Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T16:19:48.652Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Equal Access and Miller's Equilibrium

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Extract

Controversy over the implications of debt and the rationale belying capital structure has seemingly come to rest upon a plateau defined by Miller's equilibrium analysis of aggregate corporate debt [10]. In “Debt and Taxes,” Miller reasserts his contention that whether capital is obtained through debt or equity has no bearing on the market value of the firm and is, therefore, irrelevant--a notion which has long been accepted with some reluctance by the finance academe. When the Modigliani-Miller model was first offered some 20 years ago [11], it was accompanied by a set of assumptions which portrayed the world of corporate finance in such malleable terms as to make the irrelevancy propositions palatable. Adaptation of this theoretical model (by its originators) to its secular counterpart through the imposition of corporate taxes [12] brought about a reassuring reversal of the irrelevancy doctrine, but left in its stead the disconcerting prescription to maximize firm value by financing exclusively via debt. Consideration of tax effects at the personal level by Farrar and Selwyn [7] marked the next concession to reality by capital structure theorists. Instead of alienating the original model still further from observed corporate behavior, this step provided a means of reconciling the overwhelming advantage of debt financing at the corporate level with the ultimate after-tax “consumption possibilities” afforded to individual investors. Miller's analysis explains that corporations are forced to “gross up” nominal interest rates to attract bondholders who must be compensated for their personal tax liability [10]. Potential increases in market value due to the taxdeductibility of interest payments are exhausted in the competitive drive toward equilibrium—at which point there are no gains from leverage. The sanctity of the irrelevance theorem thus appears to have been restored at the aggregate level.

Type
Cost of Capital
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1981

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1]Akerlof, G.The Market for ‘Lemons’: Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84 (08 1970), pp. 488500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[2]Benston, G., and Smith, C.. “A Transactions Cost Approach to the Theory of Financial Intermediation.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 31 (05 1976), pp. 215231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[3]Campbell, T., and Kracaw, W.. “Information Production, Incentive Signaling, and the Theory of Financial Intermediation.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 35 (09 1980), pp. 863882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[4]Campbell, T., and Kracaw, W.. “Sorting Equilibria: The Incentive Problem.” Working paper, University of Utah (05 1980).Google Scholar
[5]Chen, A., and Kim, E. H.. “Theories of Corporate Debt Policy: A Synthesis.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 34 (05 1979), pp. 371384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6]Fama, E., and Miller, M.. The Theory of Finance. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston (1972).Google Scholar
[7]Farrar, D., and Selwyn, L.. “Taxes, Corporate Financial Policy and Return to Investors.” National Tax Journal, Vol. 20 (12 1967), pp. 444454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[8]Kim, E. H.Miller's Equilibrium and the Theory of Optimal Capital Structure.” Working paper, Ohio State University (03 1980).Google Scholar
[9]Leland, H., and Pyle, D.. “Informational Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 32 (05 1977), pp. 371387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10]Miller, M.Debt and Taxes.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 32 (05 1977), pp. 261276.Google Scholar
[11]Modigliani, F., and Miller, M.. “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment.” American Economic Review, Vol. 48 (06 1958), pp. 261297.Google Scholar
[12]Modigliani, F., and Miller, M.. “Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital: A Correction.” American Economic Review, Vol. 53 (06 1963), pp. 433443.Google Scholar
[13]Myers, S.Taxes, Corporate Financial Policy and the Return to Investors: Comment.” National Tax Journal, Vol. 20 (12 1967), pp. 455462.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[14]Ross, S.The Determination of Financial Structure: The Inventive-Signaling Approach.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 8 (Spring 1977), pp. 2340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[15]Spence, M.Job Market Signaling.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 87 (08 1973), pp. 355374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[16]Viscusi, K.A Note on ‘Lemons’ Markets with Quality Certification.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 9 (Spring 1978), pp. 277280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar