Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T16:21:47.710Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

MISCOORDINATION, POLITICS AND POPULISM

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 May 2022

Chanelle Duley
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Auckland, Auckland, New Zealand
Prasanna Gai*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Auckland, Auckland, New Zealand
*
*Corresponding author. Email: p.gai@auckland.ac.nz

Abstract

We present two models that shed light on two issues in the political economy of populism: incumbents who refuse to give up office following a democratic election; and politicians gambling with major policy shifts when their consequences are uncertain. In the democratic transition of power, common knowledge about the veracity of the election process enables citizens to threaten incumbents with protests if they attempt to retain their seats in power. If doubt over electoral integrity prevails, office-seeking incumbents sometimes reject electoral rules. In considering policy gambles, politicians supply policy shifts in response to voters and elites vying for a greater share of economic output. When the mapping from policy to outcomes is uncertain, voters opt for policy gambles, even though these are detrimental to their ex ante welfare, to redress the division of output. These models underscore the importance of institutions that address the source of each coordination failure.

Type
Special Issue Articles: The Political Economy of Populism
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of National Institute Economic Review

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Amiti, M., Redding, S. and Weinstein, D. (2019), ‘The impact of the 2018 tariffs on prices and welfare’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 33, 4, pp. 187210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amiti, M., Redding, S. and Weinstein, D. (2020), ‘Who’s paying for US tariffs? A longer term perspective’, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 110, pp. 541–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anand, K., Gai, P. and König, P. (2021), ‘Leaping into the dark: A model of policy gambles with self-fulfilling features’, Mimeo, University of Auckland.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, C.J. and Guillory, C.A. (1997), ‘Political institutions and satisfaction with democracy: A cross-national analysis of consensus and majoritarian systems’, American Political Science Review, 91, 1, pp. 6681.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D., Dorn, D., Hanson, G. and Majlesi, K. (2017), ‘Importing political polarization? The electoral consequences of rising trade exposure’, Working paper 22637, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baccini, L. and Weymouth, S. (2021), ‘Gone for good: Deindustrialization, white voter backlash, and U.S. presidential voting’, American Political Science Review, 115, pp. 550–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
BBC (2021), Samoa’s First Female PM Locked Out of Parliament by Losing Opponent, BBC, 24 May 2021.Google Scholar
Brown, G. (2019), A Citizens’ Assembly Is Now the Only Way to Break the Brexit Deadlock, The Guardian, 20 January 2019.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, E. (2010). ‘Regime change and revolutionary entrepreneurs’, American Political Science Review, 104, 3, pp. 446–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callander, S. (2008), ‘A theory of policy expertise’, Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 3, pp. 123–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callander, S. (2011), ‘Searching for good policies’, American Political Science Review, 105, 4, pp. 643–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, H. and Suen, W. (2016), ‘Falling dominoes: A theory of rare events and crisis contagion’, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 8, 1, pp. 228–55.Google Scholar
Chwe, M. (2001), Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and Common Knowledge, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
CNBC News (2018), Trump Tariffs Blamed for Slowdown, Less Hiring at New Volvo Plant in South Carolina, 29 November 2018.Google Scholar
Debelle, G. (2019), ‘Risks to the outlook’, Keynote address at the 14th Annual Risk Australia Conference, Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney, 15 August.Google Scholar
Diamond, D.W. and Dybvig, P.H. (1983), ‘Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity’, Journal of Political Economy, 91, 3, pp. 401–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dornbusch, R. and Edwards, S. (1991), The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duley, C. and Gai, P. (2021), ‘Electoral integrity, the concession of power, and the disciplining role of protests’, Mimeo, University of Auckland.Google Scholar
Edgerton, D. (2018), The Rise and Fall of the British Nation—A Twentieth Century History, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Edmond, C. (2013), ‘Information manipulation, coordination, and regime change’, Review of Economic Studies, 80, 4, pp. 1422–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J.D. (2011), ‘Self-enforcing democracy’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126, 4, pp. 1661–708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fetzer, T. and Schwarz, C. (2021), ‘Tariffs and politics: Evidence from Trump’s trade wars’, The Economic Journal, 131, 636, pp. 1717–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forbes (2020), Biden Will Be More Predictable than Trump on Trade, but Don’t Expect Tariff Rollbacks Anytime Soon, 8 November 2020.Google Scholar
Goodwin, M.J. and Heath, O. (2016), ‘The 2016 referendum, Brexit and the left behind: An aggregate-level analysis of the result’, The Political Quarterly, 87, pp. 323–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, J., Hellwig, T. and Fieldhouse, E. (2021), ‘Who gets what: The economy, relative gains and Brexit’, British Journal of Political Science, 52, 1, pp. 320–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guriev, S. and Papaioannou, E. (2021), ‘The political economy of populism’, Journal of Economic Literature, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Harrison, B. (1999), ‘The rise, fall and rise of political consensus in Britain since 1940’, History, 84, pp. 301–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J.C. and Selten, R. (1988), A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Huffington Post (2011), Did Hillary Clinton Really Support NAFTA? Aides, Biographers Say No, 25 May 2011.Google Scholar
Katz, M.L. and Shapiro, C. (1986), ‘Technology adoption in the presence of network externalities’, Journal of Political Economy, 94, 4, pp. 822–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, T. (1989), ‘Sparks and prairie fires: A theory of unanticipated political revolution’, Public Choice, 61, 1, pp. 4174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, A.T., Tucker, J.A. and LaGatta, T. (2015), ‘Elections, protest, and alternation of power’, The Journal of Politics, 77, 4, 1142–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, J. (2018), How Russia Helped Swing the Election for Trump, The New Yorker, 1 October.Google Scholar
Morris, S. and Shin, H.S. (2003), ‘Global games: Theory and applications’, in Dewatripont, M., Hansen, L.P. and Turnovsky, S.J. (eds), Advances Economics and Econometrics Theory and Applications Eighth World Congress, Volume 1, New York: Cambridge University Press. pp. 56114.Google Scholar
Morris, S. and Yildiz, M. (2019), ‘Crises: Equilibrium shifts and large shocks’, American Economic Review, 109, 8, pp. 2823–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norris, P. and Grömping, M. (2017), Populist Threats to Electoral Integrity: The Year in Elections, 2016–2017, Cambridge, MA: Electoral Integrity Project.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, M. (1996), ‘Models of currency crises with self-fulfilling features’, European Economic Review, 40, 3–5, pp. 1037–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Post and Courier (2015), Advantages Help Steer Volvo to South Carolina, 10 May 2015.Google Scholar
Powell, J. (2019), The Rise and Fall of Britain’s Political Class: From Westminster to Whitehall, Elites Are Failing and Our Political System Is Collapsing, New Statesman, 30 January.Google Scholar
Schama, S. (2020), The Two Americas: LBJ, MLK and What the Dramas of 1965 Can Teach a Polarised Nation, Financial Times, 29 October 2020.Google Scholar
Schelling, T.C. (1960), The Strategy of Conflict, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
The Guardian (2016), Trump Escalates Economic Tirade Against Free Trade, China and Globalism, 28 June 2016.Google Scholar
The Guardian (2020), It’s not Over: Trump Supporters Protest Biden Victory in Swing States, 8 November 2020.Google Scholar
The New York Times (2018), Tariffs Imperil a Hometown Business in South Carolina: BMW, 19 July 2018.Google Scholar
The Washington Post (2015), The CNN Democratic Debate Transcript, 12 October 2015.Google Scholar
Weingast, B.R. (1997), ‘The political foundations of democracy and the rule of the law’, American Political Science Review, 91, 2, pp. 245–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ziegler, C.E. (2018), ‘International dimensions of electoral processes: Russia, the USA, and the 2016 elections’, International Politics, 55, 5, pp. 557–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar