Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T23:07:36.502Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Rules, perception and emotion: When do institutions determine behaviour?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 November 2018

Brendan Markey-Towler*
Affiliation:
School of Economics, University of Queensland, Australia
*
*Corresponding author. Email: brendan.markeytowler@uqconnect.edu.au

Abstract

This paper seeks to answer the question of what psychological preconditions must exist for institutions to determine behaviour and order our societies. We defend the notion that institutional theory may gain from such a contribution. We introduce a new theory of the mind as a network structure within which the psychological process operates to integrate insights from cognitive and affective psychology into institutional theory. We discover that institutions must be expressed as rules in mental networks which guide thinking and behaviour, be embedded within a cognitive apparatus such that they are called to mind by perception to so guide thinking and behaviour and be anchored to emotion such that they are endowed with urgency in order for them to have a hold on individual behaviour. From this theory we derive definite predictions, as well as policy insights.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Almudi, I., Fatas-Villafranca, F., Izquierdo, L. R. and Potts, J. (2017), “The Economics of Utopia: A Co-evolutionary Model of Ideas, Citizenship and Socio-political Change,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, DOI 10.1007/s00191-017-0507-7.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. (2015), “Why is the Equilibrium Notion Essential for a Unified Institutional Theory? A Friendly Remark on the Article by Hindriks and Guala,” Journal of Institutional Economics, 11: 485488.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. (2011), “Institutions as Cognitive Media between Strategic Interactions and Individual Beliefs,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 79, pp. 2034.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. and Hamilton, W. D. (1981), “The Evolution of Cooperation,” Science, 211: 13901396.Google Scholar
Ayres, C. (1944), The Theory of Economic Progress, Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Ayres, C. (1953), “The Role of Technology in Economic Theory,” American Economic Review, 43: 279287.Google Scholar
Baumeister, R. F. and Tierney, J. (2011), Willpower, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Baumeister, R. F., Braslavsky, E., Muraven, M. and Tice, D. M. (1998), “Ego Depletion: Is the Active Self a Limited Resource? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 74: 12521265.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1968), “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political Economy, 76: 169217.Google Scholar
Boulding, K. (1956), The Image, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1990), “The Domain of Constitutional Economics,” Constitutional Political Economy, 1: 118.Google Scholar
Brunswik, E. (1943), “Organismic Achievement and Environmental Probability,” Psychological Review, 50(3): 255272.Google Scholar
Coase, R. (1937), “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica (New Series), 4(6): 386405.Google Scholar
Coase, R. (1984), “The New Institutional Economics,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 140: 229231.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. (1924), Legal Foundations of Capitalism, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. (1931), “Institutional Economics,” American Economic Review, 21(4): 648657.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. (1934), Institutional Economics, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Crowe, J. (2014a), “Law as an Artefact Kind,” Monash University Law Review, 40(3), 737757.Google Scholar
Crowe, J. (2014b), “Radicalising Hayekian Constitutionalism,” University of Queensland Law Journal, 33(2): 379389.Google Scholar
Crowe, J. and Lee, C. Y. (2015), “Law as Memory,” Law and Critique, 26: 251266.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. (1859), On the Origin of Species, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. (1872), The Expression of the Emotions in Man and Animals, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dewey, J. (1910), How We Think. DC Heath, Lexington.Google Scholar
Dopfer, K. (2004), “The Economic Agent as Rule Maker and Rule User: Homo Sapiens Oeconomicus,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14: 177195.Google Scholar
Dopfer, K. and Potts, J. (2008), The General Theory of Economic Evolution, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dopfer, K., Foster, J. and Potts, J. (2004), “Micro-meso-macro,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14: 263279.Google Scholar
Eagleman, D. M. (2011), Incognito, Melbourne: Text Publishing.Google Scholar
Earl, P. (1983), The Economic Imagination, Brighton: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Earl, P. (1986a), Lifestyle Economics, Brighton: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Earl, P. (1986b), “A Behavioural Analysis of Demand Elasticities,” Journal of Economic Studies, 13: 2037.Google Scholar
Earl, P. (1990), “Economics and Psychology: A Survey,” Economic Journal, 100: 718–55.Google Scholar
