Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T12:06:27.051Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Une analyse économique de la sécession

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Grégoire Rota Graziosi*
Affiliation:
Faculté de Droit et Sciences Economiques, Université de Franche-Comté, LIBRE**
Get access

Résumé

Cet article propose une analyse économique de la sécession. Il s’inspire des travaux d’Alesina et Spolaore (1997), de Berkowitz (1997) et de Bolton et Roland (1997). Le raisonnement mené au niveau des Etats est largement transférable aux collectivités locales (régions, villes,…). Le recours à une représentation spatiale de la population nous permet d’appréhender l’hétérogénéité des préférences individuelles en matière de bien public. Le pays est supposé divisé en deux régions. La décision de sécession résulte d’un arbitrage individuel entre pression fiscale et localisation du bien public local, cet arbitrage évoluant selon la taille et le découpage régional du pays. En l’absence de disparités de revenus, nous montrons que le centre, la plus grande des deux régions, est davantage enclin à l’indépendance. Une approche normative, en terme de surplus, conclut notre analyse en appréciant l’efficacité économique du processus démocratique. Il apparaît alors que toute sécession unilatérale réduit le bien-être des deux régions.

Summary

Summary

The purpose of this article is to provide an economic analysis of secession. It can be viewed as an immediate successor of the works of Alesina and Spolaore (1997), Berkowitz (1997) and Bolton and Roland (1997). We use a spatial representation of the population to study the heterogeneity of individual’s preference in public goods. In a two-region country, the size has two antagonist effects on individual utility. On one hand, as the country grows, the individual fiscal pressure goes down. And on the other hand, more and more people feel frustrated by the production of public good in an unique place, the capital. Without revenu disparities, we show the center prefers the secession. A normative view ends this analysis. We conclude that unilateral secession reduces the two-region welfare.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2001 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

Je tiens particulièrement à remercier Bertrand Crettez ainsi que les deux rapporteurs anonymes de la revue pour leurs précieux conseils sur les versions précédentes. Mes remerciements s’adressent également à Jean-Michel Courtault et à François Maréchal. Je reste seul responsable des erreurs ou omissions qui peuvent encore subsister.

**

Laboratoire Interdisciplinaire Bisontin de Recherches Économiques 45 D, Avenue de l’Observatoire, 25030 Besançon, rota@francemail.com

References

Alesina, A. et Spolaore, E., (1997), “On the number and size of nation”, The Quaterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), pp. 10271056.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., Perotti, P. et Spolaore, E., (1995), “Together separately? Issues on the costs and benefits of political and fiscal unions”, European Economic Review, Papers and Procedings, 39 (34), pp. 751758.Google Scholar
Berkowitz, D., (1997), “Regional income and secession: Center-periphery relations in emerging market economies”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 27(1), pp. 1745.Google Scholar
Black, D., (1948), “On the rationale of group decision-making”, Journal of Political Economy, in Jackson, P. M. (ed), The Foundations of Public Finance, 1996, Elgar Reference Collection, International Library of Critical Writings in Economics, 71, pp. 8091.Google Scholar
Bolton, P., Roland, G. et Spolaore, E., (1996), “Economic theories of the break-up and integration of nations”, European Economic Review, 40(35), pp. 697705.Google Scholar
Bolton, P. et Roland, G., (1997), “The break-up of nations: a political economy analysis”, The Quaterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), pp. 1057–90.Google Scholar
Boniface, P., (2000), «La prolifération étatique», La Revue Internationale et Stratégique, 37, pp. 5964.Google Scholar
Bookman, M.Z., (1993), The economics of secession, Londres, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bordignon, M. et Brusco, S., (1999), “Optimal secession rules”, Document de travail (http://www.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/Economics/wooders/bb.pdf).Google Scholar
Buchanan, A., (1991), Secession. The morality of political divorce from Fort Sumter to Lithuania and Quebec, Boulder, Westview Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M., (1997), Post-socialist political economy, Selected Essays, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. et Faith, R. L., (1987), “Secession and the limits of taxation: towards a theory of internal exit”, American Economic Review, 77(5), pp. 10231031.Google Scholar
Casella, A. et Feinstein, J.S., (1999), “Public goods in trade:on the formation of markets and political jurisdiction”, Document de travail (http://www.columbia.edu).Google Scholar
Casella, A., (1992), “On markets and clubs: economic and political integration of regions with unequal productivity”, American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings, Mai, 82(2), pp. 115121.Google Scholar
Dieckhoff, A., (2000), La nation dans tous ses États, les identités nationales en mouvement, France, Flammarion.Google Scholar
Dion, S., 1996, “The reemergence of secessionism: lessons from Quebec”, in Breton, A. Galeotti, G. Salmon, P. et Wintrobe, R. (éds), Nationalism and rationalism, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp. 116142.Google Scholar
Drèze, J., (1993), “Regions of Europe: A feasible Status, to be discussed”, Economic Policy, 8(17), pp. 265287.Google Scholar
Faini, R., Galli, G. Gennari, P. et Rossi, F., 1997, “An empirical puzzle: falling migration and growing unemployment differentials among Italian regions”, European Economic Review, 41 (35), pp. 571579.Google Scholar
Feinstein, J. S., (1992), “Public-good provision and political stability in Europe”, American Economic Review, 82(2), pp. 323329.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, F., (1992), The end of History and the last man, New-York, The free Press, traduction (1996), La fin de l’Histoire et le dernier Homme, France, Champs Flammarion.Google Scholar
Gellner, A., (1989), Nations and nationalismes, Paris, Payot.Google Scholar
Goyal, S. et Staal, K., (1999), “The political economy of regionalism”, Document de travail, Econometric Institute Report 9957/A.Google Scholar
Hetcher, M., (1992), “The dynamics of secession”, Acta Sociologica, 35, pp. 267283.Google Scholar
Hobsbawm, E., (1990), Nations and nationalim since 1780. Programme, myth, reality. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, traduction, (1992), Nations et Nationalisme depuis 1780, Paris, Gallimard.Google Scholar
Hochman, O., Pines, D. et Thisse, J.-F., (1995), “On the optimal structure of local governments”, American Economic Review, 85(5), pp. 12241240.Google Scholar
Musil, J., (1992), “Czechoslovakia in the middle of transition”, Daedalus, 121, pp. 175195.Google Scholar
Riker, W. H. et Lemco, J., (1987), “The relation between structure and stability in federal governments”, in Riker, W. H. (éd), The development of American federalism, Boston, Academic Publishers Kluwer.Google Scholar
Tiebout, C.M., (1956), “A pure theory of local public economics”, Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), pp. 416–24.Google Scholar
Ulen, T., (1998), “Secession” in Newman, P. (éd), The new palgrave dictionary of economics and the law, New York, Stockton Press, pp. 401405.Google Scholar
Yarbrough, B. et Yarbrough, R., (1998), “Unification and secession: group size and ‘escape from lock-in’”, KYKLOS, 51(2), pp. 171195.Google Scholar
Young, R., (1998), “Games of secession” in Newman, P. (éd), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, New York, Stockton Press, pp. 183187.Google Scholar