Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-11T08:10:21.633Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A NONLINEAR ANALYSIS OF THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE–CONSUMPTION RELATIONSHIP

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 July 2017

Efthymios G. Pavlidis
Affiliation:
Lancaster University Management School
Ivan Paya*
Affiliation:
Lancaster University Management School
David A. Peel
Affiliation:
Lancaster University Management School
*
Address correspondence to: Ivan Paya, Department of Economics, Lancaster University Management School, Lancaster LA1 4YX, UK; e-mail: i.paya@lancaster.ac.uk.

Abstract

A variety of international macroeconomic models predict a relationship between the real exchange rate and consumption. The empirical evidence in favor of such a relationship is limited, the so-called Backus and Smith puzzle. In this paper, we extend the analysis to allow for nonlinear dynamics and volatility changes across exchange rate regimes. Our findings suggest that long-run relationships in line with standard international business cycle models do exist for many Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries. Further, Monte Carlo experiments illustrate that the nonlinear models can generate the Backus and Smith and the exchange rate disconnect puzzles. In this paper, we also contribute to the nonlinear real exchange rate literature by establishing a theoretical relationship between volatility and persistence. In accordance with the theoretical results, our empirical findings suggest that the increase in volatility in the post-Bretton Woods era is associated with relatively fast mean reversion of the real rate toward its equilibrium value.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We are grateful to participants of the 2nd International Workshop on Financial Markets and Nonlinear Dynamics for useful comments and suggestions. Documentation about the data used in this paper is available from the Lancaster University data archive at http://dx.doi.org/10.17635/lancaster/researchdata/84.

References

REFERENCES

Backus, David K. and Smith, Gregor W. (1993) Consumption and real exchange rates in dynamic economies with non-traded goods. Journal of International Economics 35 (3), 297316.Google Scholar
Balassa, Béla (1964) The purchasing power parity doctrine: A reappraisal. Journal of Political Economy 72 (6), 584596.Google Scholar
Benigno, Gianluca and Thoenissen, Christoph (2008) Consumption and real exchange rates with incomplete markets and non-traded goods. Journal of International Money and Finance 27 (6), 926948.Google Scholar
Bombardini, Matilde and Trebbi, Francesco (2012) Risk aversion and expected utility theory: An experiment with large and small stakes. Journal of the European Economic Association 10 (6), 13481399.Google Scholar
Chari, Varadarajan V., Kehoe, Patrick J., and McGrattan, Ellen R. (2002) Can sticky price models generate volatile and persistent real exchange rates? Review of Economic Studies 69 (6), 533563.Google Scholar
Chetty, Raj (2006) A new method of estimating risk aversion. American Economic Review 96 (5), 18211834.Google Scholar
Dmitriev, Alexandre and Krznar, Ivo (2012) Habit persistence and international comovements. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16 (S3), 312330.Google Scholar
Dumas, Bernard (1992) Dynamic equilibrium and the real exchange rate in a spatially separated world. Review of Financial Studies 5 (2), 153180.Google Scholar
Granger, Clive W. J. and Teräsvirta, Timo (1993) Modelling Nonlinear Economic Relationships. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Head, Allen C., Mattina, Todd D., and Smith, Gregor W. (2004) Real exchange rates, preferences, and incomplete markets: Evidence, 1961–2001. Canadian Journal of Economics 37 (3), 782801.Google Scholar
Johansen, Søren (1991) Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica 59 (6), 15511580.Google Scholar
Kilian, Lutz and Taylor, Mark P. (2001) Why is it so Difficult to Beat the Random Walk Forecast of Exchange Rates. Working paper series 088, European Central Bank.Google Scholar
King, Robert G., Plosser, Charles I., and Rebelo, Sergio T. (1988) Production, growth and business cycles, I. The basic neoclassical model. Journal of Monetary Economcis 21 (2), 195232.Google Scholar
Kollmann, Robert (1995) Consumption, real exchange rates and the structure of international asset markets. Journal of International Money and Finance 14 (2), 191211.Google Scholar
Kollmann, Robert (2012) Limited asset market participation and the consumption-real exchange rate anomaly. Canadian Journal of Economics 45 (2), 566584.Google Scholar
Koop, Gary, Pesaran, M. Hashem, and Potter, Simon M. (1996) Impulse response analysis in nonlinear multivariate models. Journal of Econometrics 74 (1), 119147.Google Scholar
Layard, Richard, Mayraz, Guy, and Nickell, Stephen (2008) The marginal utility of income. Journal of Public Economics 92 (8), 18461857.Google Scholar
Li, Nan (2014) Transaction costs, nonfundamental uncertainty, and the exchange rate disconnect. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18 (08), 17511772.Google Scholar
Lothian, James R. and Taylor, Mark P. (2008) Real exchange rates over the past two centuries: How important is the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect? Economic Journal 118 (532), 17421763.Google Scholar
Michael, Panos, Nobay, A. Robert, and Peel, David A. (1997) Transactions costs and nonlinear adjustment in real exchange rates: An empirical investigation. Journal of Political Economy 105 (4), 862879.Google Scholar
Mussa, Michael L. (1986) Nominal exchange rate regimes and the behaviour of real exchange rates: Evidence and implications. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 25, 117214.Google Scholar
Pavlidis, Efthymios G., Paya, Ivan, and Peel, David A. (2015) Testing for linear and nonlinear Granger causality in the real exchange rate–consumption relation. Economics Letters 132, 1317.Google Scholar
Paya, Ivan and Peel, David A. (2006) A new analysis of the determinants of the real dollar-sterling exchange rate: 1871–1994. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38 (8), 19711990.Google Scholar
Rogoff, Kenneth S. (1996) The purchasing power parity puzzle. Journal of Economic Literature 34 (2), 647668.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul (1964) Theoretical notes on trade problems. Review of Economics and Statistics 46 (2), 145154.Google Scholar
Taylor, Mark P. and Kilian, Lutz (2003) Why is it so difficult to beat the random walk forecast of exchange rates? Journal of International Economics 60 (1), 85107.Google Scholar
Taylor, Mark P., Peel, David A., and Sarno, Lucio (2001) Nonlinear mean-reversion in real exchange rates: toward a solution to the purchasing power parity puzzles. International Economic Review 42 (4), 10151042.Google Scholar
Teräsvirta, Timo (1994) Specification, Estimation, and evaluation of smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of the American Statistical Association 89 (425), 208218.Google Scholar
Wada, Tatsuma (2014) The role of transitory and persistent shocks in the consumption correlation and international comovement puzzles. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18 (6), 12341270.Google Scholar