Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T15:06:41.407Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HOW WELL WERE CREDITORS’ RIGHTS PROTECTED IN EARLY MODERN SPAIN? THE CASE OF THE PUBLIC MORTGAGE REGISTRY IN MALAGA

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 May 2020

José Luis Peña-Mir*
Affiliation:
Universitat de Barcelonaa
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

New Institutional Economics treats early modern Spain as an example of a state whose political and contracting institutions hindered economic growth. However, the assumption that Spanish political institutions were predatory in this respect has been called into question. This paper challenges the idea that Spain was unable to develop sufficiently good contracting institutions, of which we know relatively little. Using data from Malaga's notarial credit market, I show that legal institutions facilitated contractual compliance in private financial transactions. Specifically, public mortgage registries, which had improved the registration of properties used as collateral since their creation in 1768, favoured the subscription of larger contracts. Furthermore, results suggest that registries could have contributed to the development of a more impersonal credit market.

Resumen

RESUMEN

La Nueva Economía Institucional ha considerado a la España del Antiguo Régimen como ejemplo de Estado cuyas instituciones políticas y contractuales lastraron el crecimiento económico. El carácter depredador de las instituciones políticas en España durante el Antiguo Régimen ha sido cuestionado, si bien la supuesta debilidad de las instituciones contractuales no ha recibido el mismo grado de atención. Mediante datos procedentes del mercado notarial de crédito de Málaga demuestro que el cumplimiento de las transacciones crediticias se vio facilitado por la acción de varias instituciones contractuales. Una de ellas fueron los oficios de hipotecas, creados en 1768. Los oficios contribuyeron a un mejor registro de las propiedades empleadas como garantías hipotecarias, lo que redundo en la suscripción de operaciones más elevadas. Así mismo se sugiere que los oficios pudieron contribuir a la creación de mercados crediticios más impersonalizados.

Type
Articles/Artículos
Copyright
Copyright © Instituto Figuerola, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, 2020

1. INTRODUCTION

The association between economic performance and the quality of institutions has been stressed by New Institutional Economics (hereafter NIE). According to NIE, institutions work as «the rules of the game in a society», altering individual incentives and the process of economic decision-making, which, in turn, leads to the development or stagnation of markets (North Reference North1990). Sustained economic growth results from the creation of an efficient economic organisation that protects ordinary people from both predatory rulers and the unilateral alteration of contracts (North Reference North1981).

Early modern Spain has traditionally been portrayed as the stereotype of a country that suffered economic backwardness due to its inefficient economic organisation. Spain, the argument goes, was unable to create either a political framework that limited the arbitrariness of the royal powers or an effective legal system that avoided breaches of contracts.Footnote 1 Some authors have dismissed the notion that Spanish rulers were politically unconstrained.Footnote 2 Yet research on the capacity of the state to guarantee contractual compliance between private parties is much less developed.Footnote 3

Certainly, some economists consider that the influence of formal contracting institutions on long-term economic growth is less important than the role played by those institutions that constrain government.Footnote 4 However, the impact of the legal system on the development of markets through the emergence of a low transaction cost environment has been widely recognised by many scholars.Footnote 5

Public registries—land, companies and credit registries—are among the most important contracting institutions. Well-designed public registries support impersonal exchanges by reducing transaction costs and reinforcing property rights (Arruñada Reference Arruñada2012). As for land registries, they provide creditors with information about a debtor's collateral (ex ante) and accelerate the judicial process after a default (ex post). Recently, some economic historians have tried to measure the effects of registration systems in mortgage markets during the medieval and early modern periods. Van Zanden et al. (Reference Van Zanden, Zuijderduijn and De Moor2012) and Van Bochove et al. (Reference Van Bochove, Deneweth and Zuijderduijn2015) show that the early registration of real estate and land transactions was crucial for the Low Countries' ability to create efficient credit markets earlier than other countries such as England. In addition, they claim that the success of these institutions can only be explained by their interaction with the legal system—mainly mortgage law—the diffusion of collateral and the role of financial intermediaries.

Building on this literature, this article analyses the impact of a specific public registry—the public mortgage registry—on Spanish notarial credit markets at the end of the early modern period. During this period, in the absence of modern banks, other financial actors emerged. Short-term credit was mainly provided by philanthropic institutions (pósitos, montes de piedad or montes píos) and merchants, whereas ecclesiastical institutions dominated the long-term credit market.Footnote 6 With respect to non-philanthropic loans, although these transactions could be agreed orally or through private documents, their notarisation provided a higher level of security.Footnote 7 In Spain, from 1768, this system was reinforced through the establishment of a network of public mortgage registries around the country.Footnote 8 Private parties were theoretically obliged to register those notarial contracts that included some specific assets as collateral, thereby clarifying property rights and reducing and expediting litigation.

Although public mortgage registries have been dismissed as insufficient for their purposes—due to non-observance of the law and their poor design—this article claims that this institution favoured the development of Spanish credit markets.Footnote 9 To test this hypothesis, I draw on a database of almost 2,500 short-term credit contracts (obligaciones) recorded by notaries in the city of Malaga before and after the creation of the public mortgage registry in 1768. By examining special mortgage and general mortgage contracts in Malaga in 1764 and 1784, I show that the creation of public mortgage registries had important consequences for the allocation of credit resources.Footnote 10 After 1768, special mortgage contracts started receiving much higher amounts than general mortgage contracts, whereas before the creation of public mortgage registries, both types had received similar amounts. Furthermore, this institution could have contributed to the development of more impersonal credit markets. Before the creation of the registry, some debtors were able to obtain larger loans thanks to their status, but other debtors lacked the alternatives allowing them to arrive at similar arrangements. After the creation of the registry, debtors could partially solve this problem and obtain more capital in the absence of such a signalling mechanism.

The rest of the article is organised as follows. In the following section, I describe the creation of public mortgage registries in Spain, focusing on their objectives, their problems and their fees. In section 3, I describe my sources. In section 4, I analyse the impact of public mortgage registries on Malaga's notarial credit market. Finally, section 5 presents the main conclusions.

2. PUBLIC MORTGAGE REGISTRIES IN EARLY MODERN SPAIN

In 1768, King Charles III promulgated a law that mandated the creation of public mortgage registries (oficios de hipotecas) across Spain (except in Navarre).Footnote 11 This law made it compulsory to register those new notarial contracts that incorporated a mortgage on a specific piece of land or real estate, an office or an annuity.Footnote 12 Mortgage registries were created mainly to avoid stellionatus, the fraudulent selling or mortgaging of encumbered and mortgaged properties as if they were free (Porras Arboledas Reference Porras Arboledas2004). The authorities wanted to create a network of local registries that gathered together all the information about mortgaged and encumbered properties. With this aim, a registry was created in each judicial district (partido/corregimiento). The registry was located in the town hall of the capital of the district, and the oldest town hall notary in the city controlled it. In addition, the high courts of justice (chancillerías and audiencias) were authorised to create new registries in other municipalities. After formalising a contract, private parties had to go to the registry where the mortgaged property was located and show a copy of the original document. The registrar would then annotate the mortgage. In the event of a default and a judicial process, this annotation would constitute proof of the property. Furthermore, unregistered mortgages did not have legal validity.Footnote 13

The creation and diffusion of mortgage registries in early modern Spain was not an easy process. In fact, prior to 1768, the Habsburg and Bourbon dynasties had both tried unsuccessfully to create similar institutions, initially for annuity contracts, and later for all the contracts that included special mortgages (Table 1). The explanation for this failure is twofold. First, the ambiguity of these laws created many problems related to terms, sanctions, the organisation of the registry and procedures (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 229-233). Second, these laws were systematically broken by the courts of justice accepting non-registered contracts as proof; by private parties hiding annuity contracts in order to avoid the payment of taxes, and also because they refused to give information about their debts;Footnote 14 by notaries who feared the loss of attributions; and especially by municipalities, as control of the registries generated constant friction when the monarchy started to privatise the offices of registrars instead of retaining them in the hands of the town hall notaries, who were under the rule of the aldermen (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 229-243; Fiestas Loza Reference Fiestas Loza1998, pp. 31-56).

TABLE 1. IMPORTANT EVENTS IN MORTGAGE REGISTRATION LEGISLATION BEFORE 1768

Sources: Novísima Recopilación de las Leyes de España, Libro X, Título XVI, Leyes I-II (1805, pp. 105-106), Serna Vallejo (Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 224-262 and 270-283), and Fiestas Loza (Reference Fiestas Loza1998, pp. 31-56).

What, then, explains the relative success of the 1768 reform?Footnote 15 Certainly, this law was less ambiguous than its predecessors.Footnote 16 Nevertheless, I suggest that at least two other reasons were relevant. On the one hand, the monarchy finally accepted the transfer of all register attributions for annuities as well as for the rest of special mortgage contracts to a single public institution ruled by the oldest town hall notaries, and ultimately by the aldermen of the municipalities.Footnote 17 With this change, the political elites of the main cities not only gained control of the offices, but also prevented—or at least obstructed—the creation of a property tax. This made economic agents more willing to register their mortgages. On the other hand, since the middle of the18th century, in a context of economic recovery (Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura Reference Álvarez-Nogal and Prados De La Escosura2013), the authorities understood that accelerating the circulation of property required that buyers and creditors could easily obtain annuities and mortgage information on a property (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, p. 217). Authors such as Vizcaíno Pérez, who worked as Lawyer of the Royal Councils, remarked on the legal problems caused by the huge number of properties encumbered with annuities.Footnote 18 In meetings of creditors, annuities' unpaid interest had preference of payment over other credit modalities (Vízcaino Pérez Reference Vizcaíno Pérez1766, pp. 71-74).Footnote 19 This reduced the ability of other creditors to recover their capital, which made them particularly interested in knowing the situation of their potential debtors to avoid stellionatus. With this aim, the monarchy introduced several reforms, including the redemption of annuities or the creation of the public mortgage registries (Peset Reference Peset1982). This need was also perceived by the municipalities, and in fact, from the middle of the 18th century until the 1768 law, increasing numbers of them created mortgages registries (Appendix 1).

Nevertheless, although the creation of public mortgage registries was crucial to strengthening the property rights of owners of both land and capital in Spain, this institution still had many problems. Some courts continued to accept non-registered special mortgages as proof (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 364-365), many individuals did not register their mortgages, so the terms for doing so were extended (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, p. 279), and the organisation of the registry's book was still problematic (Villalón Barragán Reference Villalón Barragán and Congost2008, p. 242). However, probably the most important problem was that the law did not introduce any of the principles of modern mortgage law: publicity, speciality and priority (Ribalta Haro Reference Ribalta Haro, De Dios, Infante, Robledo and Torijano2007, pp. 304-342). In line with Roman legal tradition, private titling prevailed (Arruñada Reference Arruñada2012, p. 45), general mortgages were maintained (Ribalta Haro Reference Ribalta Haro, De Dios, Infante, Robledo and Torijano2007, pp. 304-342), and the reform did not alter the antiquity principle: except in the case of privileged mortgages, old mortgages always had priority over new ones regardless of whether they were general or special mortgages (Febrero 1786, p. 665).Footnote 20 These problems have led many legal historians to argue that mortgage registries were clearly insufficient to guarantee the protection of property rights.Footnote 21 According to them, legal conditions did not favour the development of credit markets until the enactment of the Spanish Mortgage Law in 1861 and a later reform in 1869 (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 436-524).Footnote 22

Before measuring the effects of mortgage registries on early modern Spanish credit markets, a last legal aspect must be analysed: the cost of registering a mortgage. Registry fees have been considered a key factor in the success or failure of public registries. If they are high, they create an entry barrier, and, consequently, the role of the registry is severely damaged (Djankov et al. Reference Djankov, La Porta, López-De-silanes and Shleifer2002). However, this position has been criticised by other authors such as Arruñada (Reference Arruñada2007), for whom this approach only takes into account the initial costs and compulsory formalities, and disregards ex post costs, such as court fees or the time needed to foreclose a mortgage, voluntary but common formalities and the quality of the information provided by the institution.

I have calculated the amount of notarial and registration fees for several mortgage contracts worth between 100 and 50,000 reales de vellón (hereafter r.v.).Footnote 23 These prices are calculated for a two-page mortgage obligation contract, the commonest credit contract in Malaga at the time (Table 2). Although notarial fees were high for small contracts, registry fees were always low, including those of small contracts.Footnote 24 I have also compared the costs of the Spanish public mortgage registries with the costs of similar institutions in England (deed registries) and in the Low Countries (real estate transaction registries) in the 18th century.Footnote 25 I use the number of daily wages of an unskilled urban labourer as a reference: data for England and the Low Countries are from Van Bochove et al. (Reference Van Bochove, Deneweth and Zuijderduijn2015), and I have included data on the wages of unskilled urban labourers (peones) in Madrid and unskilled rural labourers (jornaleros) in Malaga during the same period (Table 3).Footnote 26 This shows that the costs, in terms of daily wages, of registration in Spain were quite similar to real tariffs in Dutch municipalities—especially for reduced deeds—and were much cheaper than in England.

TABLE 2. LEGAL COSTS AND TAXES ASSOCIATED WITH A TWO-PAGE MORTGAGE OBLIGATION CONTRACT

*Note: 1 real de vellón = 34 maravedís.

Sources: Febrero (1783, p. 410), Martínez Salazar (1789, p. 285), Novísima Recopilación de las Leyes de España, Libro X, Título XVI, Ley III, and Título XXIV, Ley X (1805, pp. 108 and 158, respectively), and Moranchel Pocaterra (Reference Moranchel Pocaterra and Sánchez-Arcilla Bernal (PI)2012, p. 737).

TABLE 3. REGISTRATION COSTS IN DIFFERENT EUROPEAN MUNICIPALITIES IN THE 18TH CENTURY. EQUIVALENT VALUE: NUMBER OF DAYS' WAGES OF AN UNSKILLED WORKER

*Note: the Spanish registries did not use the number of words to establish fees, but the number of pages. As each page included approximately 500 words, I have used this as a reference.

Sources: for Spanish municipalities, author's elaboration based on Novísima Recopilación de las Leyes de España, Libro X, Título XVI, Ley III (1805, p. 108), Villar García (Reference Villar García1982, p. 152), Pinto Crespo and Madrazo Madrazo (Reference Pinto Crespo and Madrazo Madrazo1995, p. 203), and Moranchel Pocaterra (Reference Moranchel Pocaterra and Sánchez-Arcilla Bernal (PI)2012, p. 737); for Dutch and English municipalities, see Van Bochove et al. (Reference Van Bochove, Deneweth and Zuijderduijn2015, pp. 16 and 26, respectively).

Two caveats must be made here, however. First, notaries might have not complied with the law, charging higher tariffs to their customers. Second, registration required additional costs that are difficult to estimate. Before accepting a property as a guarantee, the lender probably asked the notary to examine the debtor's property titles. Although the 1782 official fees fixed a fee for that work (Martínez Salazar 1789, p. 285), it is possible that some lenders demanded additional work from the notaries, especially in the earlier stages of the registries, in return for higher and non-regulated payments.

3. ANALYSIS OF THE DATABASE

To check whether or not the 1768 reform improved the quality of the legal framework, it is necessary to measure its impact on the credit market. With this aim, I have taken notarial credit data from the city of Malaga. In early modern Spain, as in other contemporary countries, notaries had important functions. They drew up contracts and other legal documents that could be enforced by courts, provided legal advice and recognised documents. They developed an important role in credit markets, certifying loan contracts.Footnote 27 In some countries, such as France, notaries even worked as financial intermediaries, providing information to help their clients mitigate the effects of information asymmetries (Hoffman et al. Reference Hoffman, Postel-Vinay and Rosenthal2000). Although the number of notarised loans was probably lower than those that were agreed in the informal market, the notary's participation was essential for larger contracts and transactions with foreigners and non-relatives (Dermineur Reference Dermineur2019).Footnote 28

My selection of the city of Malaga as an example is mainly explained by the important role that credit played in its economy. At the end of the 18th century, the city and its surrounding area were among the main Spanish producers of several agricultural commodities, such as wine, raisins, almonds, figs, lemons and oranges. Most of this production was later exported to the markets of northern Europe and former Spanish domains (Fisher Reference Fisher1981; Nadal Reference Nadal2003, p. 34; García Fernández Reference García Fernández2006). Commercial dynamism favoured an increase in population and the accumulation of capital in the city, helping to make Malaga one of the first industrialised areas of Spain during the 19th century (Morilla Reference Morilla1978).Footnote 29 This agro-export pattern was sustained by the city's trading houses and merchants who bought the commodities produced by the farmers and financed them periodically, receiving agricultural commodities in return. As a consequence of this situation, the city's notaries drew up a huge number of agricultural credit contracts (Peña-Mir Reference Peña-Mir2016). The primacy of small properties in this area may also have determined the relevance of credit transactions (Bernal Reference Bernal1981, p. 283; Gámez Amián Reference Gámez Amián and Morilla1995, p. 152). On the one hand, the small size of the plots made it difficult for the owners to accumulate capital or to exploit economies of scale, so they needed periodic loans in order to survive. On the other hand, as many farmers had land that could be offered as collateral, creditors had a greater incentive to lend them money.

I use notarial records for the years 1764 and 1784, that is, before and after the creation of public mortgage registries in 1768. These were years of peace and economic recovery after the Spanish participation in the Seven Years' War (1762-1763) and the American Revolutionary War (1779-1783). I have recorded two similar samples of obligation contracts (obligaciones) signed in Malaga in 1764 (1,307 contracts) and 1784 (1,181 contracts).Footnote 30

Obligations were contracts that «recorded a generic agreement in which a person recognized the mandatory nature of paying a debt or carrying out a future work» (Carvajal Reference Carvajal, Coffman, Lorandini and Lorenzini2018, pp. 216-217). They were used mainly as short-term loans: 82.5 per cent of obligation contracts drawn up in Malaga in 1784 had a duration of 1 year or less, the average lifetime being 10.3 months. Here, they were used mostly to finance agricultural activities, but they also served other purposes such as the recognition of debts, credit sales and payment of urgent expenses.Footnote 31

Two main reasons explain the selection of obligations—short-term credit—instead of annuities (censos consignativos and censos reservativos)—long-term credit—and other credit modalities.Footnote 32 First and foremost, in Castile, annuities were always supported by special mortgages, whereas obligations were not always supported by specific assets. As I want to measure the impact of special mortgages on credit conditions before and after the 1768 reform, I need to compare general mortgage and special mortgage contracts of the same kind. Second, the number of obligation contracts is much higher. For example, obligations constituted 22.8 per cent of the notarial deeds written in Malaga in 1784, whereas annuities accounted for only 1.4 per cent (Table 4). This is not a particularity of Malaga: from the mid-18th century, obligations replaced annuities as the main credit contract in many areas of Spain including Murcia (Pérez Picazo Reference Pérez Picazo1987), León (Rubio Reference Rubio1989), Alicante (Cuevas Reference Cuevas1999), Madrid (Sola Reference Sola and Torres Sánchez2000) or Almería (Díaz López Reference Díaz López2001), and the same process also occurred in other countries, such as France (Hoffman et al. Reference Hoffman, Postel-Vinay and Rosenthal2019, pp. 62-66). Of course even in these areas obligations would only appear more frequent in terms of flow. Because annuities had much longer lifetimes and the loaned amounts were usually larger, they were superior in terms of stock until well into the 19th century (Milhaud Reference Milhaud2018, pp. 20-23).Footnote 33

TABLE 4. NOTARIAL RECORDS DRAWN UP BY NOTARIES OF MALAGA IN 1784

*Note: this category includes marriage and alimony obligations, concession and tax farming contracts, recognitions of tax and ecclesiastical debts and smugglers' pardons.

Source: see footnote No. 30.

Ideally, I would like to verify whether special mortgage contracts were effectively registered. However, the mortgage registry books for the judicial district of Malaga were destroyed during the Spanish Civil War (1936-1939) (Cabrillana Reference Cabrillana1984, p.84). Nonetheless there is evidence that a public mortgage registry was indeed created. On 2 December 1774, Lorenzo Ramírez, the oldest town hall notary in the city, paid a bail bond to rule the registry in the city. He mortgaged his office, valued at 16,500 r.v. and three houses valued at 30,500 r.v. This is a very large amount, taking into account the fact that the Council of Castile had only requested the mortgage of the office and additional assets valued at 11,000 r.v. (Archivo Histórico Municipal de Málaga, caja 343, expediente 2). There is also evidence that the information in the registry was used by tribunals to solve litigation. For example, in 1784, in a court case between Manuel Gordon and Alonso García, Gregorio Martínez de la Ribera, the oldest town hall notary and the person responsible for the mortgage registry, was summoned to provide evidence about the property García had included as a special mortgage in the contract that the two parties had signed 1 year earlier (AHPM, libro 3136, pp. 214r-217v). Finally, in 1784, all those contracts that incorporated a mortgage on lands, real estate, offices or annuities included a clause that forced the contracting parties to go to the registry and register the mortgage.

4. IMPACT OF PUBLIC MORTGAGE REGISTRIES ON NOTARIAL CREDIT MARKETS

In order to evaluate the effects of public mortgage registries on Malaga's notarial credit market, I compare obligation contracts that secured the capital with all present and future assets of the debtor (general mortgages) and contracts that added specific property as collateral (special mortgages) in 1764 and 1784. Before 1768 neither general nor special mortgage contracts written in the city of Malaga were recorded in a mortgage registry.Footnote 34 As a result of the 1768 law, a public mortgage registry was created in the city, and it became compulsory to register contracts with special mortgages on certain assets (lands, real state, offices and annuities). If the registry enhanced the legal protection of creditors' property rights, I should observe improved conditions for debtors in special mortgage contracts after the creation of the registry but not earlier. In other words, contracts with special mortgages should have similar conditions to contracts with general mortgages in 1764, but they should have significantly better conditions in 1784.

To assess whether public mortgage registries had an impact on contracts, I estimate the following model, using ordinary least squares (OLS):

$$\eqalign{{\rm CAPITA}{\rm L}_i = & \,\alpha + \beta _1\,{\rm Yea}{\rm r}_i + \beta _2\,{\rm Mortgag}{\rm e}_i + \beta _ 3\,{\rm Yea}{\rm r}_i\,\times \,{\rm Mortgag}{\rm e}_i \cr & + \beta _ 4\,{\rm Statu}{\rm s}_i + {\epsilon }_i} $$

CAPITALi denotes the size of the contract in r.v. I have removed contracts that did not mention any amount and I have adjusted contracts written in 1784 for the inflation accumulated since 1764.Footnote 35 Why is the size of the contract chosen as the dependent variable instead of using the interest rate? It has certainly been suggested that interest rates in capital markets are the best measure to evaluate the efficiency of the institutional framework (North Reference North1990, p. 69).Footnote 36 However, variations in interest rates were insignificant in credit markets characterised by a high degree of information asymmetries, for example, urban credit markets during the Middle Ages and in the early modern period. As price measurement was costly, lenders would not change interest rates but would discriminate among potential borrowers using other variables instead, such as the quality of the collateral or the reputation of the borrower (Hoffman et al. Reference Hoffman, Postel-Vinay and Rosenthal2000, p. 300; Van Zanden et al. Reference Van Zanden, Zuijderduijn and De Moor2012, p. 19). This point is crucial for early modern Spain, where obligation contracts rarely included interest rates.Footnote 37 Most contracts stated that the amount was being provided «at the mercy of the lender». As has been suggested, lenders may have included the interest in the amount supposedly given by the creditor to avoid the usury laws (Tello Reference Tello1994, p. 14; Zegarra Reference Zegarra2017b, p. 81).Footnote 38 For this reason, I estimate the impact of special mortgages by looking at changes in loaned amounts.

Yeari is a dummy variable that takes value 1 if the contract is from 1784, and equals zero otherwise, to account for temporal trends. Mortgagei is a dummy variable that takes value 1 if the contract includes a special mortgage and equals zero otherwise. Contracts rarely mentioned the value of the mortgaged assets—which does not mean that lenders had no knowledge of it—so the effect of special mortgages on capital is measured in accordance with whether or not this guarantee was present. I have removed contracts that included non-registrable collateral according to the 1768 law (cattle, harvest, tools, devices, boats and cargoes). Thus, the regression includes only general mortgage contracts and registrable special mortgage contracts. It should be noted, however, that general mortgage and special mortgage clauses were complementary: contracts could include both clauses, only one or neither of them. However, in early modern Spain, it became increasingly common for all notarised contracts to include general mortgages, so negotiations revolved around the inclusion of an additional special mortgage over a specific property (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, p. 167).Footnote 39 The main advantage of special mortgages was that they linked contracts to specific assets. This link was maintained until repayment. Thus, a debtor could sell the properties used as special mortgages, but, in case of default, the creditor had stronger rights over those properties than the new owner. In contrast, if the contract was supported with a general mortgage only, the properties of the debtor could be sold without that lien and the creditor did not have any rights over them (Sigüenza 1767, pp. 40-41; Diario de México 1808, pp. 126-127 and 133-136). All the contracts in my database included a general mortgage, but just over half of them added a special mortgage. The percentage of contracts supported by special mortgages differs widely in these two years: 84.1 per cent in 1764 and 23.9 per cent in 1784. In 1764, the majority of contracts included this clause, while in 1784, its presence appears to be correlated with the amount loaned: the larger the capital, the higher the chance of a contract including a special mortgage (Table 5).

