Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T09:14:24.509Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Rule of law and the size of government

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 August 2011

RANDALL G. HOLCOMBE*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Florida State University, Tallahassee, FL 32306, USA
CORTNEY S. RODET
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Florida State University, Tallahassee, FL 32306, USA
*

Abstract:

If those with political power benefit from corrupt institutions, rulers might not adopt the rule of law so the ruling class can command a larger share of a smaller pie. An empirical analysis reveals that the size of government is larger in those countries that enforce the rule of law. If government expenditures provide some measure of the ability of the ruling class to command resources, this suggests that those with political power could benefit from imposing a fairer and more objective legal structure. Another conjecture is that those in power maintain corrupt governments to pay off their supporters and enhance their ability to remain in power. However, the rule of law is also positively associated with political stability, so better enforcement of the rule of law also enhances the ability of incumbent governments to remain in power.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. (2001), ‘The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation’, American Economic Review, 91 (5): 13691401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayittey, G. B. N. (2008), ‘The African Development Conundrum’, in Powell, B. (ed.), Making Poor Nations Rich: Entrepreneurship and the Process of Economic Development, Stanford: Stanford Business and Finance, chapter 6.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. (1990), ‘Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive’, Journal of Political Economy, 98 (5): 893921.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berggren, N. (2003), ‘The Benefits of Economic Freedom: A Survey’, Independent Review, 8 (2): 193211.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Lee, D. R. (1982), ‘Politics, Time, and the Laffer Curve’, Journal of Political Economy, 90 (4): 816819.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R. M., and Morrow, J. D. (2003), The Logic of Political Survival, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (2002), ‘The Regulation of Entry’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (1): 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Faria, H. J. and Montesinos, H. M. (2009), ‘Does Economic Freedom Cause Prosperity? An IV Approach’, Public Choice, 141 (1/2): 103127.Google Scholar
Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (2004), ‘Do Institutions Cause Growth?’, Journal of Economic Growth, 9 (3): 271303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, J. and Lawson, R. (2007), Economic Freedom of the World, 2007 Report, Vancouver, BC: Fraser Institute.Google Scholar
Holcombe, R. G. (2008), ‘Why Does Government Produce National Defense?’, Public Choice, 137 (1/2): 1119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, A. O. (1974), ‘The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society’, American Economic Review, 64 (June): 291303.Google Scholar
Landes, D. S. (1998), The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich, and Some So Poor, New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Marshall, M. G., Jaggers, K., and Gurr, T. R. (2008), ‘Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristic and Transitions, 1800–2008’, http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm (accessed 5 December 2009).Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (1990), The Lever of Riches, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Niskanen, W. A. (2003), Autocratic, Democratic, and Optimal Government, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1991), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., and Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. Jr. (1996), ‘Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: Why Some Nations are Rich, Others Poor’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10 (2): 324.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776[1937]), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. New York: Modern Library.Google Scholar
Sobel, M. E. (1987), ‘Direct and Indirect Effects in Linear Structural Equation Models’, Sociological Methods and Research, 16 (1): 155176.Google Scholar
United States Census Bureau (2010), ‘The Statistical Abstract of the United States’, 2010 edition, Section 9. Federal Government Finances and Employment, Table 459: Federal Budget Outlays by Type: 1990 to 2009, http://www.census.gov/prod/2009pubs/10statab/fedgov.pdf (accessed June 2011).Google Scholar
Yang, D. (2008), ‘Integrity for Hire: An Analysis of Widespread Customs Reform’, Journal of Law and Economics, 51 (1): 2557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar