Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-16T00:33:32.811Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Stationarity of the Conditional Mean of Real Rates of Return on Common Stocks: An Empirical Investigation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Extract

The capital asset pricing model of Sharpe [39], Lintner [28], and Mossin [33] has been the basis for many theoretical and empirical studies in capital markets. One criticism of the model hasbeen directed at the assumption that investors optimize in a one-period framework. Fama [7] and Merton [30] have shown that the results of this one-period optimization model are consistent with the results for an intertemporal optimization model if the investment opportunity set is constant over time. Specifically, the relevant parameters for the distributions of risky securities (i.e., conditional means and variances) must be constant over time. Merton has argued that this is a restrictive assumption, but there has been very little empirical evidence to suggest that changes in the investment opportunity set are significant.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1984

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

[1]Bartlett, M.S.An Introduction to Stochastic Processes with Special Reference to Methods and Applications. Third Edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (1978).Google Scholar
[2]Box, George E., and Jenkins, Gwilym M.. Time Series Analysis: Forecasting and Control. San Francisco: Holden Day (1976).Google Scholar
[3]Breeden, D.T.An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities.” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 7 (09 1979), pp. 265296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[4]Carlson, John A.Short-Term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation: Comment.” American Economic Review, Vol. 67 (06 1977), pp. 469475.Google Scholar
[5]Durbin, James. “Tests for Serial Correlation in Regression Analysis Based on the Periodogram of Least-Squares Residuals.” Biometrika, Vol. 56 (03 1969), pp. 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6]Epps, T. W.A Class of General Equilibrium Models of Asset Prices with Constant Expected Return.” University of Virginia (10 1981).Google Scholar
[7]Fama, Eugene F.Multiperiod Consumption-Investment Decisions.” American Economic Review, Vol. 60 (03 1970), pp. 163174.Google Scholar
[8]Fama, Eugene F.Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 25 (05 1970), pp. 383417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[9]Fama, Eugene F.Short-Term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation.” American Economic Review, Vol. 65 (06 1975), pp. 269282.Google Scholar
[10]Fama, Eugene F.Foundations of Finance. New York: Basic Books (1976).Google Scholar
[ll]Fama, Eugene F.Reply.” Journal of Finance, Vol 31 (03 1976), pp. 143145.Google Scholar
[12]Fama, Eugene F.Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation, and Money.” American Economic Review, Vol. 71 (09 1981), pp. 545565.Google Scholar
[13]Fama, Eugene F., and MacBeth, James D.. “Tests of the Multiperiod Two-Parameter Model.” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 1 (05 1974), pp. 4366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[14]Grossman, Sanford J., and Shiller, Robert J.. “The Determinants of the Variability of Stock Market Prices.” American Economic Review, Vol. 71 (05 1981), pp. 222227.Google Scholar
[15]Hansen, Lars P., and Singleton, Kenneth J.. “Stochastic Consumption, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Stock Market Returns.” Carnegie-Mellon University (04 1981).Google Scholar
[16]Hansen, Lars P., and Singleton, Kenneth J.Generalized Instrumental Variables Estimation of Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models.” Econometrica, Vol. 50 (09 1982), pp. 12691286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[17]Hess, Patrick J., and Bicksler, James L.. “Capital Asset Prices Versus Time Series Models as Predictors of Inflation: The Expected Real Rate of Interest and Market Efficiency.” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 2 (12 1975), pp. 341360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[18]Ibbotson, Roger G., and Sinquefield, Rex A.. Stocks, Bonds, Bills and Inflation: The Past (1926–1976) and the Future (1977–2000). Charlottesville: Financial Analysis Research Foundation (1977).Google Scholar
[19]Johnston, J.Econometric Methods. Second Edition. New York: McGraw Hill Book Company (1972).Google Scholar
[20]Joines, Douglas. “Short-Term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation: Comment.” American Economic Review, Vol. 67 (06 1977), pp. 476477.Google Scholar
[21[Judge, George G.; Griffiths, William E.; Hill, R. Carter; and Lee, Tsoung-Chao. The Theory and Practice of Econometrics. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. (1980).Google Scholar
[22]Karlin, Samuel, and Taylor, Howard M.. A First Course on Stochastic Processes. Second Edition. New York: Academic Press (1975).Google Scholar
[23]Kryzanowski, Lawrence, and To, Minh Chau. “General Factor Models and the Structure of Security Returns.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 18 (03 1983), pp. 3152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[24]LeRoy, Stephen F.Risk Aversion and the Martingale Property of Stock Prices.” International Economic Review, Vol. 14 (06 1973), pp, 436446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[25]LeRoy, Stephen F.Efficient Capital Markets: Comment.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 31 (03 1976), pp. 139141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[26]LeRoy, Stephen F.Expectations Models of Asset Prices: A Survey of Theory.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 37 (03 1982), pp. 185217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[27]LeRoy, Stephen F., and Porter, Richard D.. “The Present-Value Relation: Tests Based on Implied Variance Bounds.” Econometrica, Vol. 49 (05 1981), pp. 555574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[28]Lintner, John. “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets.” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47 (02 1965), pp. 1337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[29]Lucas, Robert E.Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy.” Econometrica, Vol. 46 (11 1978), pp. 14271445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[30]Merton, Robert C.An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model.” Econometrica, Vol. 41 (09 1973), pp. 867887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[31]Merton, Robert C.On Estimating the Expected Return on the Market: An Exploratory Investigation.” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 8 (12 1980), pp. 323362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[32]Michener, Ronald. “Variance Bounds in a Simple Model of Asset Pricing.” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90 (02 1982), pp. 166175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[33]Mossin, Jan. “Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market.” Econometrica, Vol. 34 (10 1966), pp. 768783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[34]Mundell, Robert A.. “Inflation and the Real Rate of Interest.” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 71 (06 1963), pp. 280283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[35]Nelson, Charles R., and Schwert, G. William. “Short-Term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation: Comment.” American Economic Review, Vol. 67 (06 1977), pp. 478486.Google Scholar
[36]Ohlson, James A.Risk Aversion and the Martingale Property of Stock Prices: Comments.” International Economic Review, Vol. 18 (02 1977), pp. 229234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[37]Ohlson, James A.Risk, Return, Security-Valuation and the Stochastic Behavior of Accounting Numbers.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 14 (06 1979), pp. 317336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[38]Samuelson, Paul A.Proof that Properly Discounted Present Values of Assets Vibrate Randomly.” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 4 (Autumn 1973), pp. 369374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[39]Sharpe, William F.Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 19 (09 1964), pp. 425442.Google Scholar
[40]Sharpe, William F.Portfolio Theory and Capital Markets. New York: McGraw Hill (1970).Google Scholar
[41]Shiller, Robert J.The Use of Volatility Measures in Assessing Market Efficiency.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 36 (05 1981), pp. 291304.Google Scholar
[42]Shiller, Robert J.Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends?American Economic Review, Vol. 71 (06 1981), pp. 421436.Google Scholar
[43]Singleton, Kenneth J.Extracting Measures of Ex Ante Real Interest Rates from Ex Post Rates: A Comment.” Carnegie-Mellon University (02 1981).CrossRefGoogle Scholar