Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-8ctnn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T12:18:58.582Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

SECTORAL CHANGES AND THE INCREASE IN WOMEN'S LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 May 2010

Rahşan Akbulut*
Affiliation:
Pomona College
*
Address correspondence to: Rahşan Akbulut, The George L. Argyros School of Business and Economics, Chapman University, One University Dr., Orange, CA 92866, USA; e-mail: akbulut@chapman.edu.

Abstract

Throughout the second half of the 20th century, women in the United States decided to move increasingly into the labor market. This paper investigates the growth of the service sector as an explanation for the increase in women's employment. It develops an economic model that can account for the increase in women's employment and the growth of the service sector at the same time. A growth model with two sectors and a home production technology is constructed in order to quantitatively assess the contribution of sectoral productivity differences to the change in women's employment decision. The sectoral productivities are taken from the data. This model demonstrates that a higher rate of productivity growth in market services compared to home services can account for a large fraction of the observed increase in women's labor supply from 1950 to 2005.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Aguiar, Mark and Hurst, Erik (2007) Measuring trends in leisure: The allocation of time over five decades. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (3), 9691006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albanesi, Stefania and Olivetti, Claudia (2009) Gender Roles and Medical Progress. NBER working paper 14873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attanasio, Orazio, Low, Hamish, and Sanchez-Marcos, Virginia (2008) Explaining changes in female labor supply in a life-cycle model. American Economic Review 98 (4), 15171552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailey, Martha J. (2006) More power to the pill: The impact of contraceptive freedom on women's life cycle labor supply. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (1), 289320.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. (1967) Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: Anatomy of an urban crisis. American Economic Review 57 (3), 415426.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1985) Human capital, effort, and the sexual division of labor. Journal of Labor Economics 3 (1), S33S58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, Jess, Rogerson, Richard, and Wright, Randall (1991) Homework in macroeconomics: Household production and aggregate fluctuations. Journal of Political Economy 99 (6), 11661187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caucutt, Elizabeth M., Guner, Nezih, and Knowles, John (2002) The timing of births: A marriage market analysis. Review of Economic Dynamics 5, 815855.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, Yongsung and Schorfheide, Frank (2003) Labor supply shifts and economic fluctuations. Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 17511768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisner, Robert (1988) Extended accounts for national income and product. Journal of Economic Literature 26, 16111684.Google Scholar
Fernández, Raquel (2007a) Women, work, and culture. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5 (2–3), 305332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández, Raquel (2007b) Culture as Learning: The Evolution of Female Labor Force Participation over a Century. Manuscript, New York University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández, Raquel, Fogli, Alessandra, and Olivetti, Claudia (2004) Mothers and sons: Preference formation and female labor force dynamics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (4), 12491299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fogli, Alessandra and Veldkamp, Laura (2008) Nature or Nurture? Learning and the Geography of Female Labor Force Participation. NBER working paper 14097.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Richard B. and Schettkat, Ronald (2005) Marketization of household production and the EU–US gap in work. Economic Policy 20 (41), 650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuchs, Victor R. (1978) The Service Industries and U.S. Economic Growth since World War II. In Backman, Jules (ed.), Economic Growth or Stagnation: The Future of the U.S. Economy, Chapter 6. Indianapolis, IN: Bobbs-Merrill Educational Publishing.Google Scholar
Fuchs, Victor R. (1980) Economic Growth and the Rise of Service Employment. NBER working paper 486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, Oded and Weil, David N. (1996) The gender gap, fertility, and growth. American Economic Review 86, 374387.Google Scholar
Goldin, Claudia (1990) Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic History of American Women. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Goldin, Claudia (2006) The quiet revolution that transformed women's employment, education, and family. American Economic Review 96 (2), 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldin, Claudia and Katz, Lawrence F. (2002) The power of the pill: Oral contraceptives and women's career and marriage decisions. Journal of Political Economy 110 (4), 730770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollin, Douglas, Parente, Stephen, and Rogerson, Richard (2007) The food problem and the evolution of international income levels. Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (4), 12301255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, Jeremy, Seshadri, Ananth, and Yorukoglu, Mehmet (2005) Engines of liberation. Review of Economic Studies 72 (1), 109133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Larry E., Manuelli, Rodolfo E., and McGrattan, Ellen R. (2003) Why Are Married Women Working So Much? Staff report 317, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.Google Scholar
Juster, Thomas F. and Stafford, Frank P. (1991) The allocation of time: Empirical findings, behavioral models, and problems of measurement. Journal of Economic Literature 29, 471522.Google Scholar
Knowles, John (2008) Why Are Married Men Working So Much? Manuscript, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Kongsamut, Piyabha, Rebelo, Sergio, and Xie, Danyang (2001) Beyond balanced growth. Review of Economic Studies 68, 869882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, Simon (1966) Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure, and Spread. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Locay, Luis (1990) Economic development and the division of production between households and markets. Journal of Political Economy 98, 965982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGrattan, Ellen R. and Rogerson, Richard (2004) Changes in hours worked, 1950–2000. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 28 (1), 1433.Google Scholar
McGrattan, Ellen R. and Rogerson, Richard (2008) Changes in the Distribution of Family Hours Worked since 1950. Staff report 397, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGrattan, Ellen R., Rogerson, Richard, and Wright, Randall (1997) An equilibrium model of the business cycle with household production and fiscal policy. International Economic Review 38 (2), 267290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ngai, Rachel and Pissarides, Christopher A. (2007) Structural change in a multisector model of growth. American Economic Review 97 (1), 429443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ngai, Rachel and Pissarides, Christopher A. (2008) Trends in hours and economic growth. Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 239256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olivetti, Claudia (2006) Changes in women's hours of market work: The role of returns to experience. Review of Economic Dynamics 9 (4), 557587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parente, Stephen L., Rogerson, Richard, and Wright, Randall (2000) Homework in development economics: Household production and the wealth of nations. Journal of Political Economy 108, 680687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogerson, Richard (2008) Structural transformation and the deterioration of European labor market outcomes. Journal of Political Economy 116 (2), 235259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tam, Henry (2003) Gender Role in Production, Demographic Transition and the Switch from Physical to Mental Human Capital. Working paper, York University.Google Scholar