Hostname: page-component-6bb9c88b65-x9fsb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-07-23T22:24:26.391Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An experiment in the role of identity in fostering coordination

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2025

Abraham Aldama*
Affiliation:
Vote Rev, New York, NY, USA
Daniel Draganoff
Affiliation:
University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, USA
Gantavya Pahwa
Affiliation:
University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, USA

Abstract

Coordination problems arise in many economic, political, and social situations. Many times, authorities and institutions are created to solve these coordination problems. However, the success of these institutions depends on whether people are willing to follow their prescriptions. Using a behavioral experiment on Amazon Mechanical Turk we analyze whether an authority can aid in solving hawk-dove coordination games and whether its success depends on a shared identity by the players. The authority is represented in our experiment by a randomizing device that recommends actions to players to implement a socially efficient correlated equilibrium. In the game, players are better off following the recommendations if they believe others will do as well. We investigate whether people are more likely to follow recommendations when they have a shared identity. We find that the device's success is not driven by group membership, but rather by the content of its recommendations.

Information

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Economic Science Association 2024.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Acemoglu, D, Robinson, JA. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91, 5, 13691401.Google Scholar
Agranov, M, Schotter, A. (2013). Language and government coordination: An experimental study of communication in the announcement game. Journal of Public Economics, 104, 2639.Google Scholar
Akerlof, GA, Kranton, RE. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 3, 715753.Google Scholar
Aldama, A, Vásquez-Cortés, M, Young, LE. (2019). Fear and citizen coordination against dictatorship. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 31, 1, 103125.Google Scholar
Almendares, N, Landa, D. (2007). Strategic coordination and the law. Law and Philosophy, 26, 5, 501529.Google Scholar
Angeletos, G-M, Hellwig, C, Pavan, A. (2007). Dynamic global games of regime change: Learning, multiplicity, and the timing of attacks. Econometrica, 75, 3, 711756.Google Scholar
Arifovic, J, Boitnott, JF, Duffy, J. (2019). Learning correlated equilibria: An evolutionary approach. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 157, 171190.Google Scholar
Aumann, RJ. (1974). Subjectivity and correlation in randomized strategies. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1, 1, 6796.Google Scholar
Balliet, D, Wu, J, De Dreu, CK. (2014). Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 140, 6, 15561581.Google ScholarPubMed
Bar-Tal, D. (2000). Shared beliefs in a society: Social psychological analysis, Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Bernhard, H, Fehr, E, Fischbacher, U. (2006). Group affiliation and altruistic norm enforcement. American Economic Review, 96, 2, 217221.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (2006). The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Billig, M, Tajfel, H. (1973). Social categorization and similarity in intergroup behaviour. European Journal of Social Psychology, 3, 1, 2752.Google Scholar
Brandts, J, Cooper, DJ, Fatas, E. (2007). Leadership and overcoming coordination failure with asymmetric costs. Experimental Economics, 10, 3, 269284.Google Scholar
Carlsson, H, Van Damme, E. (1993). Global games and equilibrium selection. Econometrica, 61, 5, 9891018.Google Scholar
Cartwright, E, Wooders, M. (2014). Correlated equilibrium, conformity, and stereotyping in social groups. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16, 5, 743766.Google Scholar
Cason, TN, Sharma, T. (2007). Recommended play and correlated equilibria: An experimental study. Economic Theory, 33, 1, 1127.Google Scholar
Casper, BA, Tyson, SA. (2014). Popular protest and elite coordination in a coup d’état. Journal of Politics, 76, 2, 548564.Google Scholar
Charness, G. (2000). Self-serving cheap talk: A test of Aumann's conjecture. Games and Economic Behavior, 33, 2, 177194.Google Scholar
Chen, R, Chen, Y. (2011). The potential of social identity for equilibrium selection. American Economic Review, 101, 6, 25622589.Google Scholar
Chen, Y, Li, SX. (2009). Group identity and social preferences. American Economic Review, 99, 1, 431457.Google Scholar
Connor, P, Stancato, D, Yildirim, U, Lee, S, Chen, S. (2020). Inequality in the minimal group paradigm: How relative wealth and its justification influence ingroup bias. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 88, .Google Scholar
Cooper, R, DeJong, DV, Forsythe, R, Ross, TW. (1989). Communication in the battle of the sexes game: Some experimental results. The RAND Journal of Economics, 20, 4, 568587.Google Scholar
Cooper, R, DeJong, DV, Forsythe, R, Ross, TW. (1992). Communication in coordination games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 2, 739771.Google Scholar
Cooper, R, DeJong, DV, Forsythe, R, Ross, TW. (1993). Forward induction in the battle-of-the-sexes games. American Economic Review, 83, 5, 13031316.Google Scholar
Cooper, RW, DeJong, DV, Forsythe, R, Ross, TW. (1990). Selection criteria in coordination games: Some experimental results. American Economic Review, 80, 1, 218233.Google Scholar
Coppock, A, McClellan, OA. (2019). Validating the demographic, political, psychological, and experimental results obtained from a new source of online survey respondents. Research & Politics, 6, 1, 2053168018822174.Google Scholar
Crawford, V. (1998). A survey of experiments on communication via cheap talk. Journal of Economic Theory, 78, 2, 286298.Google Scholar
d’Adda, G, Dufwenberg, M, Passarelli, F, Tabellini, G. (2020). Social norms with private values: Theory and experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 124, 288304.Google Scholar
Dickson, E. (2010). Leadership, followership, and beliefs about the world: An experiment. New York University Working Paper.Google Scholar
Dickson, ES, Gordon, SC, Huber, GA. (2015). Institutional sources of legitimate authority: An experimental investigation. American Journal of Political Science, 59, 1, 109127.Google Scholar
Dickson, ES, Scheve, K. (2006). Social identity, political speech, and electoral competition. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 18, 1, 539.Google Scholar
Duell, D, Valasek, J. (2019). Political polarization and selection in representative democracies. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 168, 132165.Google Scholar
Duffy, J, Feltovich, N. (2010). Correlated equilibria, good and bad: An experimental study. International Economic Review, 51, 3, 701721.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D, Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory, The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Gintis, H. (2010). Social norms as choreography. Politics, Philosophy & Economics, 9, 3, 251264.Google Scholar
Grossman, G, Baldassarri, D. (2012). The impact of elections on cooperation: Evidence from a lab-in-the-field experiment in Uganda. American Journal of Political Science, 56, 4, 964985.Google ScholarPubMed
Habyarimana, J, Humphreys, M, Posner, DN, Weinstein, JM. (2007). Why does ethnic diversity undermine public goods provision?. American Political Science Review, 101, 4, 709725.Google Scholar
Hadfield, GK, Weingast, BR. (2012). What is law? A coordination model of the characteristics of legal order. Journal of Legal Analysis, 4, 2, 471514.Google Scholar
Hara, K., Adams, A., Milland, K., Savage, S., Callison-Burch, C., & Bigham, J. P. (2018). A data-driven analysis of workers’ earnings on amazon mechanical turk (pp. 114). New York, NY, USA: Association for Computing Machinery.Google Scholar
Hauser, D, Paolacci, G, Chandler, JJ. Kardes, FR, Herr, PM, Schwarz, N (2019).Common concerns with MTurk as a participant pool: Evidence and solutions. Handbook of research methods in consumer psychology, New YorkRoutledge 319337.Google Scholar
Kennedy, R, Clifford, S, Burleigh, T, Waggoner, PD, Jewell, R, Winter, NJ. (2020). The shape of and solutions to the MTurk quality crisis. Political Science Research and Methods, 8, 4, 614629.Google Scholar
Kranton, RE, Sanders, SG. (2017). Groupy versus non-groupy social preferences: Personality, region, and political party. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 107, 5, 6569.Google Scholar
Landa, D, Duell, D. (2015). Social identity and electoral accountability. American Journal of Political Science, 59, 3, 671689.Google Scholar
Malis, M, Smith, A. (2019). A global game of diplomacy. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 31, 4, 480506.Google Scholar
McAdams, RH, Nadler, J. (2005). Testing the focal point theory of legal compliance: The effect of third-party expression in an experimental hawk/dove game. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 2, 1, 87123.Google Scholar
Molnar, A. (2019). Smartriqs: A simple method allowing real-time respondent interaction in qualtrics surveys. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 22, 161169.Google Scholar
Moreno, D, Wooders, J. (1998). An experimental study of communication and coordination in noncooperative games. Games and Economic Behavior, 24, 1, 4776.Google Scholar
Morris, S, Shin, HS. (1998). Unique equilibrium in a model of self-fulfilling currency attacks. American Economic Review, 88, 3, 587597.Google Scholar
Morsky, B, Akçay, E. (2019). Evolution of social norms and correlated equilibria. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 116, 18, 88348839.Google ScholarPubMed
Morton, RB, Ou, K, Qin, X. (2020). Reducing the detrimental effect of identity voting: An experiment on intergroup coordination in china. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 174, 320331.Google Scholar
North, DC. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 3, 567576.Google Scholar
Postema, GJ. (1982). Coordination and convention at the foundations of law. Journal of Legal Studies, 11, 1, 165203.Google Scholar
Schelling, TC. (1960). The strategy of conflict, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Shayo, M. (2009). A model of social identity with an application to political economy: Nation, class, and redistribution. American Political Science Review, 103, 2, 147174.Google Scholar
Tanis, M, Postmes, T. (2005). A social identity approach to trust: Interpersonal perception, group membership and trusting behaviour. European Journal of Social Psychology, 35, 3, 413424.Google Scholar
Wilson, RK, Rhodes, CM. (1997). Leadership and credibility in n-person coordination games. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41, 6, 767791.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Aldama et al. supplementary material

Aldama et al. supplementary material
Download Aldama et al. supplementary material(File)
File 1.3 MB