. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
Burke Simon P., and John Hunter. 2005. Modelling Non-Stationary Economic Time Series. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan,
Campos Julia, and Neil R. Ericsson. “Economic Modeling of Consumers' Expenditure in Venezuela.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC. 1990.
Carlin Wendy, and David Soskice. 1990. Macroeconomics and the Wage Bargain: A Modern Approach to Employment, Inflation and the Exchange Rate. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
Dimsdale Nicholas H., Stephen J. Nickell, and Nicholas Horsewood. (June 1989): “Real Wages and Unemployment in Britain during the 1930s.” Economic Journal 99 27192.Google Scholar
Dimsdale Nicholas H., and Nicholas Horsewood. (2002): “The Causes of Unemployment in Interwar Australia.” Economic Record 78, no. 243 388405.Google Scholar
Dimsdale Nicholas H., Nicholas Horsewood, and Arthur van Riel. 2004Unemployment and Real Wages in Weimar Germany.” University of Oxford, Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History, no 56.
Enders Walter. 2004. Applied Econometric Time Series Analysis, 2nd edition. New York: Wiley
Eichengreen Barry. 1992. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. Oxford: Oxford University Press
Erbe René. 1958. Die Nationalsozialistische Wirtschaftspolitik 1933–1939 im Lichte der modernen Theorie. Zurich: Polygraphischer Verlag
Eschenburg T. 1984. Die Republik von Weimar. Beiträge zur Geschichte einer Improvisierten Demokratie. Munich and Zurich: Piper Verlag
Falkus Malcolm E. (1975): “The German Business Cycle in the 1920s.” Economic History Review 28, no. 3 45165.Google Scholar
Falter Jüngen, Thomas Lindenberger, and Siegfried Schumann. 1986. Wahlen und Abstimmungen in der WeimarerRepublik. Munich: Verlag C.H.Beck,
Hall Robert L., and Charles J. Hitch. 1951. “Price Theory and Business Behaviour.” In Oxford Studies in the Price Mechanism, edited by T. Wilson and P. W. S. Andrews, 10738. Oxford: Oxford University Press
Heiber Helmut. 1966. Die Republik von Weimar. Munich: Deutsche Taschenbuch Verlag
Hendry David F. 1995. Dynamic Econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
Hoffmann Walther G., Franz Grumbach, and Helmut Hesse. 1965. Das Wachstum der deutschen Wirtschaft seit der Mitte des 19. Jahrhunderts. Berlin: Springer Verlag,
Holtfrerich Carl-Ludwig. (1984): “Zu hohe Löhne in der Weimarer Republik? Bemerkungen zur Borchardt-These.” Geschichte und Gesellschaft 10 12241.Google Scholar
Holtfrerich Carl-Ludwig. 1990. “Was the Policy of Deflation in Germany Unavoidable?” In Economic Crisis and Political Collapse: The Weimar Republic 1924–1933, edited by Jürgen von Kruedener, 6380. Oxford: Berg,
James Harold. 1986. The German Slump: Politics and Economics 1924–1936. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
Johansen Søren. (June–September 1988): “Statistical Analysis of Cointegrated Vectors.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12 23154.Google Scholar
Johansen Søren. 1995. Likelihood-Based Inference in Cointegrated Vector Autoregressive Models. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
Layard Richard, and Stephen Nickell. “Unemployment in Britain.” In The Rise in Unemployment, edited by Charles Bean, Richard Layard, and Stephen Nickell, 12169. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1986.
Layard Richard, Stephen Nickell, and Richard Jackman. 1986. Unemployment: Macroeconomic Performance and the Labor Market. Oxford: Oxford University Press:
Mason Timothy W. (1966): “Labor in the Third Reich, 1933–1939.” Past & Present 32, no. 1 11241.Google Scholar
Overy Richard J. 1996. The Nazi Economic Recovery 1932–38. 2nd edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
Pagan Adrian. 2001. “The Getting of Macroeconomic Wisdom.” In Advances in Macroeconomic Theory, edited by J. Drèze, 21935. International Economic Association, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan,
Petzina Dietmar. 1986. “The Extent and Cause of Unemployment in the Weimar Republic.” In Unemployment in the Great Depression in Weimar Germany, edited by Peter D. Stachura, 2948. London: Macmillan,
Riel Arthur van, and Arthur Shram. (1993): “Weimar Economic Decline, Nazi Economic Recovery and the Stabilization of Political Dictatorship.” This Journal 53, no. 1 71105.Google Scholar
Ritschl Albrecht. (1998): “Reparations Transfers, the Borchardt Hypothesis and the Great Depression in Germany, 1929–32: A Guided Tour for Hard-headed Keynesians.” European Review of Economic History 2, no. 1 4972.Google Scholar
Ritschl Albrecht. (1990): “Zu hohe Löhne in der Weimarer Republik? Eine Auseinandersetzung mit Holfrerichs Berechnungen zur Lohnposition der Arbeiterschaft 1925–1932.” Geschichte und Gesellschaft 16, 375402.Google Scholar
Ritschl Albrecht. 2002. “International Capital Movements and the Onset of the Great Depression: Some International Evidence.” In The Interwar Depression in an International Context, edited by Harold James, 115. Munich: Oldenbourg,
Ritschl Albrecht. 2002 Deutschlands Krise und Konjunktur, 1924–1934: Binnenkonjunktur, Auslands-verschuldung und Reparationsproblem zwischen Dawes-Plan und Transfersperre. Berlin: Akademie Verlag,
Sanmann Horst. (1965): “Daten und Alternativen der Deutschen Wirtschafts- und Finanzpolitik in der Ära Brüning.” Hamburger Jahrbuch für Wirtschafts- und Gesellschaftspolitik 10 10940.Google Scholar
Schacht Hjalmar. 1931. The End of Reparations: The Economic Consequences of the World War. London: Jonathan Cape
Schmidt Carl T. 1934. German Business Cycles 1924–1933. New York: NBER
Siegel Tilla. (1985): “Wage Policy in Nazi Germany.” Politics and Society 14, no. 1 151.Google Scholar
Sommariva Andrea, and Giuseppe Tullio. 1987. German Macroeconomic History, 1880–1979. London: Macmillan,
Stögbauer Christian. (2001): “The Radicalization of the German Electorate Swinging to the Right and to the Left in the Twilight of the Weimar Republic.” European Review of Economic History 5, no. 2 25180.Google Scholar
Temin Peter. (1971): “The Beginning of the Depression in Germany.” Economic History Review 24, no. 2 2408.Google Scholar
Temin Peter. 1989. Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press:
Temin Peter. (1990): “Socialism and Wages in the Recovery from the Great Depression in the United States and Germany.” This Journal 50, no. 2 297307.Google Scholar
Tooze J. Adam. (1999): “Weimar's Statistical Economics: Ernst Wagemann, The Reich's Statistical Office and The Institute for Business-Cycle Research.” Economic History Review 24, no. 3 52343.Google Scholar
Voth Hans-Joachim. (2003): “With a Bang and not a Whimper: Pricking Germany's “Stock Market Bubble” in 1927and the Slide into Depression.” This Journal 63, no. 1 6599.Google Scholar
Weisbrod Bernd. (1985): “Die Befreiung von den “Tariffesseln” Deflationspolitik als Krisenstrategie in der Ära Brüning.” Geschicht und Gesellschaft 16, 295325.Google Scholar