Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-lnqnp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T18:32:43.290Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Endogenizing institutions and institutional changes*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 April 2007

MASAHIKO AOKI*
Affiliation:
Stanford University

Abstract:

This paper proposes an analytical-cum-conceptual framework for understanding the nature of institutions as well as their changes. First, it proposes a new definition of institution based on the notion of common knowledge regarding self-sustaining features of social interactions with a hope to integrate various disciplinary approaches to institutions and their changes. Second, it specifies some generic mechanisms of institutional coherence and change – overlapping social embeddedness, Schumpeterian innovation in bundling games, and dynamic institutional complementarities – useful for understanding the dynamic interactions of economic, political, social, organizational, and cognitive factors.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alchian, A. and Demsetz, H. 1972, ‘Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization’, American Economic Review, 62: 777795.Google Scholar
Amable, B. 2003, The Diversity of Modern Capitalism, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, M. 1994, ‘The Contingent Governance of Teams: An Analysis of Institutional Complementarity’, International Economic Review, 35: 657676.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. 2001, Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. 2007, ‘Whither Japan's Corporate Governance?’, to appear in Aoki, M., Jackson, G., and Miyajima, H. (forthcoming), Corporate Governance in Japan: Institutional Change and Organizational Diversity, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. and Hayami, Y. (eds) 2001, Communities and Markets in Economic Development, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. and Takizawa, H. 2002, ‘Information, Incentives, and Option Value: The Silicon-Valley Model’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 30: 759786.Google Scholar
Aumann, R. J. 1976, ‘Agreeing to Disagree’, Annals of Statistics, 4: 12361239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. J. 1987, ‘Correlated Equilibrium as an Expression of Baynesian Rationality’, Econometrica, 55: 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, C. Y. and Clark, K. B. 2000, Design Rules: The Power of Modularity, Vol. I, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barca, F., Iwai, K., Pagano, U., and Trento, S. 1999, ‘The Divergence of Italian and Japanese Corporate Governance Models: The Role of Institutional Shocks’, Economic Systems, 3: 3561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardhan, P. 1977, ‘Variations in Forms of Tenancy in a Peasant Economy’, Journal of Development Economics, 4: 105118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berger, P. and Luckmann, T. 1966, The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge, NY: Doubleday Anchor.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1994, Playing Fair: Game theory and social Contract, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 2005, Natural Justice, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Blau, P. 1964/1998, Exchange and Power in Social Life, with new introduction, Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Braudel, F. 1958/1997, ‘History and the Social Sciences: The Longue Duree’, in Mathews, S. (tr.), On History, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 2455.Google Scholar
Calvert, R. L. 1995, ‘Rational Agents, Equilibrium, and Social Institutions’, in Knight, J. and Sened, I. (eds), Explaining Social Institutions, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 5793.Google Scholar
Coleman, J. 1990, Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H. 1967, ‘Towards a Theory of Property Rights’, American Economic Review, 57: 347359.Google Scholar
Denzau, A. and North, D. 1994, ‘Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions’, Kyklos, 47: 331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, P. and Powell, W. 1983, ‘The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphisms and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields’, American Sociological Review, 48: 147–160. Revised and reprinted as Chapter 3 of Powell and DiMaggio (1991): 63–82.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. K. 2004, Lawlessness and Economics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. and Marengo, L. 1994, ‘Some Elements of an Evolutionary Theory of Organizational Competence’, in England, R. W. (ed.), Evolutionary Concepts in Contemporary Economics, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 157178.Google Scholar
Fagin, R., Halpern, J. Y., Moses, Y., and Vardi, M. Y. 1995, Reasoning about Knowledge, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Field, A. J. 1981, ‘The Problem with Neoclassical Institutional Economics: A Critique with Special Reference to the North-Thomas Model of pre-1500 Europe’, Exploration in Economic History, 18: 174198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Field, A. J. 2001, Altruistically Inclined? Evolutionary Theory, the Behavioral Sciences, and the Origin of Complex Social Organization, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Gibbard, A. 1973, ‘Manipulation of Voting Schemes: A General Result’, Econometrica, 41: 587601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, H. 2000, ‘Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality’, Journal of Theoretical Biology, 206: 169179.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gintis, H. 2004, ‘Modeling Preferences’, Santa Fe Institute.Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. 1985, ‘Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness’, American Journal of Sociology, 91: 480510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. 1993, ‘Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition’, American Economic Review, 83: 525548.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 1997, ‘Micro Theory and Recent Developments in the Study of Economic Institutions through Economic History’, in Kreps, D. and Wallis, K. (eds), Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Vol. 2, New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 79113.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 2005, ‘Commitment, Coercion and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange’, in Menard, C. and Shirley, M. M. (eds), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 727786Google Scholar
Greif, A. 2006, Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade, New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1945, ‘The Use of Knowledge in Society’, American Economic Review, 35: 519530.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1976, Law, Legislation and Liberty, Vol. II: The Mirage of Social Justice, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1988, The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. 1969, A Theory of Economic History, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 2006, ‘What are Institutions?’, Journal of Economic Issues, 40: 125.Google Scholar
Holland, J., Holyoak, K., Nisbett, R., and Thagard, P. 1989, Induction: Processes of Inferences, Learning and Discovery, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, L. 1960, ‘On the Dimensional Requirements for Non-wasteful Resource Allocation Systems’, in Arrow, K. J., Karlin, S., and Suppes, P. (eds), The Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences 1959, Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, L. 1996, ‘Institutions as Families of Game-forms’, Japanese Economic Review, 47: 13132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huizinga, J. 1949, Homo Ludens. A Study of Play Element in Culture, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Ikegami, E. 2005, Bonds of Civility: Aesthetic Networks and the Political Origins of Japanese Culture, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kalai, E. and Lehrer, E. 1995, ‘Subjective Games and Equilibria’, Games and Economic Behavior, 61: 10191045.Google Scholar
Koopmans, T. 1957, Three Essays on the State of Economic Sciences, New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Kripke, S. 1963, ‘A Semantical Analysis of Modal Logic’, Acta Philosophica Fennica, 24: 8394.Google Scholar
Levi, M. 1988, Of Rule and Revenue, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, D. 1969, Conventions, A Philosophical Study, Cambridge, MA: Harvard university Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, J. W. and Rowan, B. 1977, ‘Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony’, American Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–63. Reprinted in W. W. Powel and P. DiMaggio (1991: 41–62).Google Scholar
Milgrom, P., North, D., and Weingast, B. 1990, ‘The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs’, Economics and Politics, 2: 123.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P., Qian, Y., and Roberts, J. 1991, ‘Complementarities, Momentum, and the Evolution of Modern Manufacturing’, American Economic Review, 81 (Papers and Proceedings): 8488.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. 1990, ‘Rationalizability, Learning, and Equilibrium in Games with Strategic Complementarities’, Econometrica, 59: 12551277.Google Scholar
Murdock, K. 1996, ‘The Role of Institutions in Enforcing Implicit Contracts: Analysis of Corporate and Government Policy’, Ph.D. Dissertation, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. 1995, ‘Recent Evolutionary Theorizing about Economic Change’, Journal of Economic Literature, 33: 4890.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. and Sampat, B. N. 2001, ‘Making Sense of Institutions as a Factor Shaping Economic Performance’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 44 (1): 3154.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. 1982, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. 1990, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge, UK and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. 2005, Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, M. 1993, ‘Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development’, American Political Science Review, 83: 567876.Google Scholar
Osborne, M. J. and Rubinstein, A. 1994, A Course in Game Theory, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. 1990, Governing the Commons, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, K. 1944, The Great Transformation, New York: Farrar Rinehart.Google Scholar
Powell, P. P. and DiMaggio, P. (eds) 1991, The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Prescott, E. C. and Shell, K. 2002, ‘Introduction to Sunspots and Lotteries’, Journal of Economic Theory, 107: 110.Google Scholar
Rajan, R., and Zingales, L. 2003, Saving Capitalism From the Capitalists: Unleashing the Power of Financial Markets to Create Wealth and Spread Opportunity, New York: Crown Business.Google Scholar
Roland, G. 2005, ‘Understanding Institutional Change: Fast-moving and Slow-moving Institutions’, http://emlab.berkeley.edu/users/groland/pubs/gr3.pdf.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. 1960, Strategy of Conflicts, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schotter, A. 1981, The Economic Theory of Social Institutions. Cambridge, UK and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1912/1934, The Theory of Economic Development, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press; English translation of Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung by R. Opie, 1912.Google Scholar
Scott, W. R. 1955, Institutions and Organizations, Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Searle, J. R. 1995, The Construction of Social Reality, London: Allen Lane.Google Scholar
Searle, J. R. 2005, “What is an Institution?Journal of Institutional Economics, 1: 122.Google Scholar
Shinohara, M. 2003, The Mega-growth of the Chinese Economy and Hong Kong (in Japanese), Tokyo: Keiso-Shobo.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1997, Administrative Behavior, 2nd edn, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1759/1976, The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 1986, The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Topkis, D. 1978, ‘Minimizing a Submodular Function on a Lattice’, Operations Research, 26: 305321.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. 1997, ‘The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law’, American Political Science Review, 91: 245263Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 2000, ‘The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead’, Journal of Economic Literature, 38: 595613.Google Scholar
World Bank 2002, World Development Report 2002: Building Institutions for Markets, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Young, H.P. 1998, Individual Strategy and Social Structure: An Evolutionary Theory of Institutions, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar