Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T21:56:37.615Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

FISCAL POLICY MULTIPLIERS IN AN RBC MODEL WITH LEARNING

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 July 2017

Kaushik Mitra
Affiliation:
University of Birmingham
George W. Evans
Affiliation:
University of Oregon and University of St Andrews
Seppo Honkapohja*
Affiliation:
Bank of Finland
*
Address correspondence to: Seppo Honkapohja, Bank of Finland, P.O. Box 160, FI 00101 Helsinki, Finland; e-mail: seppo.honkapohja@bof.fi.

Abstract

Using the standard real business cycle model with lump-sum taxes, we analyze the impact of fiscal policy when agents form expectations using adaptive learning rather than rational expectations (RE). The output multipliers for government purchases are significantly higher under learning, and fall within empirical bounds reported in the literature, which is in sharp contrast to the implausibly low values under RE. Positive effects of fiscal policy are demonstrated during times of economic stress like the recent Great Recession. Finally, it is shown how learning can lead to consumption and investment dynamics empirically documented during some episodes of “fiscal consolidations.”

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

An earlier version of the paper was circulated as “Fiscal Policy and Learning.” We are very grateful for financial support from ESRC Grant RES-062-23-2617 and from National Science Foundation Grant no. SES-1025011 without which this work could not have been carried out. Useful comments from referees and an associate editor are gratefully acknowledged. Any views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Bank of Finland.

References

REFERENCES

Alesina, A. and Ardagna, S. (2010) Large changes in fiscal policy: Taxes versus spending. Tax Policy and the Economy 24, 3568.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., Ardagna, S., Perotti, R. and Schiantarelli, F. (2002) Fiscal policy, profits, and investment. American Economic Review 92, 571589.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., Perotti, R., Tavares, J., Obstfeld, M. and Eichengreen, B. (1998) The political economy of Fiscal adjustments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 197248.Google Scholar
Auerbach, A., Gale, W. G. and Harris, B. H. (2010) Activist fiscal policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 24, 141164.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. and King, R. G. (1984) Macroeconomic effects from government purchases and taxes. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99, 817839.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Redlick, C. J. (2011) Macroeconomic effects from government purchases and taxes. Quarterly Journal of Economics 126, 51102.Google Scholar
Baxter, M. and King, R. G. (1993) Fiscal policy in general equilibrium. American Economic Review 83, 315334.Google Scholar
Benveniste, A., Metivier, M. and Priouret, P. (1990) Adaptive Algorithms and Stochastic Approximations. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Berardi, M. (2013) Escape dynamics and policy specification. Macroeconomic Dynamics 17, 123142.Google Scholar
Bertola, G. and Drazen, A. (1993) Trigger points and budget cuts: Explaining the effects of fiscal austerity. American Economic Review 83, 1126.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. (1990) Can severe fiscal contractions be expansionary? A tale of two small european countries: Comment. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1, 75111.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. and Leigh, D. (2013) Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers. Working paper WP/13/1, International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Branch, W. A. and Evans, G. W. (2006) A simple recursive forecasting model. Economic Letters 91, 158166.Google Scholar
Briotti, M. G. (2005) Economic Reactions to Public Finance Consolidation: A Survey of the Literature. ECB Occasional paper no. 38.Google Scholar
Campbell, J. Y. (1994) Inspecting the mechanism: An analytical approach to the stochastic growth model. Journal of Monetary Economics 33, 463506.Google Scholar
Carceles-Poveda, E. and Giannitsarou, C. (2008) Asset pricing with adaptive learning. Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 629651.Google Scholar
Chari, V., Kehoe, P. J. and McGrattan, E. R. (2007) Business cycle accounting. Econometrica 75, 781836.Google Scholar
Chetty, R., Guren, A., Day, M. and Weber, A. (2011) Are micro and macro labor supply elasticities consistent? A review of evidence on the intensive and extensive margins. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 101, 471475.Google Scholar
Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. and Rebelo, S. (2011) When is the government spending multiplier large? Journal of Political Economy 119, 78121.Google Scholar
Coenen, G., Erceg, C. J., Freedman, C., Furceri, D., Kumhof, M., Lalonde, R., Laxton, D., Lindè, J., Mouragane, A., Muir, D., Mursula, S., De Resende, C., Roberts, J., Roeger, W., Snudden, S., Trabandt, M. and in't Veld, J. (2012) Effects of fiscal stimulus in structural models. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4, 2268.Google Scholar
Cogan, J. F., Cwik, T., Taylor, J. B. and Wieland, V. (2010) New Keynesian versus old Keynesian government spending multipliers. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34, 281295.Google Scholar
Corsetti, G., Kuester, K., Meier, A. and Muller, G. J. (2010) Debt consolidation and fiscal stabilization of deep recessions. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 100, 4145.Google Scholar
Corsetti, G., Meier, A. and Muller, G. J. (2012) Fiscal stimulus with spending reversals. Review of Economics and Statistics 94, 878895.Google Scholar
Eusepi, S. and Preston, B. (2010) Central bank communication and expectations stabilization. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2, 235271.Google Scholar
Eusepi, S. and Preston, B. (2011) Expectations, learning and business cycle fluctuations. American Economic Review 101, 28442872.Google Scholar
Evans, G. W. and Honkapohja, S. (2001) Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Evans, G. W. and Honkapohja, S. (2013) Learning as a rational foundation for macroeconomics and finance. In Frydman and Phelps (2013) chap. 2, pp. 68–111.Google Scholar
Evans, G. W., Honkapohja, S. and Marimon, R. (2001) Convergence in monetary inflation models with heterogeneous learning rules. Macroeconomic Dynamics 5, 131.Google Scholar
Evans, G. W., Honkapohja, S. and Mitra, K. (2009) Anticipated fiscal policy and learning. Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 930953.Google Scholar
Evans, G. W., Honkapohja, S. and Mitra, K. (2012) Does Ricardian equivalence hold when expectations are not rational? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44, 12591283.Google Scholar
Frydman, R. and Phelps, E. (eds.) (2013) Rethinking Expectations: The Way Forward for Macroeconomics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Giannitsarou, C. (2006) Supply-side reforms and learning dynamics. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 291309.Google Scholar
Giavazzi, F. and Pagano, M. (1990) Can severe fiscal contractions be expansionary? A tale of two small European countries. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1, 75111.Google Scholar
Hall, R. E. (2009) By how much does GDP rise If the government buys more output? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2009, 183231.Google Scholar
Hamilton, B. F. and Neville, R. F. (2014) Imperfect transmission of technology shocks and the business cycle consequences. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18, 418437.Google Scholar
Heijdra, B. J. (2009) Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hemming, R., Kell, M. and Mahfouz, S. (2002) The Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy in Stimulating Economic Activity – A Review of the Literature. Working paper 02/208, International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E. G. and Vegh, C. A. (2013) How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers? Journal of Monetary Economics 60, 239254.Google Scholar
IMF (2010) World Economic Outlook, October 2010. Washington, DC: IMF Publication Services.Google Scholar
King, R. G., Plosser, C. I. and Rebelo, S. T. (1988) Production, growth and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 21, 195232.Google Scholar
King, R. G. and Rebelo, S. T. (1999) Resuscitating real business cycles. In Taylor andWoodford (1999) pp. 927–1007.Google Scholar
Leeper, E. M., Traum, N. and Walker, T. B. (2011) Clearing Up the Fiscal Multiplier Morass. NBER working paper 17444.Google Scholar
Ljungqvist, L. and Sargent, T. J. (2012) Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, 3rd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Long, J. B. Jr. and Plosser, C. I. (1983) Real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy 91, 3969.Google Scholar
Marcet, A. and Nicolini, J. P. (2003) Recurrent hyperinflations and learning. American Economic Review 93, 14761498.Google Scholar
Marcet, A. and Sargent, T. J. (1989) Convergence of least-squares learning mechanisms in self-referential linear stochastic models. Journal of Economic Theory 48, 337368.Google Scholar
Mertens, K. and Ravn, M. O. (2014) Fiscal Policy in an Expectation Driven Liquidity Trap. Review of Economic Studies 81, 16371667.Google Scholar
Milani, F. (2007) Expectations, learning and macroeconomic persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 20652082.Google Scholar
Mitra, K., Evans, G. W. and Honkapohja, S. (2013) Policy change and learning in the RBC model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, 19471971.Google Scholar
Nunes, R. (2009) Learning the inflation target. Macroeconomic Dynamics 13, 167188.Google Scholar
Orphanides, A. and Williams, J. C. (2007) Robust monetary policy with imperfect knowledge. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 14061435.Google Scholar
Perotti, R. (1999) Fiscal policy in good times and bad. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 13991436.Google Scholar
Preston, B. (2006) Adaptive learning, forecast-based instrument rules and monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 507535.Google Scholar
Ramey, V. A. (2011a) Can government purchases stimulate the economy? Journal of Economic Literature 49, 673685.Google Scholar
Ramey, V. A. (2011b) Identifying government spending shocks: It's all in the timing. Quarterly Journal of Economics 126, 150.Google Scholar
Ravn, Morten O., Schmitt-Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2012) Consumption, government spending, and the real exchange rate. Journal of Monetary Economics 59, 215234.Google Scholar
Romer, C. D. and Bernstein, J. (2009) The Job Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Plan. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Sargent, T. J. (1999) The Conquest of American Inflation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sargent, T. J. (2008) Evolution and intelligent design. American Economic Review 98, 537.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. and Woodford, M. (eds.) (1999) Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (2011) Simple analytics of the government expenditure multiplier. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3, 135.Google Scholar