Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T14:19:41.773Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Implications of Recursiveness in Capital Markets–Theory and Empirical Tests

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Extract

Much of the current work in the analysis of security returns has been directed towards improving the specification of the Sharpe diagonal capital market model [9]. Because the residuals from the market model for different securities are observed to be correlated, some factor or factors are assumed to be common to large groups of stocks exclusive of the economy-wide influences captured by the market index. King [6], for example, found industry effects to be a significant determinant of security returns. In recent articles in this journal and elsewhere Lee and Lloyd, hereafter (L&L) ([7] [8]) attempt to capture the interaction of firms within an industry. They propose a recursive capital market model, an approach which is attractive because it allows for interaction in the determination of stock prices without the complications of a more fully simultaneous equations model (Simkowitz and Logue [10]). However, the L&L application of the recursive system is not without problems in both theory and application.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1979

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1]Bentzel, R., and Hansen, B.. “On Recursiveness and Interdependency in Economic Models.” Review of Economic Studies (1954), pp. 153168.Google Scholar
[2]Farrell, J.Analyziing Covariation of Returns to Determine Homgeneous Stock Groupings.” Journal of Business (04 1974), pp. 186207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[3]Fisher, F.The Identification Problem in Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company (1966).Google Scholar
14]ISL Daily Stock Price Index. Investment Statistics Laboratory (1967).Google Scholar
[5]Johnston, J.Econometric Methods. McGraw-Hill Book Company (1963).Google Scholar
[6]King, B.Market and Industry Factors in Stock Price Behavior.” Journal of Business (01 1966), pp. 139190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7]Lee, C., and Lloyd, W.. “The Capital Asset Pricing Model Expressed as a Recursive System An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (06 1976), pp. 237249.Google Scholar
[8]Lloyd, W., and Lee, C.. “Block Recursive Systems in Asset Pricing Models.” Journal of Finance (09 1976), pp. 11011114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[9]Sharpe, W.Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium Under Condition of Risk.” Journal of Finance (09 1964), pp. 425442.Google Scholar
[10]Simkowitz, M., and Logue, D.. “The Interdependent Structure of Security Returns.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (03 1973), pp. 259272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[11]Theil, H. Principles of Econometrics. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc. (1971).Google Scholar
[12]Strotz, R. H., and Wold, H. O.. “Recursive vs. Non-Recursive Systems: An Attempt at Synthesis.” Econometrics (04 1960), pp. 417427.Google Scholar