Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T17:45:00.414Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

VOTING ONESELF INTO A CRISIS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 January 2016

Hans-Jörg Beilharz
Affiliation:
International University of Applied Science Bad Honnef, Bonn
Hans Gersbach*
Affiliation:
CER-ETH–Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich and CEPR
*
Address correspondence to: Hans Gersbach, CER-ETH–Center of Economic Research, ETH Zurich, Zurichbergstr. 18, 8092 Zurich, Switzerland; e-mail: hgersbach@ethz.ch.

Abstract

We suggest that voters' lack of recognition of complex economic links may give rise to economic policies that eventually lead to a crisis. We consider a two-sector economy in which a majoritarian political process determines governmental regulation in one sector: a minimum nominal wage. If voters recognize general equilibrium feedbacks, workers favoring market-clearing wages will form a majority across sectors. If voters take into account only direct effects in the regulated sector, not only workers that enjoy minimum wages but also workers in the other sector are willing to vote for wage rises in each period. The reason is that they expect higher real wages for themselves, too. The political process leads to constantly rising unemployment and tax rates. The resulting crisis may trigger new insights into economic relationships on the part of the voters and may reverse bad times.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Akerlof, G. (2002) Behavioral macroeconomics and macroeconomic behavior. American Economic Review 92 (3), 411433.Google Scholar
Ball, L. (2000) Near Rationality and Inflation in Two Monetary Regimes. NBER working paper 7988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barberis, N. and Thaler, R. (2002) A Survey of Behavioral Finance. NBER working paper 9222.Google Scholar
Beugnot, J. (2013) Binding minimum wage as an equilibrium selection device. Macroeconomic Dynamics 17 (7), 14111437.Google Scholar
Birney, M., Graetz, M.J., and Shapiro, I. (2006) Public opinion and the push to repeal the estate tax. National Tax Journal 59 (3), 439461.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. (2006) European unemployment: The evolution of facts and ideas. Economic Policy 21 (45), 559.Google Scholar
Blinder, Alan S. and Krueger, Alan B. (2004) What does the public know about economic policy, and how does it know it? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 327397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Board, O. and Chung, K. (2009) Object-Based Unawareness: Theory and Applications. Working paper, University of Minnesota.Google Scholar
Brenner, T. (1996) Learning in a Repeated Decision Process: A Variation-Imitation-Decision Model. Technical report, Max-Planck-Institute for Research into Economic Systems, Jena.Google Scholar
Caplan, B. (2002) Systematically biased beliefs about economics: Robust evidence of judgemental anomalies from the survey of Americans and economists on the economy. Economic Journal 112 (479), 433458.Google Scholar
Dekel, E., Lipman, B., and Rustichini, A. (1998) Standard space-state models preclude unawareness. Econometrica 66 (1), 159173.Google Scholar
Galanis, S. (2013) Unawareness of theorems. Economic Theory 52 (1), 4173.Google Scholar
Gersbach, H. and Mühe, F. (2011) Vote-buying and growth. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15 (5), 656680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gersbach, H. and Schniewind, A. (2011) Collective bargaining, awareness of general equilibrium effects, and unemployment. International Economic Review 52 (3), 693712.Google Scholar
Gersbach, H. and Wenzelburger, J. (2008) Do risk premia protect against banking crises? Macroeconomic Dynamics 12 (S1), 100111.Google Scholar
Halpern, J. and Rego, L.C. (2009) Reasoning about knowledge of unawareness. Games and Economic Behavior 62, 232262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heifetz, A., Meier, M., and Schipper, B.C. (2006) Interactive unawareness. Journal of Economic Theory 130 (1), 7894.Google Scholar
Kaas, L. and Madden, P. (2010) Minimum wages and welfare in a Hotelling duopsony. Economic Theory 43 (2), 167188.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., and Tversky, A. (eds.), (1982) Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Krupnikov, Yanna, Levine, Adam S., Lupia, Arthur, and Prior, Markus (2006) Public ignorance and estate tax repeal: The effect of partisan differences and survey incentives. National Tax Journal 59 (3), 425437.Google Scholar
Li, J. (2009) Information structure with unawareness. Journal of Economic Theory 144, 977993.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N.G. and Reis, R. (2002) Sticky information versus sticky prices: A proposal to replace the New Keynesian Phillips curve. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4), 12951328.Google Scholar
Mullainathan, S. and Washington, E. (2005) Sticking with Your Vote: Cognitive Dissonance and Voting. Yale working paper on economic applications and policy 14.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. and van Ours, J. (2000) The Netherlands and the United Kingdom: A European unemployment miracle? Economic Policy: A European Forum 15 (30), 135175.Google Scholar
Ozbay, E. (2008) Incorporating Unawareness into Contract Theory. Mimeo, University of Maryland.Google Scholar
Romer, D. (2003) Misconceptions and political outcomes. Economic Journal (113), 120.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A. (1998) Modeling Bounded Rationality. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Sargent, T.J. (1993) Bounded Rationality in Macroeconomics. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Seppecher, P. (2012) Flexibility of wages and macroeconomic instability in an agentbased computational model with endogenous money. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16 (S2), 284297.Google Scholar
Slemrod, J. (2006) The role of misconceptions in support for regressive tax reform. National Tax Journal 59 (1), 5775.Google Scholar
Visser, J. and Hemerijck, A. (1997) A Dutch Miracle. Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (2003) Imperfect common knowledge and the effects of monetary policy. In Aghion, P., Frydman, R., Stiglitz, J., and Woodford, M. (eds.), Knowledge, Information and Expectations in Modern Macroeconomics: In Honor of Edmund S. Phelps: Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar