We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
An abstract is not available for this content so a preview has been provided. Please use the Get access link above for information on how to access this content.
Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)
References
REFERENCES
Aligica, Paul D., and Tarko, Vlad. 2012. “Polycentricity: From Polanyi to Ostrom, and Beyond.” Governance25 (2): 237–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burgin, Angus. 2012. The Great Persuasion: Reinventing Free Markets since the Depression. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A.1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” The American Economic Review35 (4): 519–530.Google Scholar
Hess, Charlotte, and Ostrom, Elinor. 2011. Understanding Knowledge as a Commons from Theory to Practice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Kirzner, Israel M.1997. “Entrepreneurial Discovery and the Competitive Market Process: An Austrian Approach.” Journal of Economic Literature35 (1): 60–85.Google Scholar
Morgan, Mary S., and Boumans, Marcel. 2004. “Secrets Hidden by Two-Dimensionality: The Economy as a Hydraulic Machine.” In De Chadarevian, S. and Hopwoord, N., eds., Models: The Third Dimension of Science. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press, pp. 369–401.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Michael. 1940. The Contempt of Freedom: The Russian Experiment and After. London: Watts & Co.Google Scholar
Shackle, George L. S.1972. Epistemics and Economics: A Critique of Economic Doctrines. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, George L. S. 1973. An Economic Querist. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar