Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T11:36:03.826Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Like principal, like agent? Managerial preferences in employee-owned firms

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 November 2021

Guillermo Alves
Affiliation:
CAF Development Bank of Latin America, Buenos Aires, Argentina
Pablo Blanchard
Affiliation:
Universidad de la República, Montevideo, Uruguay
Gabriel Burdin*
Affiliation:
University of Leeds, Leeds, UK IZA, Bonn, Germany
Mariana Chávez
Affiliation:
Universidad de la República, Montevideo, Uruguay
Andrés Dean
Affiliation:
Universidad de la República, Montevideo, Uruguay
*
*Corresponding author. Email: g.burdin@leeds.ac.uk
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The relationship between firms’ owners and managers is a quintessential example of costly principal–agent interaction. Optimal design of monetary incentives and supervision mechanisms are the two traditional ways of reducing agency costs in this relationship. In this paper, we show evidence which is consistent with a third mechanism: firms have managers whose economic preferences are aligned with owners' interests. We uncover differences in economic preferences between managers employed in firms controlled by two distinct classes of ‘patrons’: employee-owned firms (worker cooperatives) and conventional investor-owned firms. In a high-stakes lab-in-the-field experiment, we find that co-op managers are less risk-loving and more altruistic than their conventional counterparts. We do not observe differences between the two groups in terms of time preferences, reciprocity, and trust. Our findings are consistent with existing evidence on worker cooperatives, such as their tendency to self-select into less risky industries and their compressed compensation structures.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Millennium Economics Ltd.

1. Introduction

A long tradition in economics, management, and organization studies conceptualizes the relationship between managers and firm owners using a principal–agent framework (Jensen and Meckling, Reference Jensen and Meckling1976). Two mechanisms usually receive the most attention in terms of addressing the potential divergence of interests between owners and managers. On the one hand, owners may introduce financial incentives, such as tying executives' compensation to the long-term performance of the company. On the other hand, owners may implement direct control mechanisms, such as performing frequent audits and evaluations. In the last few decades, the standard agency framework has been criticized for relying on a restrictive set of behavioral assumptions (Pepper and Gore, Reference Pepper and Gore2015). Moreover, advances in experimental and behavioral economics have inspired a potential third mechanism, which focuses on having managers with the ‘right’ preferences as a way of reducing the wedge between owners and managers' interests (Akerlof and Kranton, Reference Akerlof and Kranton2005; Ben-Ner, Reference Ben-Ner2013; Besley and Ghatak, Reference Besley and Ghatak2005; Fehr et al., Reference Fehr, Gächter and Kirchsteiger1997).

If managerial preferences are relevant for aligning owners and managers' incentives and thus reducing agency costs, we should empirically observe firms controlled by different principals having managers with different preferences. In this paper, we compare economic preferences between managers employed in two sharply distinct organizational settings: employee-owned firms (worker cooperatives) and conventional investor-owned firms. Worker cooperatives are owned and democratically managed by their workers. This introduces a set of differences in their objectives compared to conventional firms (Bonin et al., Reference Bonin, Jones and Putterman1993). Two of these differences are particularly relevant for the managerial preferences examined in this paper. First, worker-owners' relatively low wealth and excessive concentration of financial and labor risk in the firm they own and work for make them less oriented to choose risky investment projects (Bonin et al., Reference Bonin, Jones and Putterman1993; Drèze, Reference Drèze1976; Hansmann, Reference Hansmann1988). Second, as in standard median-voter redistribution models, co-ops have relatively more egalitarian earning structures (Abramitzky, Reference Abramitzky2008; Burdín, Reference Burdín2016; Dow, Reference Dow2018; Kremer, Reference Kremer1997; Montero, Reference Montero2020).

We conduct a lab-in-the-field experiment to gather incentive-compatible measures of risk preferences, time preferences, and social preferences (altruism, reciprocity, and trust) from 196 Uruguayan managers. Half of these managers work in worker cooperatives and the other half in conventional private-sector firms. The two subsamples of managers are balanced in terms of demographic (age, gender, and education) and firm-level characteristics (size and industry composition). In order to have a benchmark for managers' preferences, we further implemented the same experiment with a sample of 92 first-year undergraduate students. We conducted the experiment in Uruguay using oTree, an open-source platform for implementing economic experiments (Chen et al., Reference Chen, Schonger and Wickens2016). The average payment in the experiment was two times higher than the average hourly managerial wage in the Uruguayan private sector. We measured risk aversion and impatience by using lottery choice and inter-temporal choice experiments based on multiple price lists (MPLs) (Falk et al., Reference Falk, Becker, Dohmen, Huffman and Sunde2016). To measure altruism, we relied on a standard Dictator Game. We elicited trust and positive reciprocity as first- and second-mover behavior in the Trust Game (Berg et al., Reference Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe1995). To measure negative reciprocity, we used subjects' minimum acceptable offer (MAO) in an Ultimatum Game (Güth et al., Reference Güth, Schmittberger and Schwarze1982). A crucial advantage of lab-in-the-field experiments is that they are conducted in a naturalistic environment targeting a theoretically relevant population without losing control of experimental conditions, combining the benefits of both laboratory and field experiments (Gneezy et al., Reference Gneezy, Leibbrandt and List2016).

We find that the fraction of risk-loving subjects among co-op managers is 10 percentage points lower than among conventional managers. Moreover, co-op managers are more altruistic than their conventional counterparts. Dictator game transfers are, on average, 6 percentage points higher for co-op managers compared to their conventional counterparts. We also find that co-op managers are significantly more (less) likely to implement the perfectly egalitarian (selfish) allocation than conventional managers. Importantly, because these differences in preferences could be correlated with other firm and manager characteristics differing between co-ops and for-profits, we report that preference differences are robust to controlling for a set of managers' characteristics (age, education, and gender) and firms' characteristics (size and industry). We do not observe significant differences between the two groups in terms of time preferences, trust, and reciprocity. Behavioral differences between co-op and conventional managers are broadly consistent with the fact that the two types of managers report to principals (employee-owners and investors, respectively) who have a different set of objectives and preferences (Ben-Ner et al., Reference Ben-Ner, Montias and Neuberger1993).

Our study contributes to the existing literature in two distinct ways. First, our paper adds to the literature on behavioral agency theory (Pepper and Gore, Reference Pepper and Gore2015; Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia, Reference Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia1998). We use incentivized lab-in-the-field experiments to uncover the prevalence of non-standard preferences among managers, providing a new reassessment of the behavioral assumptions of the standard agency framework. By comparing managers employed in conventional firms and worker cooperatives, we move beyond the traditional focus on family firms (Neacsu et al., Reference Neacsu, Gomez-Mejia and Martin2014).Footnote 1 In a study similar to ours, Fehr and List (Reference Fehr and List2004) compare the trusting behavior of CEOs and students and find that CEOs are significantly more trustful and display more trustworthiness than students. Koudstaal et al. (Reference Koudstaal, Sloof and van Praag2016) conduct a lab-in-the-field experiment comparing entrepreneurs to managers and employees in terms of risk preferences. They find that the three groups are not different in terms of risk aversion, but entrepreneurs are less loss-averse than managers and employees. Opper et al. (Reference Opper, Nee and Holm2017) study risk preferences in a sample of CEOs of private manufacturing companies in China and document correlations between elicited risk attitudes and corporate strategic choices and performance. Nee et al. (Reference Nee, Holm and Opper2018) elicit trust among Chinese CEOs and uncover a relationship between CEO experience in relational exchange and generalized trust. Finally, Holm et al. (Reference Holm, Nee and Opper2020) study the strategic behavior of CEOs of private firms in experimental games. They show that CEOs differ from other people in strategic decision-making and beliefs about the strategy of others. We add to this literature by comparing a wide range of economic preferences across managers employed in two sharply different organizational settings. Our findings are consistent with well-known facts about the behavior of worker cooperatives in market economies, such as their tendency to select into less risky and less capital-intensive industries and their more egalitarian compensation structures (Dow, Reference Dow2018). Hence, our paper also relates to behavioral strategy research, which highlights the connection between managers' behavioral preferences and firm-level strategic choices and outcomes (Powell et al., Reference Powell, Lovallo and Fox2011).

Second, we contribute to the study of worker cooperatives, employee ownership, and alternative enterprise forms. Despite their prominent economic role in modern economies (Hansmann, Reference Hansmann, Gibbons and Roberts2012), these alternative organizational forms have received far less attention than conventional profit maximizing firms in organization studies (Gibbons and Roberts, Reference Gibbons, Roberts, Scott and Kosslyn2015).Footnote 2 Importantly, the behavior of managers has been largely overlooked in the previous theoretical and empirical literature on worker cooperatives.Footnote 3 As pointed out by Atkinson (Reference Atkinson1973), this omission may be due to the long-standing practice of assuming that worker cooperatives coherently pursue a single objective of maximizing income per worker. This assumption rules out the problem of separation of ownership and control arising in any large (conventional or cooperative) firm operating under the control of appointed managers, rendering the issue of managerial behavior of only secondary analytical importance. Ben-Ner and Ellman (Reference Ben-Ner and Ellman2013) argue that the long-run success of worker cooperatives may depend on their ability to attract and retain the appropriate mix of behavioral types. They highlight the role of social preferences and personality traits in mitigating shop-floor work incentive problems, but do not address the issue of selection into top management positions. Few papers provide evidence on individuals' prosociality in cooperatives. Ruffle and Sosis (Reference Ruffle and Sosis2006) find that kibbutz members and non-members exhibit similar levels of cooperation when faced with anonymous outsiders. Gneezy et al. (Reference Gneezy, Leibbrandt and List2016) conduct economic experiments in two Brazilian fisherman societies that differ in their workplace organization and find that fishermen cooperate and trust more when fishing is organized in teams rather than as an individual activity. Hopfensitz and Miquel-Florensa (Reference Hopfensitz and Miquel-Florensa2017) find that cooperative farmers in Costa Rica do not contribute more than private market farmers to a common fund. A set of recent theoretical papers have analyzed the importance of attracting socially motivated managers for non-profit organizations and social enterprises (Besley and Ghatak, Reference Besley and Ghatak2005, Reference Besley and Ghatak2017). To our knowledge, our paper is one of the first attempts to use economic experiments to assess the behavioral pattern of selection of managers into worker cooperatives.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the conceptual framework and hypotheses. Section 3 explains the experimental design. Section 4 presents our five main findings on managers' risk preferences, impatience, altruism, negative reciprocity, and trusting behavior. Section 5 concludes and discusses limitations and future research.

2. Conceptual framework and hypotheses

Controllers or principals are those members of the organization who collectively have the ultimate right to make decisions and delegate authority to managers or other agents (Bolton and Dewatripont, Reference Bolton, Dewatripont, Gibbons and Roberts2012; Hansmann, Reference Hansmann1988). Principals obtain their positions through the ownership of firms (Ben-Ner et al., Reference Ben-Ner, Montias and Neuberger1993). Principals are constrained by the extent to which managers are willing to cooperate and advance principals' goals. Managers may behave opportunistically and not follow owners' objectives (Jensen and Meckling, Reference Jensen and Meckling1979).

Firms can be classified according to the identity of the ultimate control group. Usually, the control group is made of persons or entities (‘patrons’) who share a common transactional relationship with the firm, either as buyers of the goods produced by the firm or as suppliers of production inputs (Hansmann, Reference Hansmann1988). In conventional investor-owned firms, control rights belong to capital suppliers. By contrast, in worker cooperatives the decisive authority collectively rests on the workforce. Given differences in the identity of their patrons, we expect to observe differences in economic preferences between managers employed in these two types of organizations. More importantly, we expect those differences to follow a pattern that is consistent with the reduction of agency costs. Next, we discuss which preferences may better align managers' decisions with owners' interests in different areas of the administration of the firm. We draw our hypotheses from existing theoretical and empirical studies on worker cooperatives.Footnote 4

2.1 Risk preferences

A long-standing explanation of the paucity of worker cooperatives in market economies rests on the idea that worker-owners may face a higher cost of risk bearing than investors. Members of a worker cooperative would be less able to cope with risk as their financial wealth and human capital are tied up in the same company (Bonin et al., Reference Bonin, Jones and Putterman1993; Drèze, Reference Drèze1976; Meade, Reference Meade1972). The preference for holding a diversified financial portfolio would be even more important when workers have firm-specific human capital (Dow, Reference Dow2018). Hence, risk-averse worker-owners would prefer to invest in relatively more conservative projects and rely on external funding.Footnote 5 Podivinsky and Stewart (Reference Podivinsky and Stewart2007) and Belloc (Reference Belloc2017) show, in fact, that worker cooperatives tend to avoid risky environments, i.e. they are less likely to enter industries in which the variance in profits is high. Moreover, there is extensive evidence showing that worker cooperatives absorb negative economic shocks through changes in income rather than layoffs (Burdín and Dean, Reference Burdín and Dean2009; Craig and Pencavel, Reference Craig and Pencavel1992; Pencavel et al., Reference Pencavel, Pistaferri and Schivardi2006).Footnote 6 This suggests that worker cooperatives attract members with a strong preference for job security (Dow, Reference Dow2018). When workers (instead of investors) act as principals in the owner–manager relationship, they may select managers that are relatively less willing to take risks.

Hypothesis 1. Co-op managers are less willing to take risks than managers employed in conventional firms.

2.2. Time preferences

Members of worker cooperatives make critical intertemporal choices regarding how to distribute the surplus between current and future consumption, i.e. between members' compensation in the current period and investment. A well-known argument states that worker cooperatives may suffer from the so-called ‘horizon problem’ (Furubotn, Reference Furubotn1976; Jensen and Meckling, Reference Jensen and Meckling1979).Footnote 7 If the assets of the cooperative are collectively owned, members have no claim on the return of investments after separation from their firm. Although the entrepreneur in a conventional business can fully pocket the investment proceeds, cooperative members can only enjoy investment returns while remaining in the firm. Hence, members' willingness to reinvest in the cooperative depends on how long they expect to stay in the firm and the expected return of the investment compared to workers' opportunity cost of the funds. If the expected employment period of members is shorter than the productive life of potential assets, this would imply that the rate of time preference (or discount rate) used in the evaluation of investment projects will be higher in cooperatives than in conventional firms.Footnote 8 Indeed, compulsory profit plow-back rules force worker cooperatives in many countries to accumulate a share of profits into asset locks (Navarra, Reference Navarra2016; Pérotin, Reference Pérotin2013). In our context, these rules could be interpreted as a commitment device aimed at helping worker-members to avoid self-destructing inter-temporal choices. Overall, we expect cooperative members would generally select and instruct managers to implement projects yielding smaller-sooner returns rather than larger-later returns.

Hypothesis 2. Co-op managers are more impatient than managers employed in conventional firms.

2.3 Social preferences

Social preferences have received increasing attention in organization studies (Ben-Ner, Reference Ben-Ner2013; Ben-Ner and Ellman, Reference Ben-Ner and Ellman2013; Camerer and Malmendier, Reference Camerer, Malmendier, Diamond and Vartiainen2007). The term refers to individuals' concern for the payoffs allocated to other individuals and the intentions that led to such payoffs (Camerer and Fehr, Reference Camerer, Fehr, Henrich, Boyd, Bowles, Camerer, Fehr and Gintis2004; Carpenter, Reference Carpenter and Macmillan2008). This definition includes altruism, reciprocity, and trusting behavior, among other prosocial behaviors.Footnote 9

Several management decisions entail within-firm distributional consequences with heterogeneous effects on different segments of the workforce. These decisions cover a wide range of managerial actions, from the definition of compensation schemes to the setting of rules regarding work conditions and required effort levels. Similarly to median-voter models of redistribution in democratic societies, cooperatives are democratic organizations and, as such, they tend to implement more egalitarian compensation schemes and working conditions (Kremer, Reference Kremer1997). Members may then want to recruit relatively more equality-oriented managers, so they are more likely to implement more egalitarian decisions.

A consequence of cooperatives' egalitarian policies that reinforces their preference for more equality-oriented managers relates to the brain-drain risks faced by this type of egalitarian organizations (Abramitzky, Reference Abramitzky2011; Burdín, Reference Burdín2016). Given that managers themselves will usually be the highest-paid worker in the co-op, they may be less likely to leave if they derive utility from themselves having a less advantageous position in the firm's earnings distribution. The lower managerial pay in cooperatives compared to conventional firms may also help to screen in more altruistic managers. Therefore, we expect altruistic preferences to be more important among co-op managers compared to their conventional peers.Footnote 10

In principle, we do not expect to observe differences between co-op and conventional managers in terms of other types of social preferences, such as reciprocity and trust. First, worker cooperatives are characterized by a dual-governance structure. On the one hand, workers-principals appoint managers, set objectives, and control how firm policies are implemented. On the other hand, managers act as quasi-principals organizing and monitoring the actions of the workers. However, although workers have the power to dismiss managers, managers cannot replace workers without a collective decision from the cooperative membership (Ben-Ner et al., Reference Ben-Ner, Montias and Neuberger1993). Overall, cooperatives offer little room for managers to reciprocate workers' actions, positively or negatively, by targeting rewards or imposing sanctions. Second, Ben-Ner and Ellman (Reference Ben-Ner and Ellman2013) highlight the role of trust in sustaining conditional cooperation in cooperatives. However, they also flag the risk of negative selection with opportunistic types seeking to join cooperatives to take advantage of trusting members.Footnote 11

Hypothesis 3. Co-op managers are more altruistic than managers employed in conventional firms.

3. Experimental design and procedures

3.1 Practical procedures

We collect experimental measures of risk, time, and social preferences. To do this, the standard procedure is to conduct incentivized experiments in a university computer laboratory using student subjects. Given the unconventional nature of our subject pool (managers), their relatively high opportunity cost of time (e.g. relevant for commuting to the laboratory site), and the complex logistics related to organizing conventional laboratory sessions, we decided to implement an online experiment. Online experiments have grown exponentially in the last few decades, particularly since the development of online labor markets such as Mturk. Horton et al. (Reference Horton, Rand and Zeckhauser2011) show that online experiments can quantitatively reproduce behavior from the physical laboratory. Eckel and Wilson (Reference Eckel and Wilson2006) discuss potential threats to the validity of online experiments. In the context of the present study, the use of online experiments is a pragmatic solution to the problem of recruiting subjects with a relatively high opportunity cost of time.

We implemented our online experiment using oTree (Chen et al., Reference Chen, Schonger and Wickens2016). oTree is an open-source software platform that allows running experiments remotely. oTree use provides a highly flexible solution as managers can participate in the experiment from their own locations at any time by relying on a wide range of devices (desktop computers, tablets, and phones). In total, 288 subjects participated in our study. This included 96 cooperative managers, 100 conventional managers, and 92 students. Managers correspond to the highest-ranked worker in firms' hierarchical structure. Thus, each manager in the experiment corresponds to a single firm. The sample of managers comes from a firm-level survey conducted by members of the research team in 2011 (Alves et al., Reference Alves, Burdin, Carrasco, Dean and Rius2012). Cooperatives in this survey were representative of the universe of Uruguay cooperatives. Conventional firms participating in the survey were representative of conventional firms in economic sectors with the presence of worker cooperatives.

The 96 cooperatives with managers participating in our experiment account for 22% of the population of Uruguayan worker cooperatives registered in 2016. Managers in cooperatives are appointed by worker-members and take care of the daily operation of the company, consulting members when it comes to making strategic decisions (e.g. investments). Uruguayan worker cooperatives usually fill managerial positions by relying on members rather than on hired labor.

Participation in the experiment was voluntary and subjects were free to quit the experiment at any time. A few manager subjects started the experiment but did not complete all of the experiment's phases or did not provide their bank account information to receive the payment. We do not consider these subjects in any of the paper's results. In the invitation letter distributed among participants, we explained the purpose of the study in very general terms (‘the objective of this research project is to analyse human behaviour in various situations’). This should mitigate concerns about potential experimenter effects, as participants had no clue about the details of the study.

We recruited students by e-mail through the student list of a first-year undergraduate course at the Business and Economics School of National University of Uruguay (Universidad de la República). An initial e-mail invitation was sent out asking for those interested in participating in the study. Responders were then contacted via e-mail providing them with information about the procedure to participate online, potential earnings, and rules of payment. Managers were contacted by phone and then received an e-mail invitation with information about the experiment's general procedure and expected earnings. After accepting to participate in the experiment, subjects received an e-mail with a unique URL to the experiment. These URLs contained a random code so even if participants communicated with one another, the link would not allow them to identify other players. This is particularly important for the Ultimatum and Trust games, which involve sequential strategic interactions. The same experimental protocol was applied to all subjects. Payoffs earned in the incentivized experiments were paid out to subjects by bank transfer in the same week they completed the experiment, except for the time discounting experiment that involved payments after 3 and 6 months. Online sessions lasted about 40 minutes and the average payoff was 1,027 Uruguayan pesos (34 US dollars at the time), including a show-up fee of 480 Uruguayan pesos. The stake is two times higher than the average hourly managerial wage in the Uruguayan private sector as reported in the official household survey. We conducted the experiment in 2018. The experiments with students extended over a couple of weeks between February and March and the experiments with managers took place between May and November.

In Table 1, we report descriptive statistics on observable characteristics for the three groups of subjects. The table shows that the subsamples of co-op and conventional managers are balanced in terms of demographic (age, gender, and education) and firm-level characteristics (size and industry composition). Students are obviously younger than managers on average.

Table 1. Descriptive statistics

Notes: Firm size categories defined as follows: small firms (less than 20 employees), medium firms (20–99 employees), and large firms (100+ employees). Standard deviation in parenthesis. In column (4), we report the difference in means test between co-op and conventional managers. In column (5), we compare managers and students.

3.2 Description of experiments

We rely on standard incentivized tasks and experimental games designed to elicit risk preferences, impatience, altruism, trust, and positive and negative reciprocity. The experiments' design follows Falk et al. (Reference Falk, Becker, Dohmen, Huffman and Sunde2016) closely. Monetary stakes were presented in points (100 points = 21 Uruguayan pesos = 0.7 US dollars). All experimental games involving strategic interactions were one-shot games in order to avoid repeated game effects. Subjects were told that they were interacting with another (anonymous) participant remotely located and that they were not going to play with the same partner more than once. We did not make participants' identities, i.e. managers employed in cooperatives and conventional firms, salient in any particular way. Participants then knew that they were interacting with human subjects but did not know about any characteristics of those subjects. In the Dictator, Ultimatum, and Trust games (see below), each subject played the game twice, once in each role. As our focus is on between-subject comparisons, choice experiments were presented in the same order to all subjects.Footnote 12

3.2.1 Risk preferences

We elicited risk preferences by using an MPL in which subjects choose between a lottery and varying safe options (Charness et al., Reference Charness, Gneezy and Kuhn2013; Dohmen et al., Reference Dohmen, Falk, Golsteyn, Huffman and Sunde2017; Holt and Laury, Reference Holt and Laury2002). We presented participants a list of 21 decisions between two options: a safe one (option A) and a risky one with known probabilities (option B). In each row, option B corresponded to earning 1,000 points with a 50% chance or zero points with a 50% chance. The safe option A, on the contrary, gradually increased from zero (row 1) to 1,000 points (row 21). After a participant made a decision for each row, we randomly determined which row was relevant for the participant's payoff. Depending on the subject's choice in that row, her payoff would be either the safe option or the outcome of the lottery. This procedure guarantees that each decision is incentive-compatible (Dohmen et al., Reference Dohmen, Falk, Golsteyn, Huffman and Sunde2017). Our measure of risk is the value of the safe option at the switching row, i.e. the row in which subjects switch from preferring the lottery to the safe payment.Footnote 13 Following Holt and Laury (Reference Holt and Laury2002), as long as subjects have monotonic preferences, they will prefer the lottery up to a certain level of the safe option, and then switch to preferring the safe option in all subsequent rows of the price list. The value of the safe option at the switching point is usually interpreted as subjects' certainty equivalent. The higher the value of the safe option, the greater is the individual's willingness to take risks. Risk-averse subjects should prefer safe options that are smaller than or equal to 500 points (the expected value of the lottery) over the lottery. Only risk-loving subjects should prefer the lottery when the offered safe payment is greater than 500 points.

3.2.2 Time discounting

We elicited time preferences by using an MPL, in which subjects choose between a payment today (400 points) and a larger delayed payment in 3 months. The early payment was always 400 points and the delayed payment increased by 10 points in each subsequent row, starting from 430 points in the first row and reaching 660 points in the 24th row. The first-row value implied an inflation-discounted annual return rate of around 24% and the value in the 24th row reached an annual return rate of around 600%. Our experimental measure of impatience is the value of the delayed payment (the implied rate of return) that is necessary to induce the subject to wait 3 months, i.e. the row in which the subject switches from the early payment to the delayed payment.Footnote 14 Similar to the procedure used in the domain of risk, after participants made a decision in each row, we randomly determined which row was relevant for the participant's payoff. To reinforce subjects' credibility about the experiment and its associated payment, we attached a letter signed by the School's Dean. We also implemented a second MPL in which we introduced front-end delay (shift horizon design): subjects choose between an early payment in 3 months and a larger payment in 6 months. The within-subject comparison between the front-end delay and no front-end delay choice sets conveys information on the extent of present bias or dynamic inconsistency among subjects (Frederick et al., Reference Frederick, Loewenstein and O'Donoghue2002).

3.2.3 Altruism

We measured altruism by the share of the endowment (300 points) transferred by dictators in a standard Dictator game. In this game, the Dictator decides how to split the endowment between herself and another player, the Recipient (Forsythe et al., Reference Forsythe, Horowitz, Savin and Sefton1994; Kahneman et al., Reference Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler1986). The standard prediction assuming self-regarding dictators is that subjects would share nothing with the Recipient and keep the whole endowment for themselves.

3.2.4 Trust

We elicited trust as the first mover's behavior in the Trust game (Berg et al., Reference Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe1995). More precisely, we measure trust as the amount sent by the first mover (‘Trustor’) in this game. In our trust game, a Trustor and Trustee each receive an initial endowment of 250 points. The Trustor can invest all or part of her money by sending any amount y ∈ {0, 50, 100, 150, 200, 250} to the Trustee. The experimenter then triples the amount sent, so that the Trustee receives 3y. The Trustee then decides to return any amount z between 0 and 3y + 250 to the Trustor. As a result of these decisions, the Trustor and Trustee's final payoffs are 250 − y + z and 250 + 3y − z, respectively. The standard prediction is that self-regarding trustees will return z = 0. Anticipating that, a self-regarding Trustor should transfer nothing (y = 0).

3.2.5 Reciprocity

Following Fehr and Gächter (Reference Fehr and Gächter2000), a preference for reciprocity is the desire to punish others seen as harming one (negative reciprocity) and the desire to benefit others seen as benefiting one (positive reciprocity). We measured negative reciprocity with the MAO in the Ultimatum game (Güth et al., Reference Güth, Schmittberger and Schwarze1982). In the Ultimatum game, a Proposer makes an offer y regarding the division of an initial endowment (500 points) between herself and a Responder. The Responder can either accept or reject the offer. In the latter case (y < MAO), both players earn zero. If the Responder accepts the offer (y ≥ MAO), she earns y and the Proposer earns 500 − y. The higher the MAO, the more subjects are willing to forgo their monetary gain in order to punish unfair offers. The standard prediction for this game is that self-regarding responders will accept any positive offer and that Proposers will offer the smallest possible positive amount. Finally, we elicit positive reciprocity as the second mover behavior in the Trust game and measure it as the amount sent back in that game. We relied on the strategy method, which implies that participants make conditional decisions for the same discrete set of predetermined offers.Footnote 15

4. Results

This section presents our main findings. We are interested in understanding whether managers employed in cooperatives exhibit different economic preferences than managers employed in conventional enterprises. For each preference domain, we compare the two subsamples of managers. We also report the results for the student pool in order to have a conventional subject pool as a benchmark.

Result 1. The share of risk-loving subjects is significantly lower among co-op managers than among managers employed in conventional firms.

We measure risk attitudes by looking at the value of the safe option at the switching row for each individual, i.e. the point in which the individual switches from the lottery to the safe payment. The higher a subject's certainty equivalent, the greater her willingness to take risk.

In Figure 1 (panel a), we plot the mean safe option for each of the three groups. The difference between co-op and conventional managers is not significant according to a Mann–Whitney test (p-value = 0.3168).Footnote 16 The associated median coefficient of relative risk aversion lies within the interval 0.13–0.24 for cooperative managers and 0–0.13 for conventional managers and students.Footnote 17

Figure 1. Risk preferences. (a) Mean safe payment at switching row. (b) Distribution of risk preferences by group.

Notes: In panel (a), the figure displays the average value of the safe payment at the switching row by group. Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.3168 (0.1169). N: Co-op managers = 83, conventional managers = 88, students = 90. In panel (b), the figure displays the distribution of risk preferences in terms of risk loving, risk averse and risk neutral subjects. Fisher's exact test (risk lovers) co-ops versus conv.: p-value = 0.051. N: Co-op managers = 96, conv. managers = 99, students = 92.

As shown in Figure 1 (panel b), the proportions of risk-neutral, risk-loving, and risk-averse subjects differ between co-op and conventional managers. Subjects are risk-neutral if they prefer the safe option to a lottery with the same expected value (i.e. 500 points) but choose the lottery for smaller values of the safe option; or if they play the lottery when the safe option is 500 points but do not play the lottery when the safe option is greater than the lottery's expected value. Subjects are risk-loving (risk-averse) if they prefer (not) to play the lottery when the safe option is larger (smaller) than the lottery's expected value. The share of risk-neutral and risk-averse subjects is not statistically different across groups at conventional values but there is a significant difference of around 10 percentage points between cooperative managers and both conventional managers and students in the share of risk-loving subjects.

To investigate this difference further, we estimate a series of Probit models in which the dependent variable equals 1 if the subject is risk loving and 0 otherwise, and the independent variable of interest is a co-op dummy. We further control for gender, age, and education. Results reported in Table A.1 in the online Supplementary Appendix reinforce the conclusion of risk-loving subjects being more common among the sample of conventional managers. The status of co-op manager is associated with a significant reduction of 10 percentage points in the probability of being a risk-loving subject, even after controlling for managers' characteristics (gender, age, and education) and firms' size and industry (column 3).Footnote 18

Result 2. There are no differences in the average degree of impatience between co-op and conventional managers. The share of dynamically inconsistent subjects is also similar across groups.

In the inter-temporal choice experiments, subjects made choices between a fixed immediate payment (400 points) and a (larger) payment to be received in 3 months. As explained in section 3, subjects also made inter-temporal choices across a 3–6 months' time horizon. As described above, the delayed payment becomes increasingly attractive as we increased its value from 430 points in row 1 to 660 points in row 24. Our experimental measure of impatience is the value of the delayed payment at the row in which subjects switch from the immediate to the delayed payment. The higher the value of the delayed payment required to postpone an immediate reward, the more impatient the subject is.

In Figure 2 (panel a), we display the mean delayed payment for the three groups in the no front-end delay (0–3 months). The difference between co-op and conventional managers is not significant according to a Mann–Whitney test (p-value = 0.7557). Regression analysis further confirms that there are no differences between the two types of managers (Tables OA.3.3 to OA.3.6 in the online Appendix). Figure 2 does not include subjects who were always impatient or always patient. Figure A.4 in the online Appendix shows the fraction of always-impatient (panel A) and always-patient (panel B) subjects by group under both the no front-end delay (left) and front-end delay condition (right). About 18% of co-op managers and 15% of conventional managers behave in that way in the no front-end delay condition. The conclusions do not change if we impute extreme values of the delayed payment to these subjects.Footnote 19

Figure 2. Time preferences. (a) Mean delayed payment by group. (b) Distribution of time preferences by group.

Notes: In panel (a), the figure displays the average delayed payment at the switching row by group (0–3 months). Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.7557 (0.2162). N: Co-op managers = 79, conventional managers = 85, students = 81. In panel (b), the figure displays the distribution of subjects' types in terms of constant discounters, future-biased, and present-biased subjects. Fisher's exact test (constant discounters) co-op versus conv.: p-value = 0.3390. N: Co-op managers = 87, conventional managers = 90, students = 79.

We exploit the within-subject comparison of intertemporal choices made under the two time frames to assess the extent of dynamic inconsistent behavior among cooperative managers. More precisely, we compute the fraction of subjects who were more, less, or equally patient in the 0–3 months than in the 3–6 months' horizon. We classify subjects as present-biased if they behave more impatiently (i.e. greater delayed payment at switching row) in 0–3 months than in 3–6 months. In other words, present-biased individuals are more impatient in the present than in the future. On the contrary, future-biased subjects behave more impatiently in the 3–6 month choice set than in the 0–3 month choice set. Finally, constant discounters are those who were equally patient in both choice sets. We report the composition of the three groups in Figure 2 (panel b). Approximately half of the cooperative managers made choices consistent with constant discounting. The share of present-biased subjects is similar across groups, ranging from 20 to 27%. None of the differences is statistically significant according to Fisher's exact tests.

In Figure 3, we plot the fraction of patient subjects at each decision row for each group in both intertemporal choice sets (0–3 months and 3–6 months). This reinforces the idea that cooperative managers' time discounting behavior is similar to the other two groups. As expected, the fraction of subjects choosing to wait increases with the amount of the delayed payment for all groups and in both choice sets. This is reassuring considering that subjects' revealed time preferences in the 0–3 months' choice may be confounded with risk aversion and credibility concerns. Individuals may attach greater risk to delayed compensation than to the immediate payment. In the 3–6 months' choice, as both payments are dated in the future, we are holding constant any perceived risk attached to future payments (Bettinger and Slonim, Reference Bettinger and Slonim2007).

Result 3. Co-op managers appear to be more altruistic than their conventional counterparts, according to their behavior in the Dictator game. The share of subjects implementing the perfectly egalitarian (selfish) allocation is higher (lower) among cooperative managers.

Figure 3. Fraction of patient subjects by group. (a) No front-end delay (0–3 months). (b) Front-end delay (3–6 months).

Notes: This figure displays the fraction of subjects that chose the larger-later payment for each value of the later payment. Panel (a): no front-end delay condition (0–3 months). Panel (b): front-end delay condition (3–6 months).

Our measure of altruism is the fraction of the endowment transferred to the other subject in a standard Dictator game. Figure 4 reports the mean give rate by group. On average, co-op managers transferred 44% of the initial endowment. This compares to a mean give rate of 38 and 31% among conventional managers and students, respectively. Differences in generosity between co-op and conventional managers are statistically significant (Mann–Whitney test: p-value = 0.0382). Students are the least generous group in our experiment, even though their average contribution is in line with previous studies.Footnote 20

Figure 4. Give rate in Dictator game by group.

Notes: This figure displays the fraction of Dictators' endowment transferred to Recipients (give rate) by group. Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.0382 (0.000). N: Co-op managers = 96, conventional managers = 100, students = 92.

In Table A.2 in the online Appendix, we report Tobit model estimates in which we regress the give rate on a co-op dummy and controls for managers' age, gender, education, firm size, and industry dummies. Estimates of the coefficient associated with the co-op dummy are consistently positive with a magnitude around seven percentage points, but imprecisely estimated.

In Figure 5, we report the distribution of give rates by group. For managers, in line with previous studies, we find a bimodal distribution with one main mode at giving nothing and the other one at splitting the endowment equally. On the one hand, about 56% of co-op managers split the endowment equally. This compares to 37 and 27% of conventional managers and students, respectively. On the other hand, the fraction of co-op managers whose behavior conforms to the standard prediction based on selfish players is 5%. This share rises to 18 and 22% for conventional managers and students, respectively. Regression analysis reported in Table A.3 in the online Appendix further confirms these differences. The fraction of cooperative managers implementing the egalitarian allocation is 21 p.p. higher compared to conventional managers, after controlling for individual and firm-level characteristics (column 3). Consistently, the fraction of purely selfish players is 13 p.p. lower among cooperative managers (column 6).

Result 4. There are no differences in the share of the endowment offered in the Ultimatum game. Moreover, the comparison of minimum acceptable offers does not reveal significant differences in terms of negative reciprocity.

Figure 5. Distribution of give rates in Dictator game by group.

Notes: This figure displays the distribution of give rates by group. N: Co-op managers = 96, conventional managers = 100, students = 92.

In Figure 6, we report the mean offer (panel a) and the MAO (panel b) for each group. The observed range of average offers is in line with previous studies (Oosterbeek et al., Reference Oosterbeek, Sloof and Kuilen2004) and we find no significant differences in the behavior of subjects playing as proposers. Co-op managers offered, on average, 44% of the endowment, whereas offers by conventional managers and students were 46 and 42%, respectively.Footnote 21

Figure 6. Ultimatum game. (a) Proposers: mean offer. (b) Respondents: MAO.

Notes: In panel (a), the figure displays the mean offer made Proposers in the Ultimatum game. Panel (a): Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.3020 (0.0291). In panel (b), the figure displays the MAO elicited from Respondents. Panel (b): Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.1931 (0.0181). Both panels: N: Co-op managers = 96, conventional managers = 100, students = 92.

The comparison of the Dictator and Ultimatum games reveals some suggestive patterns. The strategic nature of the UG implies that subjects with different degrees of altruism may exhibit similar choices. For example, in the canonical Fehr and Schmidt (Reference Fehr and Schmidt1999) model of inequity aversion, under moderate degrees of other-regarding preferences UG proposals do not depend on proposers' degree of inequity aversion but only on their expectations about receivers' preferences. In our context, this might explain why co-op and conventional managers exhibit similar proposer behavior in the UG game although DG results show that co-op managers are more altruistic. In relative terms, co-op managers transferred the same amount in the two games. By contrast, the behavior of the other two groups (conventional managers and students) reacted sharply to the new strategic incentives embedded in the Ultimatum game, rising their transfers by 8–11 p.p. compared to the Dictator game.

In Figure A.7 in the online Appendix, we report the cumulative distribution function of the fraction offered in the DG and UG. The distributions for conventional managers and students exhibit the usual pattern. The dictator game's cumulative distribution is consistent with DG offers being less generous than UG offers. Precisely, the only group for which we cannot reject the equality of the two distributions is the group of co-op managers (Kolmogorov–Smirnov test: p-value = 0.139). Acting in the role of proposers and given the veto power that responders have in this game, conventional managers and students' behavior partly reflects the strategic concern of avoiding a rejection.

Turning to responders' behavior, we rely on the MAO in the UG as a measure of negative reciprocity, i.e. a subject's willingness to punish unfair proposers at a material cost to herself. In Figure 6 (panel b), we report the average MAO by group. Acting as responders, co-op managers' MAO is approximately 40% of the endowment. Conventional managers are willing to accept slightly lower offers. However, the difference between the two groups is not statistically significant. The resulting average rejection rate was roughly 25% and similar across groups.

Result 5. Subjects' behavior in the Trust game reveals that trust and trustworthiness are not significantly different between co-op and conventional managers.

Trust can be defined as a subject's deliberate willingness to make herself vulnerable to the actions of another party (Kocher et al., Reference Kocher, Pogrebna and Sutter2013; Rousseau et al., Reference Rousseau, Sitkin, Burt and Camerer1998). In the context of the Trust game, the Trustor's trust is the willingness to transfer a positive amount to the other player with the expectation that the other person will reciprocate at her own cost. The amount returned by the trustee is commonly interpreted as a proxy for this subject's trustworthiness. Although trusting behavior allows implementing Pareto-superior allocations, it is risky for the trustor because a selfish trustee has an incentive to keep everything. Hence, trusting trustors are vulnerable to exploitation.

Figure 7 reports information on trustors (panel a) and trustees' behavior (panel b), respectively. On average, managers transferred 60% of the endowment.Footnote 22 There are no differences between co-op and conventional managers. Interestingly, students trust significantly less than managers in our experiment. This is consistent with previous evidence comparing CEOs and students and with the fact that trust increases with age (Fehr and List, Reference Fehr and List2004). This may be explained by managers' greater reliance on relational exchange in markets compared to students (Nee et al., Reference Nee, Holm and Opper2018).

Figure 7. Trust game. (a) Mean Trustor's transfer. (b) Trustee's back-transfers for each possible Trustors' transfer value.

Notes: In panel (a), the figure displays the mean Trustors' transfer by group. Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.6070 (0.0074). N: Co-op managers = 96, conventional managers = 100, students = 92. In panel (b), the figure displays Trustees' back-transfers elicited for each possible Trustors' transfer value using the strategy method.

The behavior of trustees suggests a similar pattern. We elicit trustees' choices using the strategy method. Panel b of Figure 7 reports the amount returned by trustees for each possible value of trustors' transfers.Footnote 23 On average, trustees return 34.7% of the total amount available to return. We do not observe differences in subjects' trustworthiness between co-op and conventional managers. This is confirmed when controlling for their socioeconomic characteristics (age, gender, and education), for firms' characteristics, and for managers' risk attitudes.Footnote 24 The amount returned by trustees increases with the amount transferred by trustors. There is also some indication that managers exhibit greater trustworthiness than students. Results from Mann–Whitney tests indicate that these differences between both groups of managers and students become significant for trustors' transfers of at least 150 points.

5. Discussion and conclusion

Co-op and conventional managers are accountable to different principals: worker-members and investors. In this paper, we compare the economic preferences of the two types of managers using incentive-compatible measures of risk preferences, time preferences, reciprocity, altruism, and trust gathered in the context of a lab-in-the-field experiment. Our analysis supports two main conclusions. First, the fraction of risk-loving subjects is lower among co-op managers compared to conventional managers. Second, co-op managers appear to be more altruistic than their conventional counterparts. We do not observe significant differences between the two groups across other preference domains, such as impatience, trust, and reciprocity.

As managers' preferences mediate important strategic decisions within firms, our results have important implications for understanding the behavior of cooperatives in competitive markets. Observed differences between co-op and conventional managers in terms of risk preferences and altruism seem consistent with well-documented facts about the actual behavior of cooperative firms, such as their concentration in less risky and less capital-intensive industries (Podivinsky and Stewart, Reference Podivinsky and Stewart2007) and their egalitarian compensation policies (Abramitzky, Reference Abramitzky2011; Burdín, Reference Burdín2016; Montero, Reference Montero2020). Our findings indicate that the different identity of principals in worker cooperatives and conventional firms induces different patterns of behavioral selection among managers. The observed pattern is consistent with the alignment of preferences of managers and worker-principals, which, in turn, may contribute to reducing agency costs in worker cooperatives.Footnote 25

Our results suggest that less risk-prone and more altruistic individuals tend to self-select into cooperative management positions. One limitation of our research design, however, is that we cannot distinguish between selection and endogenous preference formation channels. Observed behavioral differences between individuals in worker cooperatives and conventional firms could also be due to the fact that firm ownership shapes individual preferences. The idea that preferences are malleable and may change because of contextual factors or the long-term exposure to certain institutions is now widely accepted (Bowles, Reference Bowles1998; Fehr and Hoff, Reference Fehr and Hoff2011). Experimental studies have shown that democratic institutions affect cooperative behavior (Dal Bó et al., Reference Dal Bó, Foster and Putterman2010) and organizational decision processes affect ethical behavior toward outsiders (Ellman and Pezanis-Christou, Reference Ellman and Pezanis-Christou2010). Carpenter and Seki (Reference Carpenter and Seki2011) provide field experimental evidence from Japanese fishermen supporting the idea that social preferences are endogenous to the adoption of a cooperative institution. Ben-Ner and Ellman (Reference Ben-Ner and Ellman2013) specifically discuss the potential effects of organizational design on employees' preferences.Footnote 26

Moreover, more research is needed to understand whether differences in economic preferences between co-op and conventional managers correlate with industry characteristics and translate into different management practices, organizational design, and performance.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000783.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Ran Abramitzky, Avner Ben-Ner, Peter Howley, Neel Ocean, Louis Putterman, Tommaso Reggiani, the editor Geoffrey Hodgson and three anonymous referees, and conference and workshop participants at Ciriec (Bucharest), IAFEP (Lubjiana), SIOE (Stockholm), N.G.O. (Rome), and LACEA (Mexico) for helpful comments and suggestions. An earlier version of this paper circulated under the title ‘The Economic Preferences of Cooperative Managers’. This study was funded by Comisión Sectorial de Investigación Cientifíca, Universidad de la República (Uruguay).

Footnotes

1 We also speak to the experimental literature comparing students and non-standard subjects (Batsaikhan and Putterman, Reference Batsaikhan and Putterman2019; Fréchette, Reference Fréchette2015, Reference Fréchette2016; Gneezy and Imas, Reference Gneezy and Imas2016).

2 According to Arando et al. (Reference Arando, Gago, Podivinsky and Stewart2012), worker-managed firms account for 13% of economic activity in the northern Italian province of Emilia Romagna and 8% of industrial gross value added (and 4% of overall gross value) in Basque Country, Spain, where the Mondragon Cooperative Corporation is located. In 2016, employment in non-profit organizations represented 10% of total US private sector employment (Ghatak, Reference Ghatak, Powell and Bromley2020).

3 The study of managers' preferences acquires special relevance given the evidence on the effect of managers' behavioral traits in shaping firm behavior and, hence, productivity (Bandiera et al., Reference Bandiera, Prat, Hansen and Sadun2020; Bertrand and Schoar, Reference Bertrand and Schoar2003; Bloom and Van Reenen, Reference Bloom and Van Reenen2007; Kocher et al., Reference Kocher, Pogrebna and Sutter2013; Mullins and Schoar, Reference Mullins and Schoar2016).

4 Here, we focus on theoretical arguments that may explain differences in managerial preferences between cooperatives and conventional firms. The importance of attracting specific behavioral traits for cooperatives, such as time and social preferences, has been discussed in other contexts. For instance, altruism and reciprocity may induce less shirking and sustain peer pressure and mutual monitoring in cooperative teams. Moreover, low discount rates may uphold conditional cooperation in repeated interactions via tit-for-tat strategies and allow us to overcome free-riding problems in team production. Self-selection and retention of members endowed with these behavioral traits may help to sustain high levels of shop-floor effort provision and labor discipline in cooperatives (Ben-Ner and Ellman, Reference Ben-Ner and Ellman2013; Carpenter et al., Reference Carpenter, Bowles, Gintis and Hwang2009; Putterman, Reference Putterman, Kolm and Ythier2006).

5 Compulsory profit plow-back rules also play an important role in helping worker cooperatives to accumulate capital in many countries (Pérotin, Reference Pérotin2013).

6 One could also argue that worker-owners may be willing to tolerate greater earnings’ risk in exchange for greater job security.

7 The horizon problem should not arise if workers are allowed to buy and sell membership rights in an open market. This is because any investment will be reflected in the value of individual shares. However, membership markets are generally rare and play a very limited role in the Uruguayan context.

8 One could also expect members of worker cooperatives to discount the future more heavily than owners of conventional firms if workers, in general, in the economy face a higher interest rate on borrowing compared to capital owners (Askildsen and Ireland, Reference Askildsen and Ireland1993).

9 Sen (Reference Sen1966) is an early attempt to incorporate the role of social preferences (‘sympathy’) in a theoretical model of cooperative production. Rose-Ackerman (Reference Rose-Ackerman1996) discusses the role of altruistic preferences in the context of non-profit organizations.

10 See Ghatak (Reference Ghatak, Powell and Bromley2020) for a related discussion on the selection of socially motivated managers in social sector organizations. Anecdotal evidence from Mondragon cooperatives in Basque Country also supports the idea that the internal wage structure is more compressed in worker cooperatives than in conventional firms, with the usual ratio of top-bottom not exceeding 5:1 and top managers receiving roughly 30% lower earnings than in the conventional sector (Arando et al., Reference Arando, Gago, Jones and Kato2015).

11 Despite the main focus of the study being the behavioral traits of managers in two distinct organizational settings, we also collect similar measures from a sample of students (see Fréchette (Reference Fréchette2015) for a discussion of methodological issues faced by researchers when comparing professionals and students in experiments). In line with previous studies, we expect students to behave in less pro-social ways than adults in experiments (Belot et al., Reference Belot, Duch and Miller2015; Falk et al., Reference Falk, Meier and Zehnder2013). Closely related to our study, Fehr and List (Reference Fehr and List2004) find that CEOs are significantly more trustful and display more trustworthiness than students, achieving higher efficiency in their interactions.

12 For a discussion of order effects, see Charness et al. (Reference Charness, Gneezy and Kuhn2013).

13 The fraction of subjects exhibiting multiple switching points was 17.7, 15, and 16.3% in cooperative managers, conventional managers, and students, respectively. We compute the average switching point in those cases.

14 The fraction of subjects exhibiting multiple switching points was very similar across groups (8–9%). We compute the average switching point for these cases. The fraction of subjects having non-unique switch points is similar to previous studies using multiple price lists (Holt and Laury, Reference Holt and Laury2002).

15 The use of the strategy method is also common in experiments embedded in representative surveys given the logistical problems of implementing sequential games in a one-step procedure (Fehr et al., Reference Fehr, Fischbacher, von Rosenbladt, Schupp and Wagner2003). According to Brandts and Charness (Reference Brandts and Charness2011), the strategy method produces qualitatively similar results when compared to the standard direct-response method. However, they find that the levels of punishment are lower with the strategy method.

16 We exclude subjects who never switched between the lottery and the safe payment. This share was 14, 13, and 2% for cooperative managers, conventional managers, and students, respectively.

17 We provide details on this calculation in the online Supplementary Appendix OA.4.

18 We ran additional regressions with controls for time of the day (morning, afternoon, and evening) and day of the week at which the subjects completed the experiment (see Table OA.3.1 in the online Supplementary Appendix). The basic results remain unchanged. We also estimated the regression model excluding subjects who switched multiple times between the lottery and the safe payment (see Table OA.3.2 in the online Supplementary Appendix). Despite a substantial reduction in the number of observations (25–30%), the co-op dummy remains negative, but estimates are rather imprecise.

19 We apply the following rule to impute extreme values to non-switchers. For non-switchers who are always impatient, we assigned them what would be the following value after the highest postponed value in the list (i.e. 670 points). See Figure A.5 in the online Appendix.

20 For instance, the average give rate in the meta-analysis conducted by Engel (Reference Engel2011) is 28.3%. Based on two large samples of Amazon Mechanical Turk workers, Brañas-Garza et al. (Reference Brañas-Garza, Capraro and Rascón-Ramírez2018) report an average give rate of 27–31%.

21 Regression analysis reported further confirms that there are no differences between the two types of managers in the Ultimatum Game (see Tables OA.3.7 and OA.3.8 in the online Supplementary Appendix).

22 Johnson and Mislin (Reference Johnson and Mislin2011) report an average transfer of 50% in their meta-analysis of 162 replications of the trust game. On average, trustees return 37% of the amount available to return.

23 We exclude trustees' responses involving a rate of return of more than 1. Across the five values of x, this implies excluding an average of 21 subjects of each group.

24 See Tables OA.3.9 and OA.3.10 in the online Supplementary Appendix.

25 Our results do not rule out the possibility that worker cooperatives specifically design the compensation package in order to attract certain types of managers. For instance, egalitarian pay policies implemented by cooperatives may help to screen altruistic and intrinsically motivated managers.

26 Although our experiment does not allow us to separate the sorting and endogenous preference formation channels cleanly, we provide suggestive evidence of the effect of cooperative experience on economic preferences by exploiting variation in managers' tenure. If the preference formation channel is important, one should observe some type of correlation between managers' preferences and tenure. This exercise should be interpreted with caution, as managers' tenure is obviously endogenous. In online Appendix Table A.4, we explore the existence of differences between cooperative and conventional managers in terms of risk preferences and give rate in the dictator game, adding controls for managers' tenure and an interaction between tenure and the co-op dummy. We do not find significant correlations between managerial tenure and our measures of risk and altruistic preferences.

References

Abramitzky, R. (2008), ‘The Limits of Equality: Insights from the Israeli Kibbutz’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(3): 11111159.10.1162/qjec.2008.123.3.1111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abramitzky, R. (2011), ‘Lessons from the Kibbutz on the Equality-Incentives Trade-Off’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(1): 185208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. A. and Kranton, R. E. (2005), ‘Identity and the Economics of Organizations’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1): 932.10.1257/0895330053147930CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alves, G., Burdin, G., Carrasco, P., Dean, A. and Rius, A. (2012), ‘Empleo, remuneraciones e inversión en cooperativas de trabajadores y empresas convencionales: nueva evidencia para Uruguay’, Documentos de Trabajo (working papers) 12–14, Instituto de Economia – IECON.Google Scholar
Arando, S., Gago, M., Jones, D. C. and Kato, T. (2015), ‘Efficiency in Employee-Owned Enterprises’, ILR Review, 68(2): 398425.10.1177/0019793914564966CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arando, S., Gago, M., Podivinsky, J. M. and Stewart, G. (2012), ‘Do Labour-Managed Firms Benefit from Agglomeration?’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 84(1): 193200.Google Scholar
Askildsen, J. E. and Ireland, N. J. (1993), ‘Human Capital, Property Rights, and Labour Managed Firms’, Oxford Economic Papers, 45(2): 229242.10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a042089CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (1973), ‘Worker Management and the Modern Industrial Enterprise’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3): 375392.10.2307/1882011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bandiera, O., Prat, A., Hansen, S. and Sadun, R. (2020), ‘CEO Behavior and Firm Performance’, Journal of Political Economy, 128(4): 13251369.Google Scholar
Batsaikhan, M. and Putterman, L. (2019), ‘An Honest Day's Pay: Cooperation among Entrepreneurs vs. Students, and Linkages to Real-World Business Success’, Southern Economic Journal, 86(2): 478502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belloc, F. (2017), ‘What Deters Labor-Owned Firm Creation? Evidence from Italian Manufacturing Sectors’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 45(1): 139153.10.1016/j.jce.2016.12.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belot, M., Duch, R. and Miller, L. (2015), ‘A Comprehensive Comparison of Students and Non-Students in Classic Experimental Games’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 113(C): 2633.10.1016/j.jebo.2015.02.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Ner, A. (2013), ‘Preferences and Organization Structure: Toward Behavioral Economics Micro-Foundations of Organizational Analysis’, Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 46(C): 8796.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, A. and Ellman, M. (2013), ‘The Contributions of Behavioural Economics to Understanding and Advancing the Sustainability of Worker Cooperatives’, Journal of Entrepreneurial and Organizational Diversity, 2(1): 75100.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, A., Montias, J. M. and Neuberger, E. (1993), ‘Basic Issues in Organizations: A Comparative Perspective’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 17(2): 207242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J. and McCabe, K. (1995), ‘Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History’, Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1): 122142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertrand, M. and Schoar, A. (2003), ‘Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4): 11691208.Google Scholar
Besley, T. and Ghatak, M. (2005), ‘Competition and Incentives with Motivated Agents’, American Economic Review, 95(3): 616636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and Ghatak, M. (2017), ‘Profit with Purpose? A Theory of Social Enterprise’, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 9(3): 1958.Google Scholar
Bettinger, E. and Slonim, R. (2007), ‘Patience among Children’, Journal of Public Economics, 91(1): 343363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, N. and Van Reenen, J. (2007), ‘Measuring and Explaining Management Practices Across Firms and Countries’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(4): 13511408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, P. and Dewatripont, M. (2012), ‘Authority in Organizations’, in Gibbons, R. and Roberts, J. (eds), The Handbook of Organizational Economics. Introductory Chapters, Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 342372.Google Scholar
Bonin, J. P., Jones, D. C. and Putterman, L. (1993), ‘Theoretical and Empirical Studies of Producer Cooperatives: Will Ever the Twain Meet?’, Journal of Economic Literature, 31(3): 12901320.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (1998), ‘Endogenous Preferences: The Cultural Consequences of Markets and Other Economic Institutions’, Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1): 75111.Google Scholar
Brañas-Garza, P., Capraro, V. and Rascón-Ramírez, E. (2018), ‘Gender Differences in Altruism on Mechanical Turk: Expectations and Actual Behaviour’, Economics Letters, 170(C): 1923.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J. and Charness, G. (2011), ‘The Strategy versus the Direct-Response Method: A First Survey of Experimental Comparisons’, Exp Econ, 14(3): 375398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burdín, G. (2016), ‘Equality Under Threat by the Talented: Evidence from Worker-Managed Firms’, The Economic Journal, 126(594): 13721403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burdín, G. and Dean, A. (2009), ‘New Evidence on Wages and Employment in Worker Cooperatives Compared with Capitalist Firms’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(4): 517533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F. and Fehr, E. (2004), ‘Measuring social norms and preferences using experimental games: A guide for social scientists’, in Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., and Gintis, H. (eds), Foundations of human sociality, Oxford University Press, pp. 55–95. https://doi.org/10.1093/0199262055.003.0003Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. and Malmendier, U. (2007), ‘Behavioral economics of organizations’, in Diamond, P. and Vartiainen, H. (eds), Behavioral economics and its applications. Princeton University Press, pp. 235290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J (2008), ‘Social Preferences’, in Macmillan, Palgrave (eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave: Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1974-1Google Scholar
Carpenter, J. and Seki, E. (2011), ‘Do Social Preferences Increase Productivity? Field Experimental Evidence From Fishermen in Toyama Bay’, Economic Inquiry, 49(2): 612630.Google Scholar
Carpenter, J., Bowles, S., Gintis, H. and Hwang, S.-H. (2009), ‘Strong Reciprocity and Team Production: Theory and Evidence’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 71(2): 221232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., Gneezy, U. and Kuhn, M. A. (2013), ‘Experimental Methods: Extra-Laboratory Experiments-Extending the Reach of Experimental Economics’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 91(C): 93100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, D. L., Schonger, M. and Wickens, C. (2016), ‘oTree – An Open-Source Platform for Laboratory, Online, and Field Experiments’, Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 9(C): 8897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Craig, B. and Pencavel, J. (1992), ‘The Behavior of Worker Cooperatives: The Plywood Companies of the Pacific Northwest’, American Economic Review, 82(5): 10831105.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, P., Foster, A. and Putterman, L. (2010), ‘Institutions and Behavior: Experimental Evidence on the Effects of Democracy’, American Economic Review, 100(5): 22052229.Google Scholar
Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Golsteyn, B. H. H., Huffman, D. and Sunde, U. (2017), ‘Risk Attitudes Across the Life Course’, The Economic Journal, 127(605): F95F116.Google Scholar
Dow, G. K. (2018), The Labor-Managed Firm: Theoretical Foundations, New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drèze, J. H. (1976), ‘Some Theory of Labor Management and Participation’, Econometrica, 44(6): 11251139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. and Wilson, R. (2006), ‘Internet Cautions: Experimental Games with Internet Partners’, Experimental Economics, 9(1): 5366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellman, M. and Pezanis-Christou, P. (2010), ‘Organizational Structure, Communication, and Group Ethics’, American Economic Review, 100(5): 24782491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, C. (2011), ‘Dictator Games: A Meta Study’, Experimental Economics, 14(4): 583610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., Meier, S. and Zehnder, C. (2013), ‘Do Lab Experiments Misrepresent Social Preferences? The Case of Self-Selected Student Samples’, Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(4): 839852.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., Becker, A., Dohmen, T., Huffman, D. B. and Sunde, U. (2016), ‘The Preference Survey Module: A Validated Instrument for Measuring Risk, Time, and Social Preferences’, IZA Discussion Papers, Institute of Labor Economics (IZA).Google Scholar
Fehr, E. and Gächter, S. (2000), ‘Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3): 159181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Hoff, K. (2011), ‘Introduction: Tastes, Castes and Culture: The Influence of Society on Preferences’, The Economic Journal, 121(556): F396F412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and List, J. A. (2004), ‘The Hidden Costs and Returns of Incentives – Trust and Trustworthiness among CEOs’, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(5): 743771.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. M. (1999), ‘A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3): 817868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Gächter, S. and Kirchsteiger, G. (1997), ‘Reciprocity as a Contract Enforcement Device: Experimental Evidence’, Econometrica, 65(4): 833860.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., von Rosenbladt, B., Schupp, J. and Wagner, G. G. (2003), ‘A Nation-wide Laboratory: Examining Trust and Trustworthiness by Integrating Behavioral Experiments into Representative Surveys’, IZA Discussion Papers 715, Institute of Labor Economics (IZA).Google Scholar
Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J. L., Savin, N. and Sefton, M. (1994), ‘Fairness in Simple Bargaining Experiments’, Games and Economic Behavior, 6(3): 347369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fréchette, G. (2015), ‘Laboratory Experiments: Professionals versus Students’, Handbook of Experimental Economic Methodology, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 360390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fréchette, G. (2016) Experimental Economics Across Subject Populations, Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 435480.Google Scholar
Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G. and O'Donoghue, T. (2002), ‘Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review’, Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2): 351401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furubotn, E. G. (1976), ‘The Long-run Analysis of the Labor-Managed Firm: An Alternative Interpretation’, The American Economic Review, 66(1): 104123.Google Scholar
Ghatak, M. (2020), ‘Economic Theories of the Social Sector: From Nonprofits to Social Enterprise’, in Powell, W. W. and Bromley, P. (eds), The Nonprofit Sector, Stanford: Stanford University Press, pp. 319332.Google Scholar
Gibbons, R. and Roberts, J. (2015), ‘Organizational Economics’, in Scott, R., and Kosslyn, S (eds), Emerging trends in the social and behavioral sciences, Wiley Online, pp. 115.Google Scholar
Gneezy, U. and Imas, A. (2016), ‘Lab in the Field: Measuring Preferences in the Wild’, Handbook of Economic Field Experiments, Amsterdam: North-Holland, an imprint of Elsevier, pp. 439464.Google Scholar
Gneezy, U., Leibbrandt, A. and List, J. A. (2016), ‘Ode to the Sea: Workplace Organizations and Norms of Cooperation’, The Economic Journal, 126(595): 18561883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W., Schmittberger, R. and Schwarze, B. (1982), ‘An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3(4): 367388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansmann, H. (1988), ‘Ownership of the Firm.’ The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4(2): 267304.Google Scholar
Hansmann, H. (2012), ‘Ownership and Organizational Form’, in Gibbons, R. and Roberts, J. (eds), The Handbook of Organizational Economics. Introductory Chapters, Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 891917.Google Scholar
Holm, H., Nee, V. and Opper, S. (2020), ‘Strategic Decisions: Behavioral Differences Between CEOs and Others’, Experimental Economics, 23(1): 154180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, C. A. and Laury, S. K. (2002), ‘Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects’, American Economic Review, 92(5): 16441655.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopfensitz, A. and Miquel-Florensa, J. (2017), ‘Mill Ownership and Farmer's Cooperative Behavior: The Case of Costa Rica Coffee Farmers’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 13(3): 623648.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horton, J., Rand, D. and Zeckhauser, R. (2011), ‘The Online Laboratory: Conducting Experiments in a Real Labor Market’, Experimental Economics, 14(3): 399425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H. (1976), ‘Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure’, Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4): 305360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H. (1979), ‘Rights and Production Functions: An Application to Labor-Managed Firms and Codetermination’, The Journal of Business, 52(4): 469506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, N. and Mislin, A. A. (2011), ‘Trust Games: A Meta-Analysis’, Journal of Economic Psychology, 32(5): 865889.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L. and Thaler, R. H. (1986), ‘Fairness and the Assumptions of Economics’, The Journal of Business, 59(4): S285S300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kocher, M. G., Pogrebna, G. and Sutter, M. (2013), ‘Other-regarding Preferences and Management Styles’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 88(C): 109132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koudstaal, M., Sloof, R. and van Praag, M. (2016), ‘Risk, Uncertainty, and Entrepreneurship: Evidence from a Lab-in-the-Field Experiment’, Management Science, 62(10): 28972915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kremer, M. (1997), ‘Why are Worker Cooperatives So Rare? NBER Working Papers 6118’, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meade, J. E. (1972), ‘The Theory of Labour-Managed Firms and of Profit Sharing’, The Economic Journal, 82(325): 402428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montero, E. (2020), Cooperative property rights and development: Evidence from land reform in El Salvador. Tech. Rep., Harvard University.Google Scholar
Mullins, W. and Schoar, A. (2016), ‘How do CEOs see Their Roles? Management Philosophies and Styles in Family and Non-Family Firms’, Journal of Financial Economics, 119(1): 2443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Navarra, C. (2016), ‘Employment Stabilization Inside Firms: An Empirical Investigation of Worker Cooperatives’, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 87(4): 563585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neacsu, I., Gomez-Mejia, L. R. and Martin, G. (2014), ‘CEO Risk Taking in Family Firms: The Behavioral Agency Model, Family Control and CEO Option Wealth’, Academy of Management Proceedings, 2014(1): 11660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nee, V., Holm, H. J. and Opper, S. (2018), ‘Learning to Trust: From Relational Exchange to Generalized Trust in China’, Organization Science, 29(5): 969986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oosterbeek, H., Sloof, R. and Kuilen, G. (2004), ‘Cultural Differences in Ultimatum Game Experiments: Evidence from a Meta-Analysis’, Experimental Economics, 7(2): 171188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Opper, S., Nee, V. and Holm, H. J. (2017), ‘Risk Aversion and Guanxi Activities: A Behavioral Analysis of CEOs in China’, Academy of Management Journal, 60(4): 15041530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pencavel, J., Pistaferri, L. and Schivardi, F. (2006), ‘Wages, Employment, and Capital in Capitalist and Worker-Owned Firms’, ILR Review, 60(1): 2344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pepper, A. and Gore, J. (2015), ‘Behavioral Agency Theory: New Foundations for Theorizing About Executive Compensation’, Journal of Management, 41(4): 10451068.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pérotin, V. (2013), ‘Worker Cooperatives: Good, Sustainable Jobs in the Community’, Journal of Entrepreneurial and Organizational Diversity, 2(2): 3447.Google Scholar
Podivinsky, J. M. and Stewart, G. (2007), ‘Why is Labour-Managed Firm Entry So Rare?: An Analysis of UK Manufacturing Data’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 63(1): 177192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, T. C., Lovallo, D. and Fox, C. R. (2011), ‘Behavioral Strategy’, Strategic Management Journal, 32(13): 13691386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putterman, L. (2006), ‘Reciprocity, Altruism, and Cooperative Production’, in Kolm, S., and Ythier, J. M. (eds), Handbook on the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism, Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 14091435.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1996), ‘Altruism, Nonprofits, and Economic Theory’, Journal of Economic Literature, 34(2): 701728.Google Scholar
Rousseau, D. M., Sitkin, S. B., Burt, R. S. and Camerer, C. (1998), ‘Not So Different After all: A Cross-Discipline View of Trust’, Academy of Management Review, 23(3): 393404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruffle, B. J. and Sosis, R. (2006), ‘Cooperation and the in-Group-out-Group Bias: A Field Test on Israeli Kibbutz Members and City Residents’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60(2): 147163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. K. (1966), ‘Labour Allocation in A Cooperative Enterprise’, The Review of Economic Studies, 33(4): 361371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiseman, R. M. and Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (1998), ‘A Behavioral Agency Model of Managerial Risk Taking’, Academy of Management Review, 23(1): 133153.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Descriptive statistics

Figure 1

Figure 1. Risk preferences. (a) Mean safe payment at switching row. (b) Distribution of risk preferences by group.Notes: In panel (a), the figure displays the average value of the safe payment at the switching row by group. Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.3168 (0.1169). N: Co-op managers = 83, conventional managers = 88, students = 90. In panel (b), the figure displays the distribution of risk preferences in terms of risk loving, risk averse and risk neutral subjects. Fisher's exact test (risk lovers) co-ops versus conv.: p-value = 0.051. N: Co-op managers = 96, conv. managers = 99, students = 92.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Time preferences. (a) Mean delayed payment by group. (b) Distribution of time preferences by group.Notes: In panel (a), the figure displays the average delayed payment at the switching row by group (0–3 months). Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.7557 (0.2162). N: Co-op managers = 79, conventional managers = 85, students = 81. In panel (b), the figure displays the distribution of subjects' types in terms of constant discounters, future-biased, and present-biased subjects. Fisher's exact test (constant discounters) co-op versus conv.: p-value = 0.3390. N: Co-op managers = 87, conventional managers = 90, students = 79.

Figure 3

Figure 3. Fraction of patient subjects by group. (a) No front-end delay (0–3 months). (b) Front-end delay (3–6 months).Notes: This figure displays the fraction of subjects that chose the larger-later payment for each value of the later payment. Panel (a): no front-end delay condition (0–3 months). Panel (b): front-end delay condition (3–6 months).

Figure 4

Figure 4. Give rate in Dictator game by group.Notes: This figure displays the fraction of Dictators' endowment transferred to Recipients (give rate) by group. Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.0382 (0.000). N: Co-op managers = 96, conventional managers = 100, students = 92.

Figure 5

Figure 5. Distribution of give rates in Dictator game by group.Notes: This figure displays the distribution of give rates by group. N: Co-op managers = 96, conventional managers = 100, students = 92.

Figure 6

Figure 6. Ultimatum game. (a) Proposers: mean offer. (b) Respondents: MAO.Notes: In panel (a), the figure displays the mean offer made Proposers in the Ultimatum game. Panel (a): Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.3020 (0.0291). In panel (b), the figure displays the MAO elicited from Respondents. Panel (b): Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.1931 (0.0181). Both panels: N: Co-op managers = 96, conventional managers = 100, students = 92.

Figure 7

Figure 7. Trust game. (a) Mean Trustor's transfer. (b) Trustee's back-transfers for each possible Trustors' transfer value.Notes: In panel (a), the figure displays the mean Trustors' transfer by group. Mann–Whitney test co-op versus conventional (student): p-value = 0.6070 (0.0074). N: Co-op managers = 96, conventional managers = 100, students = 92. In panel (b), the figure displays Trustees' back-transfers elicited for each possible Trustors' transfer value using the strategy method.

Supplementary material: PDF

Alves et al. supplementary material

Alves et al. supplementary material 1

Download Alves et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 237.8 KB
Supplementary material: PDF

Alves et al. supplementary material

Alves et al. supplementary material 2

Download Alves et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 2.6 MB