Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T08:25:53.050Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Salaire minimum, allocations chômage et efficacité du marché du travail

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Frédéric Gavrel
Affiliation:
CERENE, Université du Havre, Faculté des Affaires Internationales, 25 rue Philippe Lebon, BP 420, 76057 Le Havre Cedex, France, frederic.gavrel@univ-lehavre.fr, isabelle.lebon@univ-lehavre.fr.
Isabelle Lebon
Affiliation:
CERENE, Université du Havre, Faculté des Affaires Internationales, 25 rue Philippe Lebon, BP 420, 76057 Le Havre Cedex, France, frederic.gavrel@univ-lehavre.fr, isabelle.lebon@univ-lehavre.fr.
Get access

Résumé

En utilisant un modèle d'appariement avec différenciation des qualifications, nous étudions l'effet du salaire minimum sur le fonctionnement du marché du travail. L'introduction d'un salaire minimum semble améliorer l'adéquation des travailleurs aux emplois en rendant les “mauvaises” associations impossibles. Trois résultats principaux sont ainsi établis. Premièrement, le salaire minimum peut augmenter l'efficacité du marché du travail. Ensuite, dès que le salaire minimum est suffisamment élevé pour contraindre effectivement la formation des salaires, les allocations chômage perdent tout effet positif sur la productivité et deviennent invariablement inefficientes (en excluant les situations de sur-emploi). Finalement, des simulations numériques montrent que l'introduction d'un salaire minimum peut être un meilleur instrument de régulation du marché du travail que l'augmentation des allocations chômage.

Summary

Summary

Using a simple matching model with differentiated skills, we study the effect of a minimum wage on mismatch. Introducing a minimum wage appears to improve the assignment of jobs to workers by making “bad” matches impossible. Three main results are established. First, a minimum wage increase may improve the efficiency of the labour market. Next, as soon as the minimum wage is binding (some workers do earn this minimum), unemployment benefits loose their effect on productivity, becoming invariably inefficient then. In the end, numerical simulations show that introducing a minimum wage might be more efficient than increasing unemployment benefits.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2008 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

**

Les auteurs remercient Antoine d'Autume, Pieter Gautier, André Zylberberg et le rapporteur anonyme pour leurs remarques et suggestions, mais restent seuls responsables des éventuelles erreurs et insuffisances.

References

Bibliographie

Acemoglu, D. et Shimer, R. (2000). “Productivity gains from unemployment insurance,” European Economic Review, vol. 44, pp. 11951224.Google Scholar
Aghion, P. et Howitt, P. (1992). “A model of growth through creative destruction”, Econometrica, vol. 60, pp. 323351.Google Scholar
Albrecht, J. Gautier, P. et Vroman, S. (2003). “Matching with multiple applications”, Economics Letters, vol. 78, n°1, pp. 6770.Google Scholar
Amine, S. Gavrel, F. et Lebon, I. (2007). “Jobs specialization vs unemployment: More on the productivity effect of unemployment benefits”, Spanish Economic Review, vol. 9, pp. 177191.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. et Diamond, P. (1989). “The Beveridge curve”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1, pp. 176.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. et Fisher, S. (1989). Lectures on Macroeconomics, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Card, D. et Krueger, A. (1994). “Minimum wages and employment: a case study of the fast-food industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania”, American Economic Review, vol. 84, pp. 772793.Google Scholar
Card, D. et Krueger, A. (1995). Myth and measurement, the new economics of the minimum wage, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gavrel, F. (2001). “Differentiation of skills, firms’ recruitment strategy and unemployment benefits in an efficiency wage model”, De Economist, vol. 149, pp. 347364.Google Scholar
Gavrel, F., Lages dos Santos, P. et Lebon, I. (2002). β = η is not enough: Reexamining the efficiency of the labour market in a matching model with differentiation of skills, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Gavrel, F. et Lebon, I. (2004). Providing Pissarides’ stochastic job matching model with microeconomic foundations. A reconsideration of Mari-mon and Zilibotti (1999) circle model, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Hall, R. (1977). “An aspect of the economic role of unemployment”, in: Harcourt, G. (ed), The Microeconomic Foundations of Macroeconomics, Maclillan.Google Scholar
Hosios, D. (1990). “On the efficiency of matching and related models of search and unemployment”, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 55, pp. 279298.Google Scholar
Marimon, R. at Zilibotti, F. (1999). “Unemployment VS. mismatch of talents: Reconsidering unemployment benefits”, Economic Journal, vol. 109, pp. 266291.Google Scholar
Me Kenna, C. (1985). Uncertainty and the labour market, Harvester Press.Google Scholar
Petrongolo, B. et Pissarides, C. (2001). “Looking into the black box : A survey of the matching function”, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 39, pp. 390431.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. (1979). “Job matchings with state employment agencies and random search”, Economic Journal, vol. 89, pp. 818833.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. (1984). “Efficient job rejection”, Economic Journal, vol. 94, pp. 97108.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. (2000). Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2e ed, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Rebitzer, J. et Taylor, L. (1995). “The consequences of minimum wage laws: some new theoretical ideas”, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 56, pp. 245255.Google Scholar
Salop, S. (1979). “Monopolistic competition with outside goods”, Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 10, pp. 141156.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. (1946). “The economics of minimum wage legislation”, American Economic Review, vol. 36, pp. 358365.Google Scholar