Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T16:55:00.619Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

INHERITED TASTES AND ENDOGENOUS LONGEVITY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2017

Luciano Fanti
Affiliation:
University of Pisa
Luca Gori*
Affiliation:
University of Genova
Cristiana Mammana
Affiliation:
University of Macerata
Elisabetta Michetti
Affiliation:
University of Macerata
*
Address correspondence to: Luca Gori, Department of Political Science, University of Genova, Piazzale E. Brignole, 3a, I-16125 Genova (GE), Italy; e-mails: luca.gori@unige.it, dr.luca.gori@gmail.com.

Abstract

This article aims at studying a general equilibrium model with overlapping generations that incorporates inherited tastes (aspirations) and endogenous longevity. The existence of standard-of-living aspirations transmitted between two subsequent generations in a context where the individual state of health depends on public investments in health has some remarkable consequences at the macroeconomic level. First, aspirations allow escaping from the well-known poverty trap scenario described by Chakraborty (2004). Second, the steady-state equilibrium may be destabilized through a super-critical Neimark–Sacker bifurcation when the health tax rate is set at too high or too low a level. This causes endogenous fluctuations in income and longevity.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We gratefully acknowledge that this work has been performed within the activity of the PRIN-2009 project “Structural Change and Growth,” MIUR (Ministry of Education), Italy. We are also indebted to Xavier Raurich, Jaime Alonso-Carrera, and participants at conferences “Structural Change, Dynamics and Economic Growth” held in Livorno, Italy on September 2013 and “International Conference on Applied Business and Economics” held in Manhattan, New York, USA, on October 2013. We are also indebted to two anonymous reviewers for valuable and stimulating comments allowing an improvement in the quality of the work. The usual disclaimer applies. The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

References

REFERENCES

Alonso-Carrera, J., Caballé, J. and Raurich, X. (2004) Consumption externalities, habit formation and equilibrium efficiency. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 106, 231251.10.1111/j.0347-0520.2004.00357.xGoogle Scholar
Alonso-Carrera, J., Caballé, J. and Raurich, X. (2005) Growth, habit formation, and catching up with the Joneses. European Economic Review 49, 16651691.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2004.03.005Google Scholar
Alonso-Carrera, J., Caballé, J. and Raurich, X. (2007) Aspirations, habit formation, and bequest motive. Economic Journal 117, 813836.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02051.xGoogle Scholar
Artige, L., Camacho, C. and de la Croix, D. (2004) Wealth breeds decline: reversals of leadership and consumption habits. Journal of Economic Growth 9, 423449.10.1007/s10887-004-4542-5Google Scholar
Ashraf, Q. and Galor, O. (2013) The ‘out of Africa’ hypothesis, human genetic diversity, and comparative economic development. American Economic Review 103, 146.10.1257/aer.103.1.1Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1992) Habits, addictions and traditions. Kyklos 45, 327345.10.1111/j.1467-6435.1992.tb02119.xGoogle Scholar
Blackburn, K. and Cipriani, G. P. (2002) A model of longevity, fertility and growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 26, 187204.10.1016/S0165-1889(00)00022-1Google Scholar
Caballé, J. and Moro-Egido, A. I. (2014) Effects of aspirations and habits on the distribution of wealth. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 116, 10121043.10.1111/sjoe.12069Google Scholar
Cervellati, M. and Sunde, U. (2011) Life expectancy and economic growth: the role of the demographic transition. Journal of Economic Growth 16, 99133.10.1007/s10887-011-9065-2Google Scholar
Cervellati, M. and Sunde, U. (2013) Life expectancy, schooling, and lifetime labor supply: theory and evidence revisited. Econometrica 81, 20552086.Google Scholar
Chakraborty, S. (2004) Endogenous lifetime and economic growth. Journal of Economic Theory 116, 119137.10.1016/j.jet.2003.07.005Google Scholar
de la Croix, D. (1996) The dynamics of bequeathed tastes. Economics Letters 53, 8996.10.1016/S0165-1765(96)00888-9Google Scholar
de la Croix, D. (2001) Growth dynamics and education spending: the role of inherited tastes and abilities. European Economic Review 45, 14151438.10.1016/S0014-2921(00)00060-XGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D. and Michel, P. (1999) Optimal growth when tastes are inherited. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23, 519537.10.1016/S0165-1889(98)00028-1Google Scholar
de la Croix, D. and Michel, P. (2002) A Theory of Economic Growth: Dynamics and Policy in Overlapping Generations. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511606434Google Scholar
Diamond, P. A. (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. American Economic Review 55, 11261150.Google Scholar
Ehrlich, I. (2000) Uncertain lifetime, life protection, and the value of life saving. Journal of Health Economics 19, 341367.10.1016/S0167-6296(99)00030-2Google Scholar
Fanti, L. and Gori, L. (2013) Fertility-related pensions and cyclical instability. Journal of Population Economics 26, 12091232.10.1007/s00148-012-0462-4Google Scholar
Fanti, L. and Gori, L. (2014) Endogenous fertility, endogenous lifetime and economic growth: the role of child policies. Journal of Population Economics 27, 529564.10.1007/s00148-013-0472-xGoogle Scholar
Fanti, L., Gori, L., Mammana, C. and Michetti, E. (2016) Complex Dynamics in an OLG Model of Growth with Inherited Tastes. MPRA working paper no. 69906.Google Scholar
Farmer, R. E. A. (1986) Deficits and cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 40, 7786.10.1016/0022-0531(86)90008-6Google Scholar
Fioroni, T. (2010) Child mortality and fertility: public vs private education. Journal of Population Economics 23, 7397.10.1007/s00148-009-0248-5Google Scholar
Fogel, R. W. (2004) The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Galor, O. (2005) From stagnation to growth: unified growth theory. In Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, pp. 171293. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Galor, O. (2011) Unified Growth Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.10.2307/j.ctvcm4h7mGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. (2012) The demographic transition: causes and consequences. Cliometrica, Journal of Historical Economics and Econometric History 6, 128.Google Scholar
Galor, O. and Moav, O. (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 11331191.10.1162/003355302320935007Google Scholar
Galor, O. and Özak, Ö. (2016) The agricultural origins of time preference. American Economic Review 106, 30643103.10.1257/aer.20150020Google Scholar
Galor, O. and Weil, D. N. (2000) Population, technology, and growth: from Malthusian stagnation to the Demographic Transition and beyond. American Economic Review 90, 806828.10.1257/aer.90.4.806Google Scholar
Gollin, D. (2002) Getting income shares right. Journal of Political Economy 110, 458474.10.1086/338747Google Scholar
Gómez, M. A. (2015) Equilibrium dynamics in an endogenous growth model with habit formation and elastic labor supply. Macroeconomic Dynamics 19, 618642.10.1017/S1365100513000503Google Scholar
Gori, L. and Michetti, E. (2016) The dynamics of bequeathed tastes with endogenous fertility. Economics Letters 149, 7982.10.1016/j.econlet.2016.10.018Google Scholar
Grandmont, J. M. (1985) On endogenous competitive business cycles. Econometrica 53, 9951045.10.2307/1911010Google Scholar
Grandmont, J. M., Pintus, P. and de Vilder, R. (1998) Capital-labor substitution and competitive nonlinear endogenous business cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 80, 1459.10.1006/jeth.1997.2383Google Scholar
Hall, R. E. and Jones, C. I. (2007) The value of life and the rise in health spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, 3972.10.1162/qjec.122.1.39Google Scholar
Ikefuji, M. and Mino, K. (2009) Internal vs. External Habit Formation in a Growing Economy with Overlapping Generations. ISER discussion paper no. 750, Osaka University.Google Scholar
Kaneko, A., Kato, H., Shinozaki, T. and Yanagihara, M. (2016) Bequeathed tastes and fertility in an endogenous growth model. Economics Bulletin 36, 14221429.Google Scholar
Leung, M. C. M. and Wang, Y. (2010) Endogenous health care, life expectancy and economic growth. Pacific Economic Review 15, 1131.10.1111/j.1468-0106.2009.00486.xGoogle Scholar
Livi-Bacci, M. (2006) A Concise History of World Population, 4th ed. Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell.Google Scholar
Lorentzen, P., McMillan, J. and Wacziarg, R. (2008) Death and development. Journal of Economic Growth 13, 81124.10.1007/s10887-008-9029-3Google Scholar
Michel, P. and de la Croix, D. (2000) Myopic and perfect foresight in the OLG model. Economics Letters 67, 5360.10.1016/S0165-1765(99)00246-3Google Scholar
Nakamura, H. and Mihara, Y. (2016) Effect of public health investment on economic development via savings and fertility. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20, 13411358.10.1017/S1365100514000911Google Scholar
Raut, L. K. and Srinivasan, T. N. (1994) Dynamics of endogenous growth. Economic Theory 4, 770790.10.1007/BF01212030Google Scholar
Reichlin, P. (1986) Equilibrium cycles in an overlapping generations economy with production. Journal of Economic Theory 40, 89102.10.1016/0022-0531(86)90009-8Google Scholar
Schäfer, A. and Valente, S. (2011) Habit formation, dynastic altruism and population dynamics. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 365397.10.1017/S136510051000009XGoogle Scholar
Weil, D. N. (2007) Accounting for the effect of health on economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, 12651306.10.1162/qjec.122.3.1265Google Scholar
World Bank (2015) World Development Indicators Database. Washington D.C., US: World Bank.Google Scholar
World Health Statistics (2015) Part II. Global Health Indicators. Switzerland: WHO Press.Google Scholar
Yasui, D. (2016) Adult longevity and growth takeoff. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20, 165188.10.1017/S1365100514000285Google Scholar