Earl, P. (1995), Microeconomics for Business and Marketing, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Earl, P. (2015), “Anchoring in Economics: On Frey and Gallus in the Aggregation of Behavioural Anomalies,” Economics, 9, www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2014-37 (accessed 29 July 2018).Google Scholar
Earl, P. (2017), “Lifestyle Changes and the Lifestyle Selection Process,” Journal of Bioeconomics, 19: 97114.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1998), “Emotions and Economic Theory,” Journal of Economic Literature, 36: 4774.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (2009), Reason and Rationality, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Festinger, L. (1957), A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Freud, S. (1917), A General Introduction to Psychoanalysis, Hertfordshire: Wordsworth Editions.Google Scholar
Freud, S. (1930), Civilisation and its Discontents, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. and Goldstein, D. G. (1996), “Reasoning the Fast and Frugal Way: Models of Bounded Rationality,” Psychological Review, 103: 650669.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. (1999), Simple Heuristics that Make Us Smart, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Goleman, D. (1996), Emotional Intelligence, London: Bloomsbury.Google Scholar
Hart, H. L. A. (1961), The Concept of Law, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Haidt, J. (2001), “The Emotional Dog and Its Rational Tail: A Social Intuitionist Approach to Moral Judgment,” Psychological Review, 108: 814834.Google Scholar
Haidt, J. (2012), The Righteous Mind, London: Vintage.Google Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1919), “The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory,” American Economic Review, 9: 309318.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1952), The Sensory Order, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1988), The Fatal Conceit, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hermann-Pillath, C. (2017), “Institutional Naturalism: Reflections on Masahiko Aoki's Contribution to Institutional Economics,” Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 14: 501522.Google Scholar
Heiner, R. (1983), “The Origin of Predictable Behavior,” American Economic Review, 73: 560595.Google Scholar
Heiner, R. (1985), “Origin of Predictable Behavior: Further Modelling and Applications,” American Economic Review, 75: 391396.Google Scholar
Hindriks, F. and Guala, F. (2015), “Institutions, Rules, and Equilibria,” Journal of Institutional Economics, 11: 459480.Google Scholar
Hinkle, D. (1965), The Change of Personal Constructs from the Viewpoint of a Theory of Construct Implications. Doctoral Thesis, Ohio State University.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (1998), “The Approach of Institutional Economics,” Journal of Economic Literature, 36: 166192.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (2004), The Evolution of Institutional Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (2010), “Choice, Habit and Evolution,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20: 118.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. and Knudsen, T. (2010), Darwin's Conjecture, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hume, D. (1777), An Enquiry Concerning Human Understanding (2nd edition). Cambridge: Hackett Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Jung, C. G. (ed.) (1964), Man and His Symbols, London: Aldus Books.Google Scholar
Jung, C. G. (1968), Analytical Psychology, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Kant, I. (1781), Critique of Pure Reason, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Kelly, G. A. (1963), A Theory of Personality, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1902), Mutual Aid, New York: Dover.Google Scholar
Lawson, C. (2015a), “Order and Process in Institutionalist Thought: Commons and Ayres,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39: 10531084.Google Scholar
Lawson, T. (2012), “Ontology and the Study of Social Reality: Emergence, Organisation, Community, Power, Social Relations, Corporations, Artefacts and Money,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 36: 345385.Google Scholar
Lawson, T. (2015b), “The Nature of the Firm and the Peculiarities of the Corporation,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39: 132.Google Scholar
Lawson, T. (2016), “Comparing Conceptions of Social Ontology: Emergent Social Entities and/or Institutional Facts? Journal for the Theory of Social Behaviour, 46: 359399.Google Scholar
LeDoux, J. (1996), The Emotional Brain, London: Orion.Google Scholar
Leeson, P. (2009), The Invisible Hook. Princeton University Press. Princeton.Google Scholar
Leeson, P. (2014), Anarchy Unbound, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (1996), “Out of Control: Visceral Influences on Behavior,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65: 272292.Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (2000), “Emotions in Economic Theory and Economic Behavior,” American Economic Review, 90: 426432.Google Scholar
Luria, A. (1973), The Working Brain, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Maslow, A. (1943), “A Theory of Human Motivation,” Psychological Review, 50: 370396.Google Scholar
Markey-Towler, B. (2018), An Architecture of the Mind, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Markey-Towler, B. (forthcoming), “The Competition and Evolution of Ideas in the Public Sphere: A New Foundation for Institutional Theory,” Journal of Institutional Economics.Google Scholar
Marshall, P. (1992), Demanding the Impossible, New York: HarperPerennial.Google Scholar
Merleau-Ponty, M. (1945), The Phenomenology of Perception, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Merleau-Ponty, M. (1948), The World of Perception, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Metcalfe, J. and Mischel, W. M. (1999), “A Hot/Cool-system Analysis of Delay of Gratification: Dynamics of Willpower,” Psychological Review, 106: 319.Google Scholar
Mischel, W. M. (2014), The Marshmallow Test, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Mitchell, W. C. (1913), Business Cycles, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Newell, A. (1990), Unified Theories of Cognition, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Newman, J. H. (1870), An Essay in Aid of a Grammar of Assent, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nietzsche, F. (1901), The Will to Power, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
North, D. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. (1991), “Institutions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5: 97112.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2000), “Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14: 137158.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. and Basurto, X. (2011), “Crafting Analytical Tools to Study Institutional Change,” Journal of Institutional Economics, 7), 317343.Google Scholar
Packard, V. (1957), The Hidden Persuaders, London: Pelican.Google Scholar
Panksepp, J. (1998), Affective Neuroscience, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Peterson, J. (1999), Maps of Meaning, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Piaget, J. (1923), The Language and Thought of the Child, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Pinker, S. (1999), How the Mind Works, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. (1958), Personal Knowledge, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. (1962), The Tacit Dimension, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Popper, K. (1945), The Open Society and Its Enemies, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ratnapala, S. (2003), “Securing Constitutional Government: The Perpetual Challenge,” The Independent Review, 8: 526.Google Scholar
Ratnapala, S. (2009), Jurisprudence, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sapolsky, R. M. (2017), Behave, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Seabright, P. (2004), The Company of Strangers. Princeton University Press. Princeton.Google Scholar
Searle, J. R. (2005), “What Is an Institution? Journal of Institutional Economics, 1: 122.Google Scholar
Searle, J. R. (2010), Making the Social World, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Searle, J. R. (2015), “Status Functions and Institutional Facts: A Reply to Hindriks and Guala,” Journal of Institutional Economics, 11: 507514.Google Scholar
Shannon, C. (1948a), “A Mathematical Theory of Communication,” Bell Systems Technical Journal, 27: 379423.Google Scholar
Shannon, C. (1948b), “A Mathematical Theory of Communication,” Bell Systems Technical Journal, 27: 623666.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1947), Administrative Behaviour (4th edition), New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1956), “Rational Choice and the Structure of the Environment,” Psychological Review, 63: 129138.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1967), “Motivation and Emotional Controls of Cognition,” Psychological Review, 74: 2939.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1968), Sciences of the Artificial, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1976), “From Substantive to Procedural Rationality,” in Latsis, S. (ed.) Method and Appraisal in Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 129148.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1978a), “On How to Decide What to Do,” Bell Journal of Economics, 9: 494507.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1978b), “Rationality as a Process and Product of Thought,” American Economic Review, 68: 116.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. (1898), “Why is Economics not an Evolutionary Science? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 12: 373397.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. (1899), The Theory of the Leisure Class, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. (1904), The Theory of Business Enterprise, New York: Charles Scribners.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. (1914), The Instinct of Workmanship, and the State of the Industrial Arts, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Von Neumann, J. (1958), The Computer and the Brain, Yale, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (1979), “Transaction-cost Economics: The Governance of Contract Relations,” Journal of Law and Economics, 22: 233261.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (2002), “The Theory of the Firm as Governance Structure: From Choice to Contract,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16: 171195.Google Scholar