Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T09:34:38.490Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Why We Need a New Theory of Government

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 February 2006

Margaret Levi
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Washington, Seattle (mlevi@u.washington.edu)

Extract

In the 1970s I was among a group of scholars endlessly debating theories of the state. Others in the discussion were my recent predecessor as APSA President, Theda Skocpol, and my immediate successor, Ira Katznelson. What intrigued us was a vast literature, grounded in neo-Marxism and covering huge swaths of history and geography. Nearly all the important books and articles were by sociologists and historians, but with Structure and Change in Economic History, my then-colleague, economist Douglass North, transformed the debate by using economic models of transaction costs and property rights to model the state's role in economic prosperity over time. Most political scientists now acknowledge the importance of this perspective, but it nonetheless helped precipitate twenty years of divergence between historical and new economic institutionalists.Margaret Levi is Jere L. Bacharach Professor of International Studies in the Department of Political Science, University of Washington, Seattle (mlevi@u.washington.edu). Among her books are the single-authored Consent, Dissent and Patriotism (1997) and Of Rule and Revenue (1988) and the co-authored Cooperation Without Trust? (2005) and Analytic Narratives (1998). Many people offered me comments. I did not always take their advice, but I am grateful to Amit Ahuja, Paloma Aquilar, Marcelo Bergman, Maureen Eger, Ann Gryzmala-Busse, Bea Kelleigh, Bob Kaplan, Edgar Kiser, Victor Lapuente-Giné, Michael Lipsky, Kenneth Kollman, José-Maria Maravall, Peter May, Leonardo Morlino, Steve Pfaff, Kate Pflaumer, Frances Fox Piven, Christoph Pohlmann, Nancy Rosenblum, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, Bo Rothstein, Susan Stokes, Katherine Stovel, Joan Tronto, and Ashutosh Varshney. My greatest debt is to the two graduate students who read and commented on several drafts as well as located the materials I needed to write this presentation: John Ahlquist and Audrey Sacks.

Type
PRESIDENTIAL ADDRESS
Copyright
© 2006 American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglou, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2002. Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 123194.Google Scholar
Acemoglou, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005. Economic history and political science: Clarifying questions, methods and answers. Political Economist 12 (3): 4–5, 7, 11, 13.Google Scholar
Anderson, Perry. 1974a. Lineages of the absolutist state. London: Verso.
Anderson, Perry. 1974b. Passages from antiquity. London: Verso.
Arrow, Kenneth. 1951. Social choice and individual values. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Bachrach, Peter, and Morton S. Baratz. 1962. Two faces of power. American Political Science Review 56 (4): 94752.Google Scholar
Bachrach, Peter, and Morton S. Baratz. 1963. Decisions and nondecisions: An analytical framework. American Political Science Review 57 (3): 63242.Google Scholar
Bardhan, Pranap. 2004. Scarcity, conflicts and cooperation: Essays in political and institutional economics of development. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Bates, Robert H. 2001. Prosperity and violence. New York: Norton.
Bates, Robert H. 2005. Political insecurity and state failure in contemporary Africa. CID Working Paper (115).
Bates, Robert H., Avner Greif, Margaret Levi, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, and Barry R. Weingast. 1998. Analytic narratives. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Beissinger, Mark R. 2001. Nationalism and the collapse of the Soviet state. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bergman, M. 2002. Who pays for social policy? A study on taxes and trust. Journal of Social Policy 31:289305.Google Scholar
Bianco, William. 1994. Trust: Representatives and constituents. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Block, Fred. 1977. The ruling class does not rule. Socialist Revolution 33:628.Google Scholar
Boone, Catherine. 2003. Political topographies of the African state: Territorial authority and institutional choice. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bowles, Samuel. 1998. Endogenous preferences: The cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1): 75111.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 2000. Optimal parochialism: The dynamics of trust and exclusion in networks. Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts.
Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 2002. Social capital and community governance. Economic Journal 112:41936.Google Scholar
Braithwaite, John. 1998. Institutionalizing distrust, enculturating trust. In Trust and governance, ed. V. Braithwaite and M. Levi. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Brennan, Geoffrey. 1998. Democratic trust: A rational choice theory view. In Trust and governance, ed. V. Braithwaite and M. Levi. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson, and James D. Morrow. 2003. The logic of political survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Burns, James MacGregor 1977. Wellsprings of political leadership. American Political Science Review 71 (1): 26675.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall. 2002. Identity, expression and rational choice. In Political science: State of the discipline, ed. I. Katznelson and H. Milner. New York: Norton.
Churchill, Winston. 1974 [1947]. Speech, House of Commons, November 11, 1947. In Winston S. Churchill: His complete speeches, 1897–1963, ed. R. R. James. New York: Chelsea House.
Collier, Paul, Lani Elliott, Håvard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol, and Nicholas Sambanis. 2003. Breaking the conflict trap: Civil war and development policy. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Cook, Karen S, Russell Hardin, and Margaret Levi. 2005. Cooperation without trust? New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
de Waal, Alex. 2003. How will HIV/AIDS transform African governance? African Affairs 102:123.Google Scholar
Ensminger, Jean. 1999. Examining trust, cooperation, and fairness: A cross-cultural study using experimental economics. Pasadena: California Institute of Technology.
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. 1996. Explaining interethnic conflict. American Political Science Review 90 (4): 71535.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. 2004. Neotrusteeship and the problem of weak states. International Security 28 (4): 543.Google Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Armin Falk. 1999. Wage rigidity in a competitive incomplete contract market. Journal of Political Economy 107 (1): 10634.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John. 1991. Rationality and interpretation: Parliamentary elections in early Stuart England. In The Economic approach to politics, ed. K. R. Monroe. New York: Harper Collins.
Ferejohn, John. 1993. Structure and ideology: Change in Parliament in early Stuart England. In Ideas and foreign policy: Beliefs, institutions, and political change, ed. J. Goldstein and R. O. Keohane. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Ferejohn, John, and Deborah Satz. 1995. Unification, universalism, and rational choice theory. Critical Review 9 (1–2): 7184.Google Scholar
Fjeldstad, Odd-Helge 2004. What's trust got to do with it? Non-payment of service charges in local authorities in South Africa. Journal of Modern African Studies 42 (4): 53962.Google Scholar
Gates, William H., and Chuck Collins. 2003. Wealth and our commonwealth: Why America should tax accumulated fortunes. Boston: Beacon Press.
Gintis, Herbert. 2003. Solving the puzzle of prosociality. Rationality and Society 15 (2): 15587.Google Scholar
Goldstone, Jack, Ted Gurr, Barbara Harff, Marc A. Levy, Monty Marshall, Robert H. Bates, Colin H. Kahl, Pamela T Surko, John C. Ulfelder, and Alan N. Unger. 2000. State Failure Task Force Report: Phase III findings. McLean, VA: Science Applications International Corporation (SAIC).
Greif, Avner. 1994. Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist societies. Journal of Political Economy 102 (5): 91250.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1998. Self-enforcing political systems and economic growth: Late medieval Genoa. In Analytic narratives, ed. R. Bates, A. Greif, M. Levi, J.-L. Rosenthal and B. Weingast. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Greif, Avner, and David D. Laitin. 2004. A theory of endogenous institutional change. American Political Science Review 98 (4): 63352.Google Scholar
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2002. Redeeming the past: The regeneration of Communist successor parties in East Central Europe after 1989. Cambridge University Press Studies in Comparative Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Hagan, John. 1991. Destiny and drift: Subcultural preferences, status attainments, and the risks and rewards of youth. American Sociological Review 56 (5): 56782.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Alexander, John Jay, and James Madison. 2000 [1787]. The Federalist. New York: New American Library.
Hardin, Russell, ed. 2004. Distrust. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Hechter, Michael. 1975. Internal colonialism. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Hechter, Michael. 2000. Containing nationalism. New York: Oxford University Press.
Hechter, Michael, and William Brustein. 1980. Regional modes of production and patterns of state formation in western Europe. American Journal of Sociology 85 (5): 106194.Google Scholar
Henrich, Joseph, Robert Boyd, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr, and Herbert Gintis, eds. 2004. Foundations of human sociality: Economic experiments and ethnographic evidence from fifteen small-scale societies. New York: Oxford University Press.
Huckfeldt, Robert, and John Sprague. 1987. Networks in context: The social flow of political information. American Political Science Review 81 (4): 1197216.Google Scholar
Hume, David. 1947. Of the original contract. In Social contract, ed. S. E. Barker. London: Oxford University Press.
Jacobs, Lawrence, and Theda Skocpol, eds. 2005. Inequality and American democracy: What we know and what we need to learn. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Jervis, Robert. 1978. Cooperation under the security dilemma. World Politics 30 (2): 167214.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard H. Thaler. 1991a [1986]. Fairness and the assumptions of economics. In Quasi-rational economics, ed. R. H. Thaler. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard H. Thaler. 1991b [1986]. Fairness as a constraint on profit-seeking: Entitlements in the market. In Quasi-rational economics, ed. R. H. Thaler. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Kasfir, Nelson. 2004. Domestic anarchy, security dilemmas, and violent predation. In When states fail: Causes and consequences, ed. R. I. Rotberg. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Katznelson, Ira, and Barry R. Weingast, eds. 2005. Preferences and situations: Points of intersection between historical and rational choice institutionalism. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Keefer, Philip. 2004. What does political economy tell us about economic development—and vice versa? Annual Review of Political Science 7:24772.Google Scholar
Keohane, Nannerl O. 2005. On leadership. Perspectives on Politics 3 (4): 70522.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O. 2001. Governance in a partially globalized world. American Political Science Review 95 (1): 113.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O. 2002. Power and governance in a partially globalized world. London: Routledge.
Kiser, Edgar. 1994. Markets and hierarchies in early modern tax systems: A principal-agent analysis. Politics and Society 22 (3): 285316.Google Scholar
Kiser, Edgar, and Yoram Barzel. 1991. The origins of democracy in England. Rationality and Society 3:396422.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and social conflict. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kreps, David M. 1990. Corporate culture and economic theory. In Perspectives in positive political economy, ed. J. Alt and K. Shepsle. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kuran, Timur. 1995. Private truths, public lies. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Kurzban, Robert. 2003. Biological foundations of reciprocity. In Trust and reciprocity: Interdisciplinary lessons from experimental research, ed. E. Ostrom and J. Walker. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Laitin, David et al. 1994. Language and the construction of states: The case of Catalonia in Spain. Politics and Society 22 (1): 529.Google Scholar
Lake, David A. 1992. Powerful pacifists: Democratic states and war. American Political Science Review 86 (1): 2437.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1981. The predatory theory of rule. Politics and Society 10 (4): 43165.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1988. Of rule and revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Levi, Margaret. 1997. Consent, dissent and patriotism. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Levi, Margaret. 1998. A state of trust. In Trust and governance, ed. V. Braithwaite and M. Levi. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Levi, Margaret. 2000. When good defenses make good neighbors. In Institutions, contracts, and organizations: Perspectives from new institutional economics, ed. C. Menard. Colchester, UK: Edward Elgar.
Levi, Margaret. 2002. The state of the study of the state. In The state of the discipline, ed. I. Katznelson and H. Milner. New York: Norton (with APSA).
Levi, Margaret. 2005. Inducing preferences within organizations. In Preferences and situations: Points of intersection between historical and rational choice institutionalism, ed. I. Katznelson and B. R. Weingast. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Lieberman, Evan S. 2003. Race and regionalism in the politics of taxation in Brazil and South Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Lindblom, Charles E. 1982. Another state of mind. American Political Science Review 76 (1): 921.Google Scholar
Lukes, Steven. 1974. Power : a radical view. London: Macmillan.
Luong Jones, Pauline. 2002. Institutional change and continuity in post-Soviet Central Asia. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Macedo, Stephen, Yvette Alex-Assensoh, Jeffrey M. Berry, Michael Brintnall, David E. Campbell, Luis Ricardo Fraga, Archon Fung, William A. Galston, Christopher F. Karpowitz, Margaret Levi, Meira Levinson, Keena Lipsitz, Richard G. Niemi, Robert D. Putnam, Wendy M. Rahn, Rob Reich, Robert R. Rodgers, Todd Swanstrom, and Katherine Cramer Walsh. 2005. Democracy at risk: How political choices undermine citizen participation, and what we can do about it. Washington, D.C: Brookings.
Manion, Melanie. 2004. Corruption by design: Bribery in Chinese enterprise licensing. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Mann, Michael. 1986. The sources of social power: A history of power from the beginning to A.D. 1760. Vol. I. London and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mann, Michael. 1993. The sources of social power: The rise of classes and nation-states, 1760–1914. Vol. II. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mantzavinos, C. 2001. Individuals, institutions, and markets. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mantzavinos, C., Douglass C. North, and Syed Shariq. 2004. Learning, institutions, and economic performance. Perspectives on Politics 2 (1): 7584.Google Scholar
May, P. J. 2004. Compliance motivations: Affirmative and negative bases. Law & Society Review 38 (1): 4168.Google Scholar
McMillan, John, and Christopher Woodruff. 2000. Private order under dysfunctional public order. Michigan Law Review 98 (8): 242158.Google Scholar
Mehta, Pratap Bhanu. 2003. The burden of democracy. New Delhi: Penguin Books India.
Miller, Gary. 1992. Managerial dilemmas. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Moe, Terry. 2005. Power and political institutions. Perspectives on Politics 3 (2): 21933.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C. 2005. Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
North, Douglass C., and Robert Paul Thomas. 1973. The rise and decline of the western world. New York: Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C., and Barry R. Weingast. 1989. Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth century England. Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 80332.Google Scholar
O'Connor, James. 1973. The fiscal crisis of the state. New York: St. Martin's Press.
Olson, Mancur. 1993. Dictatorship, democracy and development. American Political Science Review 87 (3): 56776.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Ostrom, Elinor. 1998. A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action. American Political Science Review 92 (1): 122.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 2005. Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Pateman, Carole. 1988. The sexual contract. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Pinney, Neil, and John T. Scholz. 1995. Duty, fear, and tax compliance: The heuristic basis of citizenship behavior. American Journal of Political Science 39: 490512.Google Scholar
Posen, Barry R. 1993. The scurity dilemma and ethnic conflict. Survival 35 (1): 2747.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2004a. Economic history and political science. Political Economist 12 (2): 1, 3, 9–13.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2004b. Institutions matter? Government and Opposition 39 (4): 52740.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, Michael Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, and Frederick Limogi. 2000. Democracy and development: Political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950–1990. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Przeworski, Adam, and Michael Wallerstein. 1982. The structure of class conflict in democratic capitalist societies. American Political Science Review 76 (2): 21538.Google Scholar
Riker, William H. 1984. The heresthetics of constitution-making: The presidency in 1787, with comments on determinism and choice. American Political Science Review 78 (1): 116.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani, ed. 2003. In search of prosperity: Analytic narratives on economic growth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramnian, and Francesco Trebbi. 2004. Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and the integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth 9: 13165.Google Scholar
Root, Hilton L. 1989. Tying the king's hands: Credible commitments and royal fiscal policy during the Old Regime. Rationality and Society 1: 24058.Google Scholar
Root, Hilton L. 1994. The fountain of privilege: Political foundations of markets in Old Regime France and England. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1999. Corruption and government: Causes, consequences, and reform. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 2001. Trust, honesty and corruption: reflection on the state-building process. Archives Européennes de Sociologie 42 (3): 52670.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1998. The political economy of absolutism reconsidered. In Analytic narratives. See Bates et al.
Rotberg, Robert I., ed. 2004. When states fail: Causes and consequences. Princeton, Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Rothstein, Bo. 1998. Just institutions matter. London: Cambridge University Press.
Rothstein, Bo. 2005. Social traps and the problem of trust. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Sachs, Jeffrey, John W. McArthur, Guido Schmidt-Traub, Margaret Kruk, Chandrika Bahadur, Michael Faye, and Gordon McCord. 2004. Ending Africa's Poverty Trap. Brooking Papers on Economic Activity 1: 117216.Google Scholar
Sanchez-Cuenca, Ignacio. In progress. Preferences over choices. Madrid: Juan March Institute.
Schattschneider, E.E. 1960. The semisovereign people; a realist's view of democracy in America. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.
Schofield, Norman. 2000. Constitutional political economy: On the possibility of combining rational choice theory and comparative politics. Annual Review of Political Science 3: 277303.Google Scholar
Scholz, John T. 1998. Trust, taxes, and compliance. In Trust and covernance, ed. V. Braithwaite and M. Levi. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Scott, James C. 1985. Weapons of the weak. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Scott, James C. 1992. Domination and the arts of resistance: Hidden transcripts. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Skocpol, Theda. 1979. States and social revolutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Skocpol, Theda. 1985. Bringing the state back in. In Bringing the state back in, ed. P. B. Evans, D. Rueschemeyer, and T. Skocpol. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Sokoloff, Kenneth J., and Stanley Engerman. 2000. History lessons: Institutions, factor endowments, and paths of development in the New World. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (3): 21732.Google Scholar
Stokes, Susan C. 2001a. Mandates and democracy: Neoliberalism by surprise in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Stokes, Susan C. 2001b. Public support for market reforms in new democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Stovel, Katherine. 2004. “AIDS and social transformation.” Unpublished paper, Department of Sociology, University of Washington.
Thelen, Kathleen. 1999. Historical institutionalism in comparative politics. Annual Review of Political Science 2: 369404.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 2004. How institutions evolve: The political economy of skills in comparative-historical perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Tilly, Charles. 1975. The formation of national states in Western Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Capital, coercion, and European states, A.D. 990–1992. Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell.
Tilly, Charles. 2005. Trust and rule. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Tyler, Tom R. 1990. Why people obey the law. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Varshney, Ashutosh. 2002. Ethnic conflict and civic life. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1974. The modern world system. New York: Academic Press.
Ward, Michael D., and Kristin Bakke. 2005. Predicting civil conflict: On the utility of empirical research. Presented at Conference on Disaggregating the Study of Civil War and Transnational Violence, at University of California Institute of Global Conflict and Cooperation, San Diego.
Weber, Max. 1958. Politics as a vocation. In From Max Weber, ed. H. H. Gerth and C. W. Mills. New York: Oxford University Press.
Weiner, Myron. 1989. The Indian paradox: Violent social conflict and democratic politics. In The Indian paradox: Essays in Indian politics, ed. A. Varshney. New Delhi: Sage.
Weingast, Barry R. 1995. The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7 (1): 131.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1998. Political stability and civil war: Institutions, commitment, and American democracy. In Analytic narratives, ed. R. H. Bates, A. Greif, M. Levi, J.-L. Rosenthal and B. R. Weingast. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Wildavsky, Aaron. 1987. Choosing preferences by constructing institutions. American Political Science Review 81: 321.Google Scholar
Wilkinson, Steven. 2004. Votes and violence: Electoral competition and ethnic riots in India. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Wilkinson, Steven. In progress. Colonization, institutions and conflict.
Winter, Soren, and Peter May. 2001. Motivation for compliance with environmental regulations. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 20 (4): 67598.Google Scholar