TABLE 5. PERCENTAGE OF CONTRACTS AND AMOUNTS SUPPORTED WITH SPECIAL MORTGAGES IN 1764 AND 1784

*Note: this range only includes two contracts in 1764 and three contracts in 1784.

**Note: this range does not include any contract in 1764 and only two contracts in 1784.

Source: see footnote No. 30.

Yeari × Mortgagei is an interaction variable that appears only when the year is 1784 and a special mortgage is included, in order to measure the incidence of special mortgages in the presence of a public mortgage registry. If my hypothesis is correct, neither the year nor the inclusion of a special mortgage should be significant by themselves. It is only their interaction that should be statistically significant, as it is only after the creation of a public mortgage registry that special mortgages should have an effect on amounts loaned.

Statusi is a dummy variable that takes value 1 if the contract includes the status of the debtor and equals zero otherwise. As noted above, Hoffman et al. (Reference Hoffman, Postel-Vinay and Rosenthal2000) and Van Zanden et al. (Reference Van Zanden, Zuijderduijn and De Moor2012) consider reputation to be—along with collateral—the main variable used by lenders to discriminate between potential debtors. The reputation of debtors cannot be established from contracts directly, but its impact can be approached by looking at whether the status of the borrower was mentioned or not. Only 5.26 per cent of the contracts in my database included such a mention.Footnote 40 This could be motivated by the need of some groups, such as the military or the Church, to confirm or renounce their corporate privileges. Alternatively, debtors might have wanted to emphasise their material capacity to repay the loan, in which case mentioning their status could serve as a signalling mechanism. The majority of debtors who mentioned their status were of high or medium social rank and had regular rents from lands, real estate, annuities or tithes (priests, ecclesiastical institutions and aldermen), high public salaries (army and royal officers) or large trading profits (merchants and trading houses). Additionally, many of them belonged to organisations and corporations that could support them in case of default (the army, guilds, professional associations, etc.). Having the means to repay a loan is obviously not the same as having the intention to do so, but there was an indisputable element of prestige in both cases. Therefore, I expect status to have a significant effect on the amount of the contract. Finally, epsilon is the error term.

Table 6 shows the main results. As I expected, the year variable and the special mortgage variable are not significant by themselves. However, the interaction term that combines both variables has a significant impact on the size of capital. This suggests that the mere introduction of a special mortgage did not have noticeable effects over loaned amounts. It was only when the effectiveness of this clause became guaranteed by a well-performing registry that debtors received larger amounts. Thus, special mortgage contracts drawn up after the creation of the public mortgage registries received, on average, around 3,000 r.v. more than general mortgage contracts (drawn up in 1764 or 1784) and special mortgage contracts drawn up before 1768. In 1784, contracts with special mortgages on registrable assets were more than twice the size of contracts with a general mortgage only. In 1764, in contrast, there were no significant differences in the amounts loaned through different type of contract (see Appendix 2).Footnote 41 This is consistent with the hypothesis that the reform of 1768 had a positive impact on the allocation of credit resources.

TABLE 6. OLS REGRESSION RESULTS: IMPACT OF THE MORTGAGE REGIME AND THE STATUS OF THE BORROWER ON THE CAPITAL

t-statistics in parentheses.

Significance levels: *P < 0.1, **P < 0.05, ***P < 0.01.

Source: see footnote No. 30.

Before 1768, the absence of public mortgage registries made it difficult to determine whether the collateral had already been mortgaged or not. Consequently, although creditors demanded the introduction of this clause as a preventive mechanism, it had no impact on loaned amounts. After 1768, new special mortgages began to be registered and trust in their effectiveness increased. This new institution helped clarify the seniority of lenders, improving the functioning of the market. The creation of a public mortgage registry did not increase the number of contracts with special mortgages in the short term, but rather the opposite, as evidenced by the fact that they decreased from 84.1 per cent of all contracts in 1764 to 23.9 per cent in 1784.Footnote 42 However, public mortgage registries ensured a better use of special mortgages. Debtors who wanted large amounts were required to include them, whereas general mortgages were enough for those who borrowed smaller amounts. Probably one of the main consequences of the creation of the public mortgage registry in the short term was a major segmentation of the notarial credit market. A huge number of debtors would become indebted through several small- and medium-value general mortgage contracts. A small percentage would continue using special mortgage contracts, but in smaller numbers and for larger amounts.Footnote 43 These results suggest that, contrary to traditional historiography, public mortgage registries helped to improve the protection of property rights in early modern Spain.

Finally, the status dummy has a large positive effect on the capital of the contract. Contracts that mentioned the status of the borrower were 6,300 r.v. larger than those that did not. Since this variable includes both 1764 and 1784 contracts, it shows that high- and medium-ranked members of the community could rely on their status to obtain larger amounts during the entire period.Footnote 44 This emphasises the importance that these types of mechanisms played in the absence of more sophisticated institutions, such as registries. It also suggests that the creation of the public mortgage registry helped to encourage more impersonal financial transactions. Once the debtors were able to strengthen their position as property owners, they could sustain their credit relationships on the basis of the quality of their collateral, becoming less dependent on their status. This would be especially helpful for low-status debtors. In this regard, registries were surely not enough to create a purely impersonal credit market, but they were probably a step forward in this direction. Notwithstanding the above, the number of observations is low and the statistical effect is not highly significant, so further research is needed to confirm this hypothesis.

5. CONCLUSIONS

This article has examined the degree of protection given to creditors' rights in Spanish notarial credit markets at the end of the early modern period. I have focused on the role played by public mortgage registries in order to explore the extent to which formal institutions fostered a high level of contractual compliance in these markets. The creation of mortgage registries was a long and contested process that began in the 16th century and was characterised by constant breaches of the law and clashes between the monarchy and the municipalities over their control. Ultimately, in 1768, a network of accessible public registries was created in many Spanish areas. This change was favoured by better organisation of the registries, greater awareness of their importance and the fact that the monarchy renounced its control of the institution. Although these registries experienced many problems until they were replaced by public land registries in the second half of the 19th century, their creation in the late 18th century improved the allocation of credit resources.

To test this hypothesis, I have relied on a sample of almost 2,500 obligation contracts drawn up in the city of Malaga, before and after the creation of these registries. My analysis shows that, before the creation of public mortgage registries, contracts that included special mortgages on lands, real estate, offices and annuities received the same amounts as contracts that only included general mortgages—whose guarantees were theoretically weaker. After the creation of the public mortgage registries, however, contracts with special mortgages on those assets received more than twice as much as those that only included a general mortgage. Once special mortgages began to be registered regularly, they started to have real effects on credit conditions. Although initially the creation of a public mortgage registry did not increase the number of contracts with special mortgages, from that moment this clause helped debtors to obtain larger loans.

The results also suggest that public mortgage registries could have helped to create more impersonal markets. Debtors whose status was included in the contract—usually individuals of high and medium social rank who enjoyed regular incomes and/or who belonged to large organisations—received higher amounts than non-status debtors both before and after the creation of the mortgage registry. For these individuals, the creation of the registry was not so important because their social position helped them mitigate the reluctance of creditors to give them larger loans. For other debtors, however, other institutional arrangements were required, and the creation of the registry could have been one of them. Nevertheless, since the sample of observations that mention the status is small and the statistical effect is not highly significant, further research is needed in order to confirm or discard this hypothesis.

As my results refer to a single city, they must be interpreted with caution. This is especially relevant in a context of jurisdictional fragmentation characterised by a high degree of political autonomy on the part of the municipalities. Thus, the introduction and impact of public mortgage registries could have been conditioned by the economic needs of each judicial district, as well as by the degree of support for them among the elites, the notaries and the local judicial system.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

I thank the financial support provided by the Spanish Ministry of Education. I also want to thank Blanca Sánchez Alonso, the editor of Revista de Historia Económica—Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History. I am particularly indebted to my supervisors Yadira María González de Lara Mingo and Yolanda Blasco-Martel, without whose suggestions and support I would never have been able to write this paper. I have benefited from many comments by two anonymous referees as well as those of Carles Sudrià Triay, Alfonso Herranz-Loncán, María Alejandra Irigoin, Oscar Gelderblom, Germán Forero-Laverde, Pablo Fernández Cebrián, Nicolás Nogueroles Peiró and Antonio Carmona Portillo. I gratefully acknowledge comments by Anne Murphy, Tim Van Der Valk and the rest of the participants at the residential training course organised by the Economic History Society (Manchester, December 2017). Very special thanks are due to Pau Belda-i-Tortosa and Xabier García Fuente for their help and support. The usual disclaimers apply.

SOURCES AND OFFICIAL PUBLICATIONS

Archivo Histórico Municipal de Málaga: caja 343, expediente 2 (1775).

Archivo Histórico Provincial de Málaga: protocolos notariales de Málaga capital (1764), libros 2472, 2492, 2626, 2709, 2773, 2854, 2872, 2895, 2908, 2950, 2953, 2997, 3009, 3032 and 3081. Protocolos notariales de Málaga capital (1784), libros 2859, 2914, 3006, 3027, 3047, 3049, 3050, 3136, 3150, 3160, 3167, 3174, 3195, 3236, 3256, 3269, 3306, 3323, 3331, 3338, 3356, 3365, 3383, 3390 and 3392. Protocolos notariales de Málaga capital (1808), libro 3639.

Catalogues: Archivo de la Corona de Aragón, Archivo del Reino de Galicia, Archivo del Reino de Mallorca, Archivo del Reino de Valencia, Archivo Histórico de Mahón, Archivo Histórico de Protocolos de Madrid, Archivo Histórico Nacional, Archivo Histórico Universitario de Santiago de Compostela, Archivo Municipal de Écija, Archivo Real y General de Navarra, and Archivos Históricos Provinciales (44 Spanish Provincial Historical Archives).

Diario de México (1808), Tomo VII (September-December, 1807). Ciudad de México: Oficina de Don Juan Bautista de Arizpe.

Ley Hipotecaria (1861). Madrid: Ministerio de Gracia y Justicia.

Los Códigos Españoles Concordados y Anotados (1851). Madrid: Imprenta de la Publicidad.

Novísima Recopilación de las Leyes de España (1805). Madrid: Imprenta de Sancha.

LEGAL HANDBOOKS

ALCARAZ Y CASTRO, I. (1762): Breve introducción del método y práctica de los cuatro juicios. Madrid: Oficina de Domingo Fernández de Arrojo.

BUSTOS RODRÍGUEZ, M (2005): Cádiz en el sistema atlántico. La ciudad, sus comerciantes y la actividad mercantil (1650-1800). Cádiz: Servicio de Publicaciones de la Universidad de Cádiz.

FEBRERO, J. (1783): Librería de escribanos e instrucción jurídica theórico práctica para principiantes part 1, vol 3. 3 edn. Madrid: Imprenta de Don Pedro Marín.

FEBRERO, J. (1786): Librería de escribanos e instrucción jurídica theórico práctica para principiantes part 2, vol 3. Madrid: Imprenta de Don Pedro Marín.

MARTÍNEZ SALAZAR, A. (1789): Práctica de substanciar pleitos executivos, y ordinarios, conforme al estilo de las chancillerías, audiencias y demás tribunales del Reyno. 4 edn. Madrid: Librería de Hurtado.

SIGÜENZA, P. (1767): Tratado de cláusulas instrumentales. Madrid: Imprenta y librería de Don Antonio Mayoral.

APPENDIX 1

LIST OF REGISTRIES CREATED IN SPAIN BEFORE 1768*

APPENDIX 2

VARIATIONS OF AVERAGE CONTRACTS ACCORDING TO TYPE OF MORTGAGE IN 1764 and 1784 (GENERAL MORTGAGE = 100)

Footnotes

a

Department of Economic History, Institutions, Politics and World Economy, Barcelona, Spain. jlpenamir@ub.edu

1 See, for example, North and Thomas (Reference North and Thomas1973), North (Reference North1981) and Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2005).

2 Some authors consider jurisdictional fragmentation, rather than predatory rule, to be the main institutional barrier to modern economic growth in Spain. See Yun (Reference Yun1998) and Grafe (Reference Grafe2012). For a general approach to jurisdictional fragmentation in Europe, see Elliott (Reference Elliott1992) and Epstein (Reference Epstein2000).

3 On the legal and judicial changes that led to the emergence of credit markets in Castile in the transition between the medieval and early modern periods, see Carvajal (Reference Carvajal2013). On the incidence of the law on commercial practices in Castile in the 17th century, see Cárceles de Gea (Reference Cárceles De Gea2006). On the functioning of the Castilian judiciary between 1500 and 1700, see Kagan (Reference Kagan1981). On the role played by the courts of the Casa de Contratación, see Fernández de Castro (Reference Fernández de Castro2015). On the functions performed by the Mesta, see Drelichman (Reference Drelichman2009). On the relevance of the merchant guilds of Burgos and Bilbao, see González Arce (Reference González Arce2010) and Lamikiz (Reference Lamikiz, Angulo Morales and Aragón Ruano2016), respectively. On the role of notaries, see Extremera Extremera (Reference Extremera Extremera2009).

4 See Acemoglu and Johnson (Reference Acemoglu and Johnson2005). For a critique, see Greif (Reference Greif, Greif, Kiesling and Nye2015).

5 The implications of legal origins over financial development, contract enforcement and organisational forms have been stressed by La Porta et al. (Reference La Porta, López-De-silanes, Shleifer and Vishny1998), Spamann (Reference Spamann2010), Musacchio and Turner (Reference Musacchio and Turner2013) and Lamoreaux (Reference Lamoreaux2016); the importance of contract design to solve information asymmetries by Hart (Reference Hart1995); the interaction of formal and informal institutions by Greif et al. (Reference Greif, Milgrom and Weingast1994); the need to create institutions which provide useful information about contractual partners by De Soto (Reference De Soto2000), Djankov et al. (Reference Djankov, La Porta, López-De-silanes and Shleifer2002) and Arruñada (Reference Arruñada2007, Reference Arruñada2012).

6 The first private banking network in Spain was not created until the middle of the 19th century (Sudrià and Blasco Martel Reference Sudrià and Blasco-Martel2016). Two syntheses on credit markets in early modern Spain are provided by Ruíz Martín (Reference Ruíz Martín1970) and Plaza Prieto (Reference Plaza Prieto1976). On the role of philanthropic institutions, see Anes (Reference Anes1969), Gómez Díaz and Fernández-Revuelta Pérez (Reference Gómez Díaz and Fernández-Revuelta Pérez1998) and Carbonell-Esteller (Reference Carbonell-Esteller2000). On the role of ecclesiastical institutions in credit markets, see Milhaud (Reference Milhaud2019).

7 Notarised debt instruments had legal advantages over private debt instruments and oral agreements in both debt collection lawsuits (only one creditor) and meetings of creditors (several creditors). In debt collection lawsuits notarised contracts guaranteed automatic access to the executory process (juicio ejecutivo). This legal variant ensured the immediate seizure of the assets of the debtor in case of default and a faster trial than the usual procedure (juicio ordinario). In meetings of creditors, notarised contracts had priority of payment with respect to non-notarised contracts of the same category. Detailed expositions of the executory process prior to the Spanish Liberal Revolution are provided by Alcaraz y Castro (1762, pp. 58-92) and Martínez Salazar (1789, pp. 3-136). For a complete exposition of meetings of creditors, see Febrero (1786, pp. 623-738).

8 Some economic historians have used this source for several purposes. Congost (Reference Congost1988) analyses the evolution of land property in Girona between 1768 and 1862. Fernández de Pinedo (Reference Fernández De Pinedo, González, Maluquer and Riquer1985), Castañeda (Reference Castañeda, Nadal, Maluquer and Sudrià1991), De la Torre (Reference De La Torre1994) and Díaz López (Reference Díaz López2001) study the replacement of annuities by obligations in Biscay, Barcelona, Navarre and Almería, respectively, during the 18th and 19th centuries. Cebreiro Ares (Reference Cebreiro Ares2016) describes this source for Santiago de Compostela. Congost and García Orallo (Reference Congost and García Orallo2018) study the circulation of land in 19th century Spain. Milhaud (Reference Milhaud2018) analyses the existence of a crowding-out process in Spain at the end of the 18th century.

9 Most legal historians question the effectiveness of this institution. Some of them consider public mortgage registries incapable of protecting creditors' rights during this period (Roca Sastre Reference Roca Sastre1954; Menchén Reference Menchén1974; Serna Reference Serna Vallejo1995). Lacruz (Reference Lacruz2003) and Ribalta Haro (Reference Ribalta Haro, De Dios, Infante, Robledo and Torijano2007) also criticise them, but they recognise the difficulties involved in creating a more sophisticated institution in a period characterised by strong economic and legal limitations. Finally, authors such as Rivas Palá (Reference Rivas Palá1978) and Chico (Reference Chico1981) consider public mortgage registries a modern institution in an Ancien Régime economic context. A synthesis of arguments both for and against the role of the mortgage registries is available in Villalón Barragán (Reference Villalón Barragán and Congost2008, pp. 241-243).

10 Special mortgages were those that guaranteed the contract with a specific asset of the debtor. By contrast, general mortgages were those that guaranteed the contract with all present and future assets of the debtor, but did not specify any particular property. For a discussion of the advantages of special mortgages over general mortgages, see section 4.

11 The public mortgage registry was not established in Navarre until 1817 and it required the approval of the Navarrese estates, the cortes (De Pablo Contreras Reference De Pablo Contreras1991). Some years later, mortgage registries were also created in Spanish America and the Philippines. They had other names (anotadurías de hipotecas), as well as some differences with respect to the metropolis (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 309-313).

12 Some modifications were introduced later. For instance, in 1774, it became mandatory to register pre-1768 mortgages too (Novísima Recopilación de las Leyes de España, Libro X, Título XVI, Ley III, Footnote No. 3, 1805, p. 109). Furthermore, in Catalonia, since 1774, the registration of contracts with general mortgages was also compulsory (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 283-286).

13 Novísima Recopilación de las Leyes de España, Libro X, Título XVI, Ley III, 1805, pp. 106-109.

14 Although there was no tax on real estate transfers in early modern Castile—in Spain a real estate transfer tax was not implemented until 1829—annuity contracts had to pay a sales tax (alcabala). Regarding seigneurial rights, Castile had only an annual payment and a commission over emphyteutic property transfers (laudemio). In early modern France, for example, there were both several royal taxes (insinuation, droit de contrôle, centième denier) and multiple seigneurial rights (lods et ventes, quint et requint, relief, rachant, ensaisinement) over real estate transfers (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 23, 47, 129, 240-241 and 292).

15 Both Spanish archives and the Registros de la Propiedad of Madrid and Barcelona contain books from public mortgage registries created in the last third of the 18th century for forty-three of the fifty current Spanish provinces. This proves that—even though they were not used widely at first—a network of registries emerged rapidly across the Spanish territory. The list of Spanish archives that contain public mortgage registry books is provided in the section «Sources and Official Publications». Archive catalogues are available on their respective websites and on the Censo-Guía de Archivos de España e Iberoamérica website at censoarchivos.mcu.es. The information about the Registros de la Propiedad of Barcelona and Madrid is from López and Tatjer (Reference López and Tatjer1985) and Milhaud (Reference Milhaud2018), respectively.

16 Both the law of 1539 and that of 1713, to a lesser extent, failed to regulate many crucial aspects, such as procedures, terms and, above all, the organisation of mortgage books. This ambiguity generated uncertainty and was used by many municipalities to avoid applying the law effectively. In order to fill these gaps and to ensure compliance with the law, the Council of Castile began to collect reports from municipalities and high courts of justice from 1756 (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 275-280).

17 Some private Contadurías were maintained, but they gradually disappeared (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, p. 272).

18 For example, according to my sample, 56.0 and 69.0 per cent of the mortgage obligation contracts written in the city of Malaga in 1764 and 1784, respectively, were encumbered with public and private annuities.

19 For instance, in the meeting of creditors of the merchant Andrés del Pino (1807-1808), annuity creditors were paid in full, while lenders whose capital had been loaned through other modalities suffered partial debt relief. Archivo Histórico Provincial de Málaga (hereafter AHPM), protocolos notariales de Málaga capital, libro 3639, pp. 488r-495v.

20 Privileged mortgages were credits with priority of payment in cases of default. Some privileged mortgages were dowry credits, fixed-assets loans or debts with the Royal Treasury, the Church or landlords (Febrero, 1786, pp. 653-716).

21 See footnote No. 9.

22 This law replaced mortgage registries with land registries, and register attributions were transferred from notaries to independent registrars. General mortgages were eliminated, the number of privileged mortgages fell, and it became compulsory to register all of them. Finally, the date of inscription in the registry was the date on which the deed was presented in the registry (Ley Hipotecaria, 1861).

23 An unskilled urban labourer in Madrid earned 4 r.v. per day in the 18th century (Pinto Crespo and Madrazo Madrazo Reference Pinto Crespo and Madrazo Madrazo1995, p. 203). An unskilled rural labourer in Malaga earned between 2.5 and 3 r.v. per day in 1784 (Villar García Reference Villar García1982, p. 152).

24 I have calculated registry fees by estimating one page per operation because the registration of the mortgage rarely occupied more space.

25 For a detailed analysis of the English case, see Nogueroles Peiró (Reference Nogueroles Peiró, De Dios, Infante, Robledo and Torijano2007) and Van Bochove et al. (Reference Van Bochove, Deneweth and Zuijderduijn2015). For a detailed analysis of the Dutch case, see Van Bochove et al. (Reference Van Bochove, Deneweth and Zuijderduijn2015).

26 I have not found out the wages for unskilled urban labourers in Malaga during this period.

27 See Hoffman et al. (Reference Hoffman, Postel-Vinay and Rosenthal2000, Reference Hoffman, Postel-Vinay and Rosenthal2019) and Dermineur (Reference Dermineur2018, Reference Dermineur2019) for France; De Luca (Reference De Luca2013) and Lorenzini (Reference Lorenzini2015) for Italy; Costa et al. (Reference Costa, Rocha and Brito2014) for Portugal; Sola (Reference Sola and Torres Sánchez2000), Peña-Mir (Reference Peña-Mir2016) and Carvajal (Reference Carvajal, Coffman, Lorandini and Lorenzini2018) for Spain; Levy (Reference Levy2012) for Mexico; Zegarra (Reference Zegarra2017a, Reference Zegarra2017b) for Peru; and Wasserman (Reference Wasserman2018) for Argentina. In the Low Countries, although notaries were not so relevant, they nonetheless had an important role. See Gelderblom et al. (Reference Gelderblom, Hup, Jonker, Coffman, Lorandini and Lorenzini2018).

28 Here, I understand as informal market or informal credit those transactions that were non-certified by legal agents, such as notaries (Dermineur, Reference Dermineur2019). Nevertheless, this is not the only definition of this concept. For example, Coffman et al. (Reference Coffman, Lorandini and Lorenzini2018, p. 2) considered that «informal credit refers to transactions that are not intermediated by operators specialized in matching demand and supply, namely professionals whose specialization was other than this, like for instance notaries, scriveners, merchants and even religious institutions». Following this definition, notarial credit would not be formal, but informal.

29 According to the Census of Floridablanca, conducted between 1785 and 1789, Malaga had 51,098 inhabitants and was the seventh most populated Spanish city. Malaga population data are available on the Instituto de Estadística y Cartografía de Andalucía website at http://www.juntadeandalucia.es.

30 The 1784 sample includes all notarial records written by twenty-two of the twenty-four notaries who worked in the city that year, discarding only those books that were almost destroyed. The 1764 sample includes all notarial records written by fifteen of the twenty-four notaries. I used the information from the 1784 sample to select these fifteen notaries, choosing those with both high and low credit-recording activity. AHPM, protocolos notariales de Málaga capital. For 1764, see libros 2472, 2492, 2626, 2709, 2773, 2854, 2872, 2895, 2908, 2950, 2953, 2997, 3009, 3032 and 3081. For 1784, see libros 2859, 2914, 3006, 3027, 3047, 3049, 3050, 3136, 3150, 3160, 3167, 3174, 3195, 3236, 3256, 3269, 3306, 3323, 3331, 3338, 3356, 3365, 3383, 3390 and 3392.

31 51.1 per cent of obligation contracts drawn up by notaries of Malaga in 1784 and 30.4 per cent of the total amount were used to finance agricultural activities.

32 The other credit modalities drawn up by notaries in Malaga in 1784 were insignificant: debt transfers (9), protests (2) and repurchases (1).

33 Several reasons have been put forward to explain this: the reduction of the cap on annuities' interest from 5 to 3 per cent in the Crown of Castile in 1705 and in the Crown of Aragon in 1750 (Peset Reference Peset1982; Reference Fernández De Pinedo, González, Maluquer and RiquerFernández de Pinedo 1985); the incompatibility of annuities in the new capitalist context (Reference Fernández De Pinedo, González, Maluquer and RiquerFernández de Pinedo 1985); recurrent defaults of municipal debts financed via annuities in the first half of 18th century (Reference AndrésAndrés 1987); the strike against tithes, land rents and perpetual mortgages rents during the crises of the Ancien Régime (Robledo Reference Robledo and Yun1991; Reference TelloTello 1994); and the crowding-out effects generated by the war period initiated in 1779 (Reference MilhaudMilhaud 2018). Of course, there were other areas where annuities maintained an important role during the second half of the 18th century and even the first half of the 19th century. See Tello (Reference Tello, De Dios, Infante, Robledo and Torijano2007).

34 There is no evidence of any registry in Malaga before 1768. Furthermore, none of the special mortgage contracts written in 1764 included a clause making their registration compulsory.

35 I used data on prices for Andalusia, the Spanish region to which Malaga belongs, estimated by Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1947, p. 155).

36 For an application of this model, see Reis (Reference Reis, Esfahani, Facchini and Hewings2010).

37 Only 0.8 per cent of the obligation contracts written in 1784 included the interest rate.

38 Official laws established interest rate ceilings for credit contracts. For example, at the end of the 18th century, the legal maximum interest rate was 3 per cent for annuities and 6 per cent for obligations. These laws are included in the Libro X of the Novísima Recopilación de las Leyes de España (1805): Título XV, Leyes VIII-IX (for annuities); and Título VIII, Ley V; Título XI, Leyes XII-XIII; Título XIII, Leyes XIV, XVII-XVIII and XXI (for obligations). This regulation did not apply to all credit modalities: in sea loans, for example, contracting parties could set interest rates freely (Bustos Rodríguez 2005, pp. 425-427).

39 In meetings of creditors, mortgage contracts had preference of payment over non-mortgage contracts, so notaries included general mortgages as prevention clauses (Febrero 1786, pp. 623-738).

40 The next statuses are quoted: military (30), priests and religious institutions (24), craftsmen (23), shipmasters (18), aldermen (7), attorneys (4), merchants (4), carters (3), farmers (3), municipal officers (3), notaries (3), royal officers (3), trading houses (2), grocers (1), managers (1), mayors (1) and nobles (1).

41 Similar results are obtained by Peña-Mir (Reference Peña-Mir2016, p. 136) in his analysis of agricultural obligation contracts in Malaga between 1779 and 1794: contracts supported with a general mortgage only—87.9 per cent of the sample—received an average amount of 1,685 r.v. and contracts supported with a special mortgage—12.1 per cent of the sample—received an average amount of 4,012 r.v.

42 Data for the city of Alcoi support this hypothesis. There, the creation of the registry did not lead to an immediate proliferation of special mortgage contracts. In the 1770s, immediately after the creation of the public mortgage registry, only 7.01 per cent of the credit contracts included special mortgages. By the 1780s, this share had increased to 29.41 per cent and in the 1810s almost half of all contracts included them (45.30 per cent). After two decades of stagnation, the share of contracts that included special mortgages rose to 59.78 in 1840s and, finally, to 96.25 per cent in the 1880s (Cuevas Reference Cuevas1999, p. 197).

43 The decrease in the number of obligation contracts with special mortgages cannot be explained by an increase in the notarial fees paid for them. According to the official fees laid down in 1722, in 1764 the fee for an obligation contract with a special mortgage was 30 r.v. and 12 r.v. without it (Los Códigos Españoles Concordados y Anotados, Tomo XII, Libro II, Título VIII, Auto XIV, 1851, p. 53). According to the official fees laid down in 1782, in 1784 each «sheet of paper» in an obligation contract with a special mortgage generated a fee of 30 r.v., while that for an obligation contract without a special mortgage was also 30 r.v. (Martínez Salazar 1789, p. 285). Of course, as noted above, it is possible that, after the creation of the registry, notaries started to demand higher fees for recognising property titles. The quality of their services would be higher but too expensive for small-value contracts.

44 The same effect is present for those contracts that were supported by non-registrable assets (excluded of the OLS model): non-status contracts received, on average, 1,737 r.v., whereas those that included it received 14,912 r.v.

*Note: I have evidence for other places, but have not been able to find the date of creation: Molina, Nájera, Ciudad Rodrigo, Palencia—all of them at the end of the 16th century, San Fernando, Toledo and Carmona (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, pp. 239, 272 and 276). In Zamora and Cádiz, other registries were created (Serna Vallejo Reference Serna Vallejo1995, p. 239 and pp. 245-246).

**Note: the archive catalogue does not state that the registry was created in that year, but the first preserved document corresponds to that year.

***Note: 1541 is the year in which Seville received the second and last order to create the registry (Porras Arboledas Reference Porras Arboledas2004, p. 252).

Sources: catalogues of Archivo Histórico de Protocolos de Madrid, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Albacete, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Cáceres, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Ciudad Real, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Gipuzkoa, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Granada, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Málaga, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Pontevedra, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Salamanca, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Santa Cruz de Tenerife, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Segovia, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Toledo, Archivo Histórico Provincial de Zamora and Archivo Municipal de Écija. See also Serna Vallejo (1995, pp. 232, 246-248 and 258); Cerdeña (Reference Cerdeña2003, p. 420); Porras Arboledas (2004, p. 252).

*Note: contracts whose amount is not specified are excluded.

**Note: emphyteutic contract between the king and the Christian families who repopulated the Kingdom of Granada after the deportation of the moriscos (Spanish Muslims who were forced to convert to Christianity) to other kingdoms under the Crown of Castile in 1571. According to this contract, the king would receive an annual rent until the settler decided to redeem the charge by buying the property from the king. See Campos Daroca (Reference Campos Daroca1984-85).

Source: see footnote No. 30.

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D., and Johnson, S. (2005): «Unbundling Institutions». Journal of Political Economy 113 (5), pp. 949-995.10.1086/432166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. (2005): «The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Economic Growth». American Economic Review 95, pp. 546-579.10.1257/0002828054201305CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Álvarez-Nogal, C., and Prados De La Escosura, L. (2013): «The Rise and Fall of Spain (1270-1850)». Economic History Review 66 (1), pp. 1-37.10.1111/j.1468-0289.2012.00656.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andrés, F. (1987): Crédito y propiedad de la tierra en el País Valenciano. Valencia: Edicions Alfons el Magnànim.Google Scholar
Anes, G. (1969): Economía e Ilustración en la España del siglo XVIII. Barcelona: Ariel.Google Scholar
Arruñada, B. (2007): «Pitfalls to Avoid When Measuring the Institutional Environment: Is ‘Doing Business’ Damaging Business?». Journal of Comparative Economics 35 (4), pp. 729-747.10.1016/j.jce.2007.08.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arruñada, B. (2012): Institutional Foundations of Impersonal Exchange: The Theory and Policy of Contractual Registries. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.10.7208/chicago/9780226028354.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernal, A. M. (1981): Historia de Andalucía vol 7. Barcelona: Planeta.Google Scholar
Cabrillana, N. (1984): «El Archivo Histórico Provincial de Málaga. Los protocolos notariales y su importancia para la investigación». Ciencias y Letras. Revista del Colegio de Doctores y Licenciados 6, pp. 83-99.Google Scholar
Campos Daroca, Mª. L. (1984-85): «Sobre la renta de población del Reino de Granada». Chronica Nova 14, pp. 57-70.Google Scholar
Carbonell-Esteller, M. (2000): «Using Microcredit and Restructuring Households: Two Complementary Survival Strategies in Late Eighteenth-Century Barcelona». International Review of Social History 45, pp. 71-92.10.1017/S0020859000115299CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cárceles De Gea, B. (2006): Derecho y comercio en la Corona de Castilla en el siglo XVII. Madrid: UNED.Google Scholar
Carvajal, D. (2013): «Crédito, privado y deuda en Castilla (1480-1521)». Universidad de Valladolid, PhD dissertation.Google Scholar
Carvajal, D. (2018): «Private Credit in Spain During the Late Eighteenth and the Early Nineteenth Centuries: Institutions, Crisis and War», in Coffman, D., Lorandini, C., and Lorenzini, M. (eds), Financing in Europe. Evolution, Coexistence and Complementarity of Lending Practices from the Middle Ages to Modern Times. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 207-236.10.1007/978-3-319-58493-5_9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castañeda, L. (1991): «Sector financer i mercat de capitals al primer terç del segle XIX», in Nadal, J., Maluquer, J., and Sudrià, C. (eds), Història Econòmica de la Catalunya Contemporània vol. 2. Barcelona: Enciclopedia Catalana, pp. 339-349.Google Scholar
Cebreiro Ares, F. (2016): «El Registro de Hipotecas y sus posibilidades para la historia urbana: el caso de Santiago de Compostela 1768-1810». Communication at the III Encuentro de Jovenes Investigadores en Historia Moderna. Universidad de Valladolid.Google Scholar
Cerdeña, R. (2003): «La Contaduría de Hipotecas de Fuerteventura: referencias históricas e inventario de su fondo documental». Tebeto: Anuario del Archivo Histórico Insular de Fuerteventura 16, pp. 415-485.Google Scholar
Chico, J. M. (1981): Estudios sobre derecho hipotecario. Madrid: Marcial Pons.Google Scholar
Coffman, D., Lorandini, C., and Lorenzini, M. (eds) (2018): Financing in Europe. Evolution, Coexistence and Complementarity of Lending Practices from the Middle Ages to Modern Times. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Congost, R. (1988): «Els propietaris i els altres. Anàlisis d´unes relacions d´explotació. La regió de Girona, 1768-1862». Universitat de Girona, PhD dissertation.Google Scholar
Congost, R., and García Orallo, R. (2018): «¿Qué liberaron las medidas liberales? La circulación de la tierra en la España del siglo XIX». Historia Agraria 74, pp. 67-102.10.26882/histagrar.074e03cCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa, L. F., Rocha, M. M., and Brito, P. (2014): «Notarial Activity and Credit Demand in Lisbon During the Eighteenth-Century». Gabinete de História Económica y Social - Série Documentos de Trabalho 51.Google Scholar
Cuevas, J. (1999): «Los orígenes financieros de la industria de Alcoi (1770-1900)». Universidad de Alicante, PhD dissertation.Google Scholar
De La Torre, J. (1994): «Coyuntura económica, crédito agrícola y cambio social en Navarra, 1750-1850». Noticiario de Historia Agraria 7, pp. 109-129.Google Scholar
De Luca, G. (2013): «Informal Credit and Economic Modernization in Milan (1802-1840)». The Journal of European Economic History 42 (1), pp. 211-234.Google Scholar
De Pablo Contreras, P. (1991): «La reacción navarra ante la Ley Hipotecaria de 1861». Revista Jurídica de Navarra 11, pp. 13-34.Google Scholar
De Soto, H. (2000): The Mystery of Capital. Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Black Swan.Google Scholar
Dermineur, E. M. (2018): «Rethinking Debt: The Evolution of Private Credit Markets in Preindustrial France». Social Science History 42, pp. 317-342.10.1017/ssh.2018.5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dermineur, E. M. (2019): «Peer-to-Peer Lending in Pre-Industrial France». Financial History Review 26 (3), pp. 359-388.10.1017/S0968565019000143CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Díaz López, J. P. (2001): «Transformaciones institucionales del mercado de capitales en un medio agrícola mediterráneo: Almería (1769-1853)». Chronica Nova 28, pp. 129-157.Google Scholar
Djankov, S., La Porta, R., López-De-silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (2002): «The Regulation of Entry». Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (1), pp. 1-37.10.1162/003355302753399436CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drelichman, M. (2009): «License to Till: The Privileges of the Spanish Mesta as a Case of Second-Best Institutions». Explorations in Economic History 46, pp. 220-240.10.1016/j.eeh.2008.10.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elliott, J. H. (1992): «A Europe of Composite Monarchies». Past and Present 137, pp. 48-71.10.1093/past/137.1.48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, S. R. (2000): Freedom and Growth: The Rise of States and Markets in Europe, 1300-1750. London: Routledge.10.4324/9780203183281CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Extremera Extremera, M. A. (2009): El Notariado en la España Moderna. Los escribanos públicos de Córdoba (siglos XVI-XIX). Madrid: Calambur.Google Scholar
Fernández de Castro, A. B. (2015): «Juzgar en las Indias: la práctica de la jurisdicción de los oidores de la audiencia de la Casa de la Contratación de Sevilla (1583-1598)». European University Institute, PhD dissertation.Google Scholar
Fernández De Pinedo, E. (1985): «Del censo a la o bligación: modificaciones en el crédito rural antes de la Primera Guerra Carlista en el País Vasco», in González, M., Maluquer, J., and Riquer, B. (eds), Industrialización y nacionalismos. Análisis comparativos. Barcelona: Servicio de Publicaciones de la UAB, pp. 297-305.Google Scholar
Fiestas Loza, A. (1998): «Don José Ballesteros y el oficio de hipotecas». Revista crítica de derecho inmobiliario 644, pp. 31-56.Google Scholar
Fisher, J. R. (1981): «Imperial «Free Trade» and the Hispanic Economy, 1778-1796». Journal of Latin American Studies 13 (1), pp. 21-56.10.1017/S0022216X00006155CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gámez Amián, A. (1995): «El crédito agrario ‘oficial’ en las provincias mediterráneas andaluzas (1856-1936)», in Morilla, J. (ed.), California y el mediterráneo: estudios de la historia de dos agriculturas competidoras. Madrid: Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca, y Alimentación, pp. 149-172.Google Scholar
García Fernández, Mª. N. (2006): Comerciando con el enemigo: el tráfico mercantil anglo-español en el siglo XVIII (1700-1765). Madrid: CSIC.Google Scholar
Gelderblom, O., Hup, M., and Jonker, J. (2018): «Public Functions, Private Markets: Credit Registration by Aldermen and Notaries in the Low Countries, 1500–1800», in Coffman, D., Lorandini, C., and Lorenzini, M. (eds), Financing in Europe. Evolution, Coexistence and Complementarity of Lending Practices from the Middle Ages to Modern Times. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 163-194.10.1007/978-3-319-58493-5_7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gómez Díaz, D., and Fernández-Revuelta Pérez, L. (1998): «Complejidad organizativa y desarrollo contable de los pósitos en España, siglos XVI-XIX». Revista de Contabilidad 2 (1), pp. 85-112.Google Scholar
González Arce, D. (2010): «La Universidad de mercaderes de Burgos y el consulado castellano en Brujas durante el siglo XV». En la España Medieval 33, pp. 161-202.Google Scholar
Grafe, R. (2012): Distant Tyranny: Markets, Power, and Backwardness in Spain, 1650-1800. Princeton-Woodstock: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2015): «Coercion and Exchange: How did Markets Evolve?», in Greif, A., Kiesling, L., and Nye, J. (eds), Institutions, Innovation and Industrialization: Essays in Economic History and Development. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 71-97.10.1515/9780691210629CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A., Milgrom, P. R., and Weingast, B. R. (1994): «Coordination, Commitment and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild». Journal of Political Economy 102, pp. 745-776.10.1086/261953CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, E. J. (1947): War and Prices in Spain (1651-1800). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hart, O. D. (1995): Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford: Oxford University Press.10.1093/0198288816.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, P. T., Postel-Vinay, G., and Rosenthal, J. L. (2000): Priceless Markets: The Political Economy of Credit in Paris, 1660-1870. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hoffman, P. T., Postel-Vinay, G., and Rosenthal, J. L. (2019): Dark Matter Credit. The Development of Peer-to-Peer Lending and Banking in France. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kagan, R. (1981): Lawsuits and Litigants in Castile, 1500-1700. Chapel Hill, North Carolina: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
La Porta, R., López-De-silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1998): «Law and Finance». Journal of Political Economy 106, pp. 1113-1155.10.1086/250042CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lacruz, J. L. (2003): Elementos de Derecho Civil. Derecho Inmobiliario Registral. Madrid: Dykinson.Google Scholar
Lamikiz, X. (2016): «¿Qué tipo de capital social generaron los gremios de comerciantes? Reflexiones a partir del ejemplo del Consulado de Bilbao, 1511-1829», in Angulo Morales, A., and Aragón Ruano, A. (eds), Recuperando el norte. Empresas, capitales y proyectos atlánticos en la economía imperial hispánica. Bilbao: Servicio Editorial de la Universidad del País Vasco, pp. 103-128.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, N. (2016): «Corporate Governance and the Expansion of the Democratic Franchise: Beyond Cross-Country Regressions». Scandinavian Economic History Review 64 (2), pp. 103-121.10.1080/03585522.2016.1175376CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, J. (2012): The Making of Market. Credit, Henequen and Notaries in Yucatan, 1850-1900. University Park, PA: The Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
López, M., and Tatjer, M. (1985): Inventari dels oficis i comptadories d'hipoteques de Catalunya. Barcelona: Generalitat de Catalunya.Google Scholar
Lorenzini, M. (2015): «The Credit Markets and Notaries in Verona in the Second Half of the Seventeenth Century». Journal of European Economic History 44 (1), pp. 123-148.Google Scholar
Menchén, B. (1974): Leyes Hipotecarias y Registrales de España. Fuentes y Evolución. Madrid: Castalia.Google Scholar
Milhaud, C. (2018): «Financial Repression as a Tool for Debt Management. Evidence from Late-Eighteenth Century Spain». Working Paper hal-01767927.Google Scholar
Milhaud, C. (2019): «Interregional Flows of Capital and Information in Spain: A Case Study of the Theresian Carmelite Order». Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 37 (1), pp. 81-110.10.1017/S0212610918000174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moranchel Pocaterra, M. