Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T17:17:15.022Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Theorems of Modern Finance in a General Equilibrium Setting: Paradoxes Resolved

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 October 2009

Extract

Looking back over the last two decades, financial economists can find considerable cause for pride and self-congratulation in the development of their discipline. From the earliest steps toward a rigorous theory of capital budgeting, through the Modigliani-Miller theorems on corporate financing and cost of capital, to the development of the capital asset pricing theory, the field of finance has garnered a well-deserved reputation for rigor, analytic sophistication, and pace of intellectual growth.

Type
Proceedings of 1977 Western Finance Association Meeting: Special Paper
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1977

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 If recessions of standard magnitude occurred at random intervals of mean length Ṯ instead of in predictable cycles, the stock market would rise in every period in which a recession was not signaled and decline only when a recession could be forecast, producing a “leading indicator” type of result. In that case, however, the depth of the stock market reaction should be limited to the effect of the recession occurring now rather than Ṯ periods from now—a rather small order of magnitude.

The only business cycle model consistent with an efficient stock market that is a leading indicator is one in which business activity is a diffusion. While there is evidence consistent with such a view of economic activity, it is not the model most people have in mind.

2 Indeed, we can already see how this relates to our earlier question. Why would we hold any real capital into a foreseeable recession unless its current price already discounts the recession? But if we hold wheat into the harvest at a price above the expected harvest price, why shouldn't we do the same for business inventories or capital equipment in the face of a recession?

3 The key to this result is that the elasticity of wealth with respect to oil inventories (above and below ground) is unity regardless of the price elasticity of consumption.

4 It is tempting to refer to this situation as nonoptimal, but clearly if there are some money or subjective costs that keep individuals from holding the portfolio which is predicted in the absence of costs, it is the actual behavior of the market that is optimal, rather than my overly simple model. Nevertheless, the discrepancy between the two models is quite illuminating.