Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T13:57:53.964Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1300 Years of the Pound Sterling

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 March 2020

Abstract

The article begins with an account of the way in which the value of the pound has changed over the last 1300 years or so. This is indicated in terms of silver and, for the last 7–800 years, also in terms of gold, wheat and Phelps-Brown's general cost of living basket. It is shown, for example, that the whole of the increase in the price of silver since 1000 has occurred in the last 60 years. These prices are used to indicate how the real wage of a building labourer has changed since the 13th century. The article then proceeds to an account of the evolution of the currency itself, from its beginning as a pound of silver cut into 240 pennies (following continential practice) to the move to a gold currency and the introduction of paper money. It concludes with a discussion of whether the whole concept of currency will eventually become obsolete.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2000 National Institute of Economic and Social Research

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I am grateful to Ray Barrell, Neil Millward and Sig Prais for their comments. This research has been supported by the ESRC under its ‘Evolving Macroeconomy’ programme.

References

Alogoskoufis, G. and Smith, R. (1995), ‘The Phillips curve, the persistence of inflation and the Lucas Critique: evidence from exchange-rate regimes’, American Economic Review, 81, pp. 1254–75.Google Scholar
Beveridge, W. (1939), Prices and Wages in England from the 12th to the 19th Century, London, Longmans.Google Scholar
Brenner, Y.S. (1962), ‘The inflation of prices in England, 1551-1650’, Economic History Review, 15, pp. 266–85.Google Scholar
Feaveryear, A. (1963), The Pound Sterling, second edn. revised by E.V. Morgan Oxford, Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hawtrey, R.G. (1947), The Gold Standard in Theory and Practice, Longmans Green & Co.Google Scholar
King, M. (1999), ‘Challenges for monetary policy: new and old’, presented to Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium, 27 August.Google Scholar
Malthus, T. (1798), An Essay on the Principle of Population and its Effects on Human Happiness, reprinted by Ward Lock, London, 1890.Google Scholar
Mitchell, B.R. (1962), Abstract of British Historical Statistics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mitchell, B.R. and Jones, H.G. (1971), Second Abstract of British Historical Statistics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Phelps-Brown, H. and Hopkins, S.V. (1955), ‘Seven centuries of the prices of consumables compared with builders' wage-rates’, Economica, 22, pp. 87133.Google Scholar
Robo, E. (1934), ‘Wages and prices in the hundred of Farnham in the thirteenth century’, Economic History, 3, pp. 2434.Google Scholar
Rolnick, A.J.,Velde, F.R. and Weber, W.E. (1996), ‘The debasement puzzle: an essay on medieval monetary history’, Journal of Economic History, 56, pp. 789808.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russell, J.C. (1948), British Mediaeval Population, Alberquerque, University of New Mexico Press.Google Scholar
Shuckburgh-Evelyn, S. (1798), ‘An account of some endeavours to ascertain a standard of weight and measure’, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London, 133, p. 1, pp. 132–76.Google Scholar
Spufford, P. (1988), Money and its Use in Mediaeval Europe, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thorold Rogers, J.E. (1903), Six Centuries of Work and Wages, London, Swan Sonnenschein and Co.Google Scholar