Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-q99xh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T08:40:20.307Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Reflections on the implications of evolutionary psychology for the theory of institutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 June 2012

JONATHAN EASTWOOD*
Affiliation:
Sociology and Anthropology, Washington and Lee University, Newcomb Hall 225, Lexington, VA 24450, USA

Abstract:

In this paper I consider the implications of work in evolutionary psychology for institutional analysis. I respond to Pascal Boyer and Michael Bang Petersen (‘The Naturalness of (Many) Social Institutions: Evolved Cognition as their Foundation’; 2012), who put forward a programmatic statement in this connection. I argue that their discussion overstates the explanatory power of evolutionary psychology and does not take sufficient account of what we already know about institutions. At the same time, I suggest that they, and the empirical work upon which they draw, make an important contribution by helping us to establish more clearly the boundary conditions of institutional analysis. I call for ongoing cooperation and for the establishment of a unified research tradition that brings together both evolutionary psychology and institutionalism.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbott, A. 2005, ‘Linked Ecologies: States and Universities as Environments for Professions’, Sociological Theory, 23 (3): 245274.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. 2004, ‘Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth’, NBER Working Paper no. 10481, http://www.nber.org/papers/w10481.pdf (accessed April 2012).Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. 2010, ‘Why is Africa Poor?’, Economic History of Developing Regions, 25 (1): 2150.Google Scholar
Barman, E. 2007, ‘An Institutional Approach to Donor Control: From Dyadic Ties to a Field-Level Analysis’, American Journal of Sociology, 112 (5): 14161457.Google Scholar
Bernard, M., Reenock, C., and Nordstrom, T. 2004, ‘The Legacy of Western Overseas Colonialism on Democratic Survival’, International Studies Quarterly, 48 (1): 225250.Google Scholar
Blyth, M., Hodgson, G. M., Lewis, O., and Steinmo, S. 2011, ‘Introduction to the Special Issue on the Evolution of Institutions’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 7 (3): 299315.Google Scholar
Boli, J. and Thomas, G. M. 1997, ‘World Culture in the World Polity’, American Sociological Review, 62 (2): 171190.Google Scholar
Boyer, P. and Petersen, M. Bang 2012, ‘The Naturalness of (Many) Social Institutions: Evolved Cognition as their Foundation’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 8 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Centeno, M. A. 2002, Blood and Debt: War and the Nation State in Latin America, University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, P. and Powell, W. 1983, ‘The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields’, American Sociological Review, 48 (2): 147160.Google Scholar
Dopfer, K., Foster, J., and Potts, J. 2004, ‘Micro-Meso-Macro’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14 (3): 263279.Google Scholar
Duina, F. 2011, Institutions and the Economy, Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Durkheim, E. 1982, The Rules of Sociological Method and Selected Texts on Sociology and its Method, Lukes, S. (ed.), Halls, W. D. (trans.), New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Durkheim, E. 1995, The Elementary Forms of Religious Life, K. E. Fields (trans.), New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Ertman, T. 1997, Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fourcade, M. and Khurana, R. 2011, ‘From Social Control to Financial Economics: the Linked Ecologies of Economics and Business in Twentieth Century America’, Harvard Business School, Working Paper 11–071, http://www.hbs.edu/research/pdf/11-071.pdf (accessed April 2012).Google Scholar
Galaskiewicz, J. 1991, ‘Making Corporate Actors Accountable: Institution-Building in Minneapolis-St. Paul’, in DiMaggio, P. and Powell, W. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 293310.Google Scholar
Gorski, P. 2003, The Disciplinary Revolution: Calvinism and the Rise of the State in Early Modern Europe, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenfeld, L. 2005, ‘Nationalism and the Mind’, Nations and Nationalism, 11 (3): 325341.Google Scholar
Greenfeld, L. 2006, ‘An Invitation to a Dialogue: A Comment on Neuroscience and Culture,’ in L. Greenfeld, Nationalism and the Mind: Essays on Modern Culture, Oxford: Oneworld Press, pp. 162–175.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 2006, Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Habermas, J. 1979, Communication and the Evolution of Society, McCarthy, T. (trans.), Boston, MA: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Hardin, R. 1997, ‘Economic Theories of the State’, in Mueller, D. C. (ed.), Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook, New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 2134.Google Scholar
Herbst, J. 2000, States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons in Authority and Control, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 2004, The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure, and Darwinism in American Institutionalism, New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. 2011, Thinking Fast and Slow, New York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux.Google Scholar
Lange, M. 2009, Lineages of Despotism and Development: British Colonialism and State Power, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Mahoney, J. 2010, Colonialism and Post-Colonial Development: Spanish America in Comparative Perspective, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mahoney, J. and Thelen, K. (eds.) 2009, Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Merton, R. K. 1979, The Sociology of Science, Theoretical and Empirical Investigations, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, J. W. 2010, ‘World Society, Institutional Theories, and the Actor’, Annual Review of Sociology, 36: 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, J. W., Boli, J., Thomas, G. M., and Ramírez, F. O. 1997, ‘World Society and the Nation-State’, American Journal of Sociology, 103 (1): 144181.Google Scholar
Meyer, J. W. and Rowan, B. 1991, ‘Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony’, in Powell, W. W. and DiMaggio, P. J. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 4162.Google Scholar
North, D. C. 1990, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., and Weingast, B. R. 2009, Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. 2005, Understanding Institutional Diversity, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pinker, S. 2003, The Blank Slate: The Modern Denial of Human Nature, New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Posner, E. A. 2000, Law and Social Norms, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Powell, W. W. and DiMaggio, P. J. 1991, The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. and Acemoglu, D. 2008, ‘The Persistence and Change of Institutions in the Americas’, Southern Economic Journal, 75 (2): 282299.Google Scholar
Searle, J. 2010, Making the Social World: The Structure of Human Civilization, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Strang, D. and Meyer, J. W. 1993, ‘Institutional Conditions for Diffusion’, Theory and Society, 22 (4): 487511.Google Scholar
Tilly, C. 1992, Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–1992, Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers Inc.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1985, The Market Institutions of Capitalism, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Woodberry, R. D. 2011, ‘Religion and the Spread of Human Capital and Political Institutions: Christian Missions as a Quasi-Natural Experiment’, in McCleary, R. M. (ed.), The Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Religion, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 111134.Google Scholar
Woodberry, R. D. (forthcoming), ‘The Missionary Roots of Liberal Democracy’, American Political Science Review.Google Scholar