Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T14:46:12.152Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The electoral costs of policy commitments

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 August 2018

Timm Betz*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Texas A&M University, 2102 Allen Building, 4348 TAMU, College Station, TX 77843, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: timm.betz@tamu.edu

Abstract

Existing arguments across political science posit that parties in government use domestic and international institutions to lock in their own policy preferences by tying the hands of successors. I demonstrate that these arguments contrast with the assumption of office-seeking parties and therefore portray an incomplete picture of the incentives of governments. The paper emphasizes the trade-off between implementing policy preferences, on the one hand, and exploiting partisan differences for electoral success, on the other hand: locking in a policy takes an issue off the table, but it also undermines a party’s ability to leverage differences to the opposition in elections. Because office-seeking parties need to take into account these electoral consequences, they have a disincentive to tie their successors’ hands. I advance this argument in the context of the establishment of independent central banks, provide empirical evidence, and suggest implications for the literature on international institutions.

Type
Original Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The European Political Science Association 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D, Johnson, S, Querubin, P Robinson, JA (2008) ‘When Does Policy Reform Work? The Case of Central Bank Independence’. NBER Working Paper Series No. 14033, Boston, MA.Google Scholar
Alesina, A (1987) Macroeconomic Policy in a Two-Party System as a Repeated Game. Quarterly Journal of Economics 102(3), 651678.Google Scholar
Barro, RJ Gordon, DB (1983) A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model. Journal of Political Economy 91(4), 589610.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B (2010) ‘Central Bank Independence, Transparency, and Accountability’. Speech at the Bank of Japan, Tokyo, Japan.Google Scholar
Bernhard, W (1998) A Political Explanation of Variations in Central Bank Independence. American Political Science Review 92(2), 311327.Google Scholar
Bernhard, W (2002) Banking on Reform: Political Parties and Central Bank Independence in the Industrial Democracies. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Bernhard, W, Broz, JL Clark, WR (2002) The Political Economy of Monetary Institutions. International Organization 56(4), 693723.Google Scholar
Bernhard, W Leblang, D (2002) Political Parties and Monetary Commitments. International Organization 56(4), 803830.Google Scholar
Bodea, C (2010a) Exchange Rate Regimes and Independent Central Banks: A Correlated Choice of Imperfectly Credible Institutions. International Organization 64(3), 411442.Google Scholar
Bodea, C (2010b) The Political Economy of Fixed Exchange Rate Regimes: The Experience of Post-Communist Countries. European Journal of Political Economy 26(2), 248264.Google Scholar
Bodea, C Hicks, R (2015a) International Finance and Central Bank Independence: Institutional Diffusion and the Flow and Cost of Capital. Journal of Politics 77(1), 268284.Google Scholar
Bodea, C Hicks, R (2015b) Price Stability and Central Bank Independence: Discipline, Credibility and Democratic Institutions. International Organization 69(1), 3561.Google Scholar
Boerzel, TA Risse, T (2003) Conceptualizing the Domestic Impact of Europe. In Featherstone, K and Radaelli, CM (eds), The Politics of Europeanization, 5780. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Boylan, DM (2001) Defusing Democracy: Central Bank Autonomy and the Transition from Authoritarian Rule. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Broz, JL (2002) Political System Transparency and Monetary Commitment Regimes. International Organization 56(4), 861887.Google Scholar
Clark, WR Arel-Bundock, V (2013) Independent but Not Indifferent: Partisan Bias in Monetary Policy at the Fed. Economics & Politics 25(1), 126.Google Scholar
Clark, WR Hallerberg, M (2000) Mobile Capital, Domestic Institutions, and Electorally Induced Monetary and Fiscal Policy. American Political Science Review 94(2), 323346.Google Scholar
Cruz, C, Keefer, P Scartascini, C (2015) The Database of Political Institutions. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.Google Scholar
Dai, X (2007) International Institutions and National Policies. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
de Figueiredo, RJP (2002) Electoral Competition, Political Uncertainty, and Policy Insulation. American Political Science Review 96(2), 321333.Google Scholar
Easterly, W Fischer, S (2001) Inflation and the Poor. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 33(2), 160178.Google Scholar
Franzese, RJ Jr. (1999) Partially Independent Central Banks, Politically Responsive Governments, and Inflation. American Journal of Political Science 43(3), 681706.Google Scholar
Franzese, RJ Jr. (2002) Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Democracies. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gandrud, C Grafstrom, C (2015) Inflated Expectations: How Government Partisanship Shapes Monetary Policy Bureaucrats’ Inflation Forecasts. Political Science Research and Methods 3(2), 353380.Google Scholar
Garriga, AC (2016) Central Bank Independence in the World: A New Data Set. International Interactions 42(5), 849868.Google Scholar
Giavazzi, F Pagano, M (1988) The Advantage of Tying One’s Hands. European Economic Review 32(5), 10551075.Google Scholar
Gilardi, F (2007) The Same, But Different: Central Banks, Regulatory Agencies, and the Politics of Delegation to Independent Authorities. Comparative European Politics 5(3), 303327.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, T (2005) International Substitutes for Domestic Institutions: Bilateral Investment Treaties and Governance. International Review of Law and Economics 25(1), 107123.Google Scholar
Goldstein, JO, Kahler, M, Keohane, RO Slaughter, A-M (2000) Introduction: Legalization and World Politics. International Organization 54(3), 385399.Google Scholar
Goodman, JB 1991 ‘The Politics of Central Bank Independence’. Comparative Politics 23(3):329–349.Google Scholar
Hibbs, DA Jr. (1977) Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy. American Political Science Review 71(4), 14671487.Google Scholar
ISSP Research Group (2008) International Social Survey Programme: Role of Government IV - ISSP 2006. Cologne: GESIS Data Archive, ZA4700 Data file.Google Scholar
Karcher, S Steinberg, DA (2013) Assessing the Causes of Capital Account Liberalization: How Measurement Matters. International Studies Quarterly 57(1), 128137.Google Scholar
Keefer, P Stasavage, D (2003) The Limits of Delegation: Veto Players, Central Bank Independence, and the Credibility of Monetary Policy. American Political Science Review 97(3), 407423.Google Scholar
Keohane, RO (1984) After Hegemony. Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Leblang, D (2002) The Political Economy of Speculative Attackes in the Developing World. International Studies Quarterly 46(1), 6991.Google Scholar
Leblang, D (2003) To Devalue or to Defend? The Political Economy of Exchange Rate Policy. International Studies Quarterly 47(4), 533559.Google Scholar
Milesi-Ferretti, GM (1995) The Disadvantage of Tying Their Hands: On the Political Economy of Policy Commitments. Economic Journal 105(433), 13811402.Google Scholar
Moravcsik, A (2000) The Origins of Human Rights Regimes: Democratic Delegation in Postwar Europe. International Organization 54(2), 217252.Google Scholar
Oatley, T (2010) International Political Economy. New York, NY: Longman.Google Scholar
Persson, T Tabellini, G (2002) Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Powell, GB Whitten, GD (1993) A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context. American Journal of Political Science 37(2), 391414.Google Scholar
Robinson, JA Torvik, R (2005) White Elephants. Journal of Public Economics 89(2–3), 197210.Google Scholar
Scheve, K (2004) Public Inflation Aversion and the Political Economy of Macroeconomic Policymaking. International Organization 58(1), 134.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G (2002) Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tufte, E (1978) Political Control of the Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Volkens, A, Lacewell, O, Lehmann, P, Regel, S, Schultze, H Werner, A (2011) The Manifesto Data Collection. Berlin: WZB.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: Link
Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Betz supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Betz supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 122.2 KB