Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T14:54:40.576Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for the Mean-Variance Portfolio Model With Constant Risk Aversion

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Extract

The familiar two-parameter model for portfolio decisions, attributed to Markowitz [11], has individuals maximizing an objective function, ϕ [E(Y), V(Y)], of mean and variance of end-of-period wealth, subject to a constraint imposed by initial wealth. In the usual version there is an arbitrary number, n, of risky assets with stochastic end-of-period values (price plus dividend) represented by the vector X with exogenously given mean vector μ and nonsingular variance matrix σ. There is also one riskless asset, whose certain end-of-period value per dollar invested is p. Final wealth, as constrained by initial wealth, W, is given by Y = WP + a' (X – OP), where a and P are vectors of risky asset quantities and prices. Assuming ϕE > 0 (wealth preference), ϕV < 0 (risk aversion), and that the Hessian of $ is negative and semidefinite, portfolio optimum calls for ϕE(μ − OP) + 2ϕVσa = 0, or

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1981

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1]Arrow, Kenneth J.Aspects of the Theory of Risk Bearing. Helsinki: Yrjo Jahnsson Foundation (1965).Google Scholar
[2]Black, Fisher. “Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing.” Journal of Business, Vol. 45 (1972), pp. 444454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[3]Copeland, Thomas E.A Model of Asset Trading under the Assumption of Sequential Information Arrival.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 31 (1976), pp. 11491168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[4]Epps, Thomas W.Security Price Changes and Transaction Volumes: Theory and Evidence.” American Economic Review, Vol. 65 (1975), pp. 586597.Google Scholar
[5]Epps, Thomas W.. “The Demand for Brokers' Services: The Relation between Security Trading Volume and Transaction Cost.” Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 7 (1976), pp. 163194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6]Epps, Thomas W.. “Efficient Markets and Martingale Price Processes.” Manuscript (1978).Google Scholar
[7]Epps, Thomas W., and Epps, Mary Lee. “The Stochastic Dependence of Security Price Changes and Transaction Volumes: Implications for the Mixture-of- Distributions Hypothesis.” Econometrica, Vol. 44 (1976), pp. 305321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[8]Feldstein, M. S.Mean-Variance Analysis in the Theory of Liquidity Preference and Portfolio Selection.” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 36 (1969), pp. 512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[9]LeRoy, Stephen F.Risk Aversion and the Martingale Property of Stock Prices.” International Economic Review, Vol. 14 (1973), pp. 436446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10]Lintner, John.The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets.” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47 (1965), pp. 1337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[11]Markowitz, Harry. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. New York: John Wiley & Sons (1959).Google Scholar
[12]Mossin, Jan. “Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market.” Econometrica, Vol. 34 (1966), pp. 768783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[13]Pratt, John W.Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large.” Econometrica, Vol. 32 (1964), pp. 122136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[14]Rabinovitch, Ramon, and Owen, Joel. “Non-Homogeneous Expectations and Information in the Capital Asset Market.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 33 (1978), pp. 575587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[15]Richter, M. K.Cardinal Utility, Portfolio Selection, and Taxation.” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 27 (1960), pp. 152166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[16]Ross, Stephen A.Mutual Fund Separation in Financial Theory—The Separating Distributions.” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 17 (1978), pp. 254286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[17]Savage, Leonard J.The Foundations of Statistics. New York: John Wiley & Sons (1954).Google Scholar
[18]Sharpe, William F.Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 19 (1964), pp. 425442.Google Scholar
[19]Tobin, J. E.Liquidity Preference as Behavior towards Risk.” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 25 (1958), pp. 6586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[20]vonNeumann, John, and Morgenstern, Oskar. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press (1944).Google Scholar