Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T14:22:09.626Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Effects of parity, sympathy and reciprocity in increasing social welfare

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 June 2020

Sandip Sen
Affiliation:
The University of Tulsa, e-mails: sandip@utulsa.edu, chad-crawford@utulsa.edu, apd615@utulsa.edu, rachnanandakumar@utulsa.edu, jah6484@utulsa.edu
Chad Crawford
Affiliation:
The University of Tulsa, e-mails: sandip@utulsa.edu, chad-crawford@utulsa.edu, apd615@utulsa.edu, rachnanandakumar@utulsa.edu, jah6484@utulsa.edu
Adam Dees
Affiliation:
The University of Tulsa, e-mails: sandip@utulsa.edu, chad-crawford@utulsa.edu, apd615@utulsa.edu, rachnanandakumar@utulsa.edu, jah6484@utulsa.edu
Rachna Nanda Kumar
Affiliation:
The University of Tulsa, e-mails: sandip@utulsa.edu, chad-crawford@utulsa.edu, apd615@utulsa.edu, rachnanandakumar@utulsa.edu, jah6484@utulsa.edu
James Hale
Affiliation:
The University of Tulsa, e-mails: sandip@utulsa.edu, chad-crawford@utulsa.edu, apd615@utulsa.edu, rachnanandakumar@utulsa.edu, jah6484@utulsa.edu

Abstract

We are interested in understanding how socially desirable traits like sympathy, reciprocity, and fairness can survive in environments that include aggressive and exploitative agents. Social scientists have long theorized about ingrained motivational factors as explanations for departures from self-seeking behaviors by human subjects. Some of these factors, namely reciprocity, have also been studied extensively in the context of agent systems as tools for promoting cooperation and improving social welfare in stable societies. In this paper, we evaluate how other factors like sympathy and parity can be used by agents to seek out cooperation possibilities while avoiding exploitation traps in more dynamic societies. We evaluate the relative effectiveness of agents influenced by different social considerations when they can change who they interact with in their environment using both an experimental framework and a predictive analysis. Such rewiring of social networks not only allows possibly vulnerable agents to avoid exploitation but also allows them to form gainful coalitions to leverage mutually beneficial cooperation, thereby significantly increasing social welfare.

Type
Adaptive and Learning Agents
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press, 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Badhwar, N. 1993. Altruism versus self-interest: sometimes a false dichotomy. Social Philosophy & Policy 10(1), 90117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baetz, O. 2015. Social activity and network formation. Theoretical Economics 10(2), 315340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barabasi, A. 2016. Network Science.Google Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J. & McCabe, K. 1995. Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior 10(1), 122142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. 1991. A comparative model of bargaining: theory and evidence. American Economic Review 81(5), 10961136.Google Scholar
Bolton, G. E. & Ockenfels, A. 2000. ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review 90(1), 166193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, L., Iba, W. & Sen, S. 2011. Modeling the emergence and convergence of norms. In IJCAI, 97102.Google Scholar
Cha, M., Haddadi, H., Benevenuto, F. & Gummadi, K. P. 2010. Measuring user influence in twitter: the million follower fallacy. In Proceedings of International AAAI Conference on Weblogs and Social, ICWSM ’10.Google Scholar
Danassis, P. & Faltings, B. 2019. Courtesy as a means to coordinate. In Proceedings of the 18th International Conference on Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems. International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, 665–673.Google Scholar
David, E. & Jon, K. 2010. Networks, Crowds, and Markets: Reasoning About a Highly Connected World. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dawes, R. M. & Thaler, R. H. 1988. Anomalies: cooperation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2(3), 187197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, T. & Taylor, P. D. 1998. The evolution of temporal patterns of selfishness, altruism, and group cohesion. The American Naturalist 152(1), 102113.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
de Vos, H. & Zeggelink, E. 1994. The emergence of reciprocal altruism and group-living: an object-oriented simulation model of human social evolution. Social Science Information 33(3), 493517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delgado, J. 2002. Emergence of social conventions in complex networks. Artificial Intelligence 141(1–2), 171185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, J. M. 2001. Learning to be thoughtless: social norms and individual computation. Computational Economics 18(1), 924.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. & Fischbacher, U. 2003. The nature of human altruism. Nature 425(6960), 785.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fehr, E., Gächter, S. & Kirchsteiger, G. 1997. Reciprocity as a contract enforcement device: experimental evidence. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 65(4), 833860.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferriere, R. & Michod, R. E. 1996. The evolution of cooperation in spatially heterogeneous population. The American Naturalist 147(5), 692718.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galán, J. M., Łatek, M. M. & Rizi, S. M. M. 2011. Axelrod’s metanorm games on networks. PLOS ONE 6(5), 111.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gambetta, D. 1988. Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations. Blackwell.Google Scholar
Goranson, R. & Berkowitz, L. 1966. Reciprocity and responsibility reactions to prior help. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 3(2), 227232.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Güth, W. & Yaari, M. E. 2004. Parity, sympathy and reciprocity. In Advances in Understanding Strategic Behaviour. Springer, 298313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krebs, D. 1970. Altruism – an examination of the concept and a review of the literature. Psychological Bulletin 73(4), 258302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahmoud, S., Miles, S. & Luck, M. 2016. Cooperation emergence under resource-constrained peer punishment. In Proceedings of the 2016 International Conference on Autonomous Agents & Multiagent Systems, AAMAS ’16, Richland, S. C. (ed). International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, 900–908.Google Scholar
Martinez-Coll, J. & Hirshleifer, J. 1991. The limits of reciprocity. Rationality and Society 3, 3564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, K., Houser, D., Ryan, L., Smith, V. & Trouard, T. 2001. A functional imaging study of cooperation in two-person reciprocal exchange. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 98(20), 1183211835.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Peleteiro, A., Burguillo, J. C. & Chong, S. Y. 2014. Exploring indirect reciprocity in complex networks using coalitions and rewiring. In Proceedings of the 2014 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multi-agent Systems, AAMAS ’14, Richland, S. C. (ed). International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, 669676.Google Scholar
Rabin, M. 1993. Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. The American Economic Review 83(5), 12811302.Google Scholar
Roth, A. E. 1995. Introduction to experimental economics’. In Kagel, A. and Roth, A. E. (eds). Handbook of Experimental Economics.Google Scholar
Salehi-Abari, A. & Boutilier, C. 2014. Empathetic social choice on social networks. In Proceedings of the 2014 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems, AAMAS ’14, Richland, S. C. (ed). International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, 693700.Google Scholar
Sally, D. 1995. Conversation and cooperation in social dilemmas: a meta-analysis of experiments from 1958 to 1992. Rationality and Society 7(1), 5892.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitz, D. 1993. Reasons for altruism. Social Philosophy & Policy, 10(1), 5268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, S. 1996. Reciprocity: a foundational principle for promoting cooperative behavior among self-interested agents. In Proceedings of the Second International Conference on Multiagent Systems, AAAI Press, 315321.Google Scholar
Sen, S. 2013. A comprehensive approach to trust management. In Proceedings of the 2013 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multi-agent Systems, AAMAS ’13, Richland, S. C. (eds). International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, 797800.Google Scholar
Taylor, P. 1992. Altruism in viscous populations – an inclusive fitness model. Evolutionary Ecology 6, 352356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsang, A. & Larson, K. 2014. Opinion dynamics of skeptical agents. In Proceedings of the 2014 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multi-agent Systems, AAMAS ’14, Richland, S. C. (ed). International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, 277284.Google Scholar
Watts, D. J. & Strogatz, S. H. 1998. Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature 393(6684), 440442.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zhang, Y., Aziz-Alaoui, M., Bertelle, C. & Guan, J. 2014. Local nash equilibrium in social networks. Scientific Reports 4, 6224.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed