Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T07:30:48.775Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Financial Planning in a Regulated Environment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Extract

Recent economic research efforts in rate of return regulation of public utilities have for the most part been couched in a static, steady-state framework, “Averch-Johnson” hypotheses being the most obvious examples [3]. Nevertheless, standard classical microeconomic analysis of rate of return regulation seems to have two important drawbacks: first, it does not address itself to multiperiod relationships; and secondly, it cannot be represented in current-practice financial terms. This paper first outlines rate of return regulation as typically practiced. It then describes the essential features of a model designed to examine intertemporally the financial and capital expansion decision tradeoffs a public utility faces given corporate, institutional, and regulatory constraints. Decision tradeoff questions have assumed substantial policy importance in recent years not only because of the ambiguities in rate of return regulation effects conceptualized in the Averch-Johnson literature but because of the behavioral (occasionally legal) importance of purely financial constraints, such as interest coverage requirements, on corporate investment and financing choices.

Type
VII. Financial Planning
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1978

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1]AT&T 1975 Statistical Report.Google Scholar
[2]AT&T, Annual Reports (19711975).Google Scholar
[3]Baumol, W., and Klevowick, A.. “The Averch-Johnson Thesis.Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Autumn 1970).Google Scholar
[4]Bell System, Statistical Manual (19711975).Google Scholar
[5]Carleton, W. T.An Analytical Model for Long Range Financial Planning.” Journal of Finance (05 1970).Google Scholar
[6]Carleton, W. T.; Dick, C. D.; and Downes, D. H.. “Financial Policy Models: Theory and Practice.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (12 1973).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7]Carleton, W. T.. “Rate of Return, Rate Base and Regulatory Lag under Conditions of Changing Capital Costs.” Land Economics (05 1974).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[8]Carleton, W. T.. “A Note on the Use of the CAPM for Utility Rate of Return Determination.” In Applications in Finance, edited by Elton, E. J. and Gruber, M. J.. North Holland (forthcoming).Google Scholar
[9]Carleton, W. T.. “A Highly Personal Comment on ‘On the Use of the CAPM in Public Utility Rate Cases.’” Financial Management (forthcoming).Google Scholar
[10]Davis, D. E.; Caccappolo, G. J.; and Chaudry, M. A.. “An Econometric Planning Model for American Telephone and Telegraph Company.Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Spring 1973).Google Scholar
[11]Dobell, A. R., Taylor, L. D.; Waverman, L.; Liu, T. H.; and Copeland, M. D. G.. “Telephone Communications in Canada: Demand, Production and Investment Decisions.Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Spring 1972).Google Scholar
[12]Federal Power Commission et al. versus Hope Natural Gas Company, 320 U.S. 591 (1949) at 603.Google Scholar
[13]Gordon, M. J.The Cost of Capital to a Public Utility. Michigan State University, Public Utilities Study (1974).Google Scholar
[14]Machado, E. L. Financial Planning in a Regulated Environment. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation. University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill (1977).Google Scholar
[15]Miller, M. H., and Modigliani, F.. “Dividend Policy, Growth and the Valuation of Shares.” Journal of Business (10 1961).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[16]Myers, S. C.The Application of Finance Theory to Public Utility Rate Cases.Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (Spring 1972).Google Scholar