Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-8ctnn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T13:06:42.715Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

NEWS ABOUT TAXES AND EXPECTATIONS-DRIVEN BUSINESS CYCLES

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 November 2017

Anca-Ioana Sirbu*
Affiliation:
Western Washington University
*
Address correspondence to: Anca-Ioana Sirbu, Department of Economics, Western Washington University, Bellingham, WA 98225, USA; e-mail: anca.sirbu@wwu.edu.

Abstract

This paper analyzes the possibility of expectations-driven business cycles to emerge in a one-sector real business cycle model if the unique driving force is news about future income tax rates. We find that good news about labor income tax rates cannot generate expectations-driven business cycles, whereas good news about capital income tax rates can. We show that a one-sector real business cycle model enriched with (i) variable capital utilization and (ii) investment adjustment costs and driven solely by news shocks about capital income tax rates is able to generate qualitatively and quantitatively realistic business cycle fluctuations. In contrast to numerous studies in the news-driven business cycle literature, our model maintains separable preferences.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I am grateful to Jang-Ting Guo for very helpful advice and continuous support throughout this project and to Richard Arnott for insightful comments. I would also like to thank Richard Suen, two anonymous referees, and seminar and conference participants at U.C. Riverside, the 20th Annual Symposium of the Society for Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 81st Annual Meetings of the Southern Economic Association, 18th International Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance, Spring 2013 Midwest Macro Meetings, 2013 Annual Conference of the Association for Public Economic Theory, and the 2013 Annual Conference of the Society for Advancement in Economic Theory for helpful suggestions and comments. Of course, all remaining errors are my own.

References

REFERENCES

Adda, Jérôme and Cooper, Russell W. (2003) Dynamic Economics: Quantitative Methods and Applications. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Atkinson, Anthony B. and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1980) Lectures on Public Economics. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Baxter, Marianne and Crucini, Mario J. (1995) Business cycles and the asset structure of foreign trade. International Economic Review 36, 821854.Google Scholar
Baxter, Marianne and Farr, Dorsey D. (2005) Variable capital utilization and international business cycles. Journal of International Economics 65, 335347.Google Scholar
Beaudry, Paul and Portier, Franck (2004) An exploration into Pigou's theory of cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 11831216.Google Scholar
Beaudry, Paul and Portier, Franck (2007) When can changes in expectations cause business cycle fluctuations in neo-classical settings? Journal of Economic Theory 135, 458477.Google Scholar
Beaudry, Paul and Lucke, Bernd (2009) Letting different views about business cycles compete. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 24, 413455.Google Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier and Perotti, Roberto (2002) An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4), 13291368.Google Scholar
Bloom, Nicholas (2014) Fluctuations in uncertainty. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28 (2), 153176.Google Scholar
Braun, R. Anton (1994) Tax disturbances and real economic activity in the postwar United States. Journal of Monetary Economics 33 (3), 441462.Google Scholar
Chang, Ly-June (1992) Business cycles with distorting taxes and disaggregated capital markets. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19, 9851009.Google Scholar
Christiano, Lawrence, Eichenbaum, Martin, and Evans, Charles (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113, 145.Google Scholar
Fernandez-Villaverde, Jesus, Guerron-Quintana, Pablo, Kuster, Keith, and Rubio-Ramirez, Juan F. (2015) Fiscal volatility shocks and economic activity. American Economic Review 105, 33523384.Google Scholar
Guo, Jang-Ting, Sirbu, Anca-Ioana, and Weder, Mark (2015) News about aggregate demand and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 72, 8396.Google Scholar
Hansen, Gary D. (1985) Indivisible labor and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 16, 309327.Google Scholar
House, Christopher L. and Shapiro, Matthew D. (2004) Phased-in Tax Cuts and Economic Activity. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 10415.Google Scholar
House, Christopher L. and Shapiro, Matthew D. (2006) Phased-in tax cuts and economic activity. American Economic Review 96, 18351849.Google Scholar
Jaimovich, Nir and Rebelo, Sergio (2009) Can news about the future drive the business cycle? American Economic Review 99, 10971118.Google Scholar
Jones, John Bailey (2002) Has fiscal policy helped stabilize the postwar U.S. economy? Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 709746.Google Scholar
Karnizova, Lilia (2010) The spirit of capitalism and expectation-driven business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 57 (6), 739752.Google Scholar
King, Robert G., Plosser, Charles I., and Rebelo, Sergio T. (1988) Production, growth and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 21, 195232.Google Scholar
Leeper, Eric M., Richter, Alexander W., and Walker, Todd B. (2012) Quantitative effects of fiscal foresight. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2), 115144.Google Scholar
Leeper, Eric M. and Walker, Todd B. (2011) Information flows and news-driven business cycles. Review of Economic Dynamics 14, 5571.Google Scholar
Leeper, Eric M., Walker, Todd B., and Yang, Shu-Chun Susan (2013) Fiscal foresight and information flows. Econometrica 81 (3), 11151145.Google Scholar
McGrattan, Ellen R. (1994) The macroeconomic effects of distortionary taxation. Journal of Monetary Economics 33 (3), 573601.Google Scholar
Mertens, Karel and Ravn, Morten (2012) Empirical evidence on the aggregate effects of anticipated and unanticipated U.S. tax policy shocks. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2), 145181.Google Scholar
Mulligan, Casey B. (2002) Capital, Interest, and Aggregate Intertemporal Substitution. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 9373.Google Scholar
Pavlov, Oscar and Weder, Mark (2013) Countercyclical markups and news-driven business cycles. Review of Economic Dynamics 16, 371382.Google Scholar
Poterba, James M. (1988) Are consumers forward looking? Evidence from fiscal experiments. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 78, 413418.Google Scholar
Ramey, Valerie (2011) Identifying government spending shocks: It's all in the timing. Quarterly Journal of Economics 126, 150.Google Scholar
Romer, Christina D. and Romer, David H. (2010) The macroeconomic effects of tax changes: Estimates based on a new measure of fiscal shocks. American Economic Review 100, 763801.Google Scholar
Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie and Uríbe, Martin (2012) What's news in business cycles. Econometrica 80, 27332764.Google Scholar
Tsai, Yi-Chan (2012) News shocks and costly technology adoption. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Vissing-Jorgensen, Annette and Attanasio, Orazio P. (2003) Stock-market participation, intertemporal substitution, and risk-aversion. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 93, 383391.Google Scholar
Yang, Shu-Chun Susan (2005) Quantifying tax effects under policy foresight. Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (8), 15571568.Google Scholar
Yang, Shu-Chun Susan (2007) A Chronology of Postwar U.S. Federal Income Tax Policy. Center for Applied Economics and Policy Research, working paper 2007-21.Google Scholar