Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-14T23:19:09.444Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Why Do Courts Delay?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 October 2022

Deborah Beim
Affiliation:
Yale University
Tom S. Clark*
Affiliation:
Emory University
John W. Patty
Affiliation:
University of Chicago
*
Contact the corresponding author, Tom Clark, at tom.clark@emory.edu.

Abstract

Answering one question often begets another. We present a decision-theoretic model that describes how this affects the sequencing of decisions over time. Because answering an easy question may raise a more difficult one, a rational judge may delay resolution even if he has perfect information about the correct decision. Furthermore, because otherwise unrelated questions may raise similar follow-ups, he may optimally clump decisions together. Our theory thus generates an endogenous economy of scale in dispute resolution and contributes to the literature on punctuated equilibrium theory. We illustrate the results of our model with a case study from legal history in the United States.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© 2017 by Law and Courts Organized Section of the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We thank Chuck Cameron, Cliff Carrubba, Mike Giles, Adam Glynn, Lewis Kornhauser, Jon Nash, Jeff Staton, Tom Walker, and seminar participants at Emory University, Princeton University, Yale University, the University of Georgia, and the Institute for Advanced Study in Toulouse for helpful comments and discussions. An earlier version of this article was presented at the 2015 annual meeting of the Southern Political Science Association and the 2015 annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association under the title “Sequential Adjudication.”

References

Baird, Vanessa A. 2004. “The Effect of Politically Salient Decisions on the US Supreme Court’s Agenda.Journal of Politics 66 (3): 755–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baird, Vanessa A. 2007. Answering the Call of the Court: How Justices and Litigants Set the Supreme Court Agenda. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press.Google Scholar
Baker, Scott, and Claudio Mezetti. 2012. “A Theory of Rational Jurisprudence.Journal of Political Economy 120 (3): 513–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnes, David W., and John M. Conley. 1986. Statistical Evidence in Litigation. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., and Bryan D. Jones. 1993. Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R. 2009. Agendas and Instability in American Politics. 2nd ed. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., Bryan D. Jones, and Peter B. Mortensen. 2014. “Punctuated Equilibrium Theory: Explaining Stability and Change in Public Policy.” In Theories of the Policy Process, 3rd ed., ed. Paul A. Sabatier and Christopher M. Weible, 59–103. Boulder, CO: Westview.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., and Leech, Beth L. 1998. Basic Interests: The Importance of Groups in Politics and in Political Science. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R. and Leech, Beth L. 2001. “Interest Niches and Policy Bandwagons: Patterns of Interest Group Involvement in National Politics.Journal of Politics 63 (4): 1191–1213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beim, Deborah, Alexander V. Hirsch, and Jonathan P. Kastellec. 2014. “Whistleblowing and Compliance in the Judicial Hierarchy.American Journal of Political Science 58 (4): 904–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beim, Deborah, and Kelly Rader. 2016. “Evolution of Conflict on the Courts of Appeals.” Working paper, Yale University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bickel, Alexander M. 1962. The Least Dangerous Branch: The Supreme Court at the Bar of Politics. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Boucher, Robert L., Jr., and Jeffrey A. Segal. 1995. “Supreme Court Justices as Strategic Decision Makers: Aggressive Grants and Defensive Denials on the Vinson Court.Journal of Politics 57 (3): 824–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan, and Matthew Stephenson. 2002. “Informative Precedent and Intrajudicial Communication.American Political Science Review 96 (4): 1–12.Google Scholar
Caldeira, Gregory A., and John R. Wright. 1988. “Organized Interests and Agenda Setting in the U.S. Supreme Court.American Political Science Review 82 (4): 1109–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callander, Steven, and Tom S. Clark. 2017. “Precedent and Doctrine in a Complicated World.American Political Science Review 111 (1): 184–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, Charles M. 1993. “New Avenues for Modeling Judicial Politics.” Paper prepared for the Conference on the Political Economy of Public Law, Rochester, NY, October 15–16. http://scholar.princeton.edu/sites/default/files/ccameron/files/newavenues.pdf.Google Scholar
Cameron, Charles M., Jeffrey A. Segal, and Donald R. Songer. 2000. “Strategic Auditing in a Political Hierarchy: An Informational Model of the Supreme Court’s Certiorari Decisions.American Political Science Review 94:101–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Tom S. 2009. “The Separation of Powers, Court-Curbing and Judicial Legitimacy.American Journal of Political Science 53 (4): 971–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Tom S., and Jonathan P. Kastellec. 2013. “The Supreme Court and Percolation in the Lower Courts: An Optimal Stopping Model.Journal of Politics 75 (1): 150–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Tom S., and Benjamin E. Lauderdale. 2012. “The Genealogy of Law.Political Analysis 20 (3): 329–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ely, John Hart. 1980. Democracy and Distrust: A Theory of Judicial Review. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Epp, Charles R. 1998. The Rights Revolution. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Lee, and Jack Knight. 1998. The Choices Justices Make. Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly.Google Scholar
Fienberg, Stephen E., ed. 1989. The Evolving Role of Statistical Assessments as Evidence in the Courts. New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishburn, Peter. 1977. “Condorcet Social Choice Functions.SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics 33:469–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fontana, David. 2011. Docket Control and the Success of Constitutional Courts. Cheltenham: Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, Justin, and Georg Vanberg. 2014. “Narrow versus Broad Judicial Decisions.Journal of Theoretical Politics 26:355–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gennaioli, Nicola, and Andrei Shleifer. 2007. “The Evolution of Common Law.Journal of Political Economy 115 (1): 43–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, Emily, Scott A. Hendrickson, and Michael S. Lynch. 2012. “The Ideological Divide: Conflict and the Supreme Court’s Certiorari Decision.Cleveland State Law Review 60:559–83.Google Scholar
Greenberg, Jack. 2004. Crusaders in the Courts: Legal Battles of the Civil Rights Movement. New York: Twelve Tables.Google Scholar
Hathaway, Oona A. 2001. “Path Dependence in the Law: The Course and Pattern of Legal Change in a Common Law System.Iowa Law Review 86:601–61.Google Scholar
Heclo, Hugh. 1978. “Issue Networks and the Executive Establishment.” In The New American Political Enterprise, ed. Anthony King. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Hurwitz, Mark S., Roger J. Moiles, and David W. Rohde. 2001. “Distributive and Partisan Issues in Agriculture Policy in the 104th House.American Political Science Review 95 (4): 911–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kastellec, Jonathan P. 2010. “The Statistical Analysis of Judicial Decisions and Legal Rules with Classification Trees.Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 7 (2): 202–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kersch, Ken I. 2004. Constructing Civil Liberties: Discontinuities in the Development of American Constitutional Law. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kornhauser, Lewis A. 1989. “An Economic Perspective on Stare Decisis.Chicago-Kent Law Review 65 (1): 63–92.Google Scholar
Kornhauser, Lewis A. 1992. “Modeling Collegial Courts I: Path Dependence.International Review of Law and Economics 12:169–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, Peter. 1987. “Sex Discrimination in Labor Markets: The Role of Statistical Evidence.American Economic Review 77 (4): 567–83.Google Scholar
Landes, William M., and Richard A. Posner. 1976. “Legal Precedent: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.Journal of Law and Economics 19 (2): 249–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lax, Jeffrey R. 2003. “Certiorari and Compliance in the Judicial Hierarchy: Discretion, Reputation, and the Rule of Four.Journal of Theoretical Politics 15 (1): 61–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lax, Jeffrey R., and Kelly T. Rader. 2009. “Legal Constraints on Supreme Court Decision Making: Do Jurisprudential Regimes Exist?Journal of Politics 72 (2): 273–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindquist, Stephanie, and David E. Klein. 2006. “The Influence of Jurisprudential Considerations on Supreme Court Decision Making: A Study of Conflict Cases.Law and Society Review 40 (1): 135–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, Kevin T. 1994. “Amici Curiae and Strategies for Gaining Access to the Supreme Court.Political Research Quarterly 47 (4): 821–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, Kevin T., and Gregory A. Caldeira. 1993. “Lawyers, Organized Interests, and the Law of Obscenity: Agenda Setting in the Supreme Court.American Political Science Review 87 (3): 717–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, Kevin T., and Barbara Palmer. 1995. “Issue Fluidity on the U.S. Supreme Court.American Political Science Review 89 (3): 691–702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, Kevin T. 1996. “Issues, Agendas, and Decision Making on the Supreme Court.American Political Science Review 90 (4): 853–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1986. “Covering, Dominance, and Institution-Free Properties of Social Choice.American Journal of Political Science 30:283–314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Nicholas R. 1980. “A New Solution Set for Tournaments and Majority Voting: Further Graph-Theoretical Approaches to the Theory of Voting.American Journal of Political Science 24 (1): 68–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1999. “Roundtable on Competition Authorities’ Enforcement Priorities.” Note DAFFE/CLP/WD(99)43 submitted by the Delegation of the United States to the Committee on Competition Law and Policy, Directorate for Financial, Fiscal and Enterprise Affairs, OECD, Paris.Google Scholar
Page, Scott E. 2006. “Path Dependence.Quarterly Journal of Political Science 1:87–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patty, John W., and Elizabeth Maggie Penn. 2014. Social Choice and Legitimacy: The Possibilities of Impossibility. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perry, H. W., Jr. 1991. Deciding to Decide: Agenda Setting in the United States Supreme Court. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Richards, Mark J., and Herbert M. Kritzer. 2002. “Jurisprudential Regimes in Supreme Court Decision Making.American Political Science Review 96 (2): 305–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Gerald N. 1991. The Hollow Hope: Can Courts Bring About Social Change? Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 1977. “Why Is the Common Law Efficient?Journal of Legal Studies 6 (1): 51–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubio, Luis, Beatriz Magaloni, and Edna Jaime. 1994. A la puerta de la ley: El estado de derecho en México. Mexico City: Cal y Arena.Google Scholar
Sanders, Elizabeth. 1999. Roots of Reform. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Spriggs, James F., II, and Paul J. Wahlbeck. 1997. “Amicus Curiae and the Role of Information at the Supreme Court.Political Research Quarterly 50 (2): 365–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 1999. One Case at a Time: Judicial Minimalism on the Supreme Court. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Tiberi, Todd J. 1993. “Supreme Court Denials of Certiorari in Conflict Cases: Percolation or Procrastination?University of Pittsburgh Law Review 54:861–92.Google Scholar
Tushnet, Mark V. 2004. The NAACP’s Legal Strategy against Segregated Education, 1925–1950. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Volokh, Eugene. 2003. “The Mechanisms of the Slippery Slope.Harvard Law Review 116:1026–1137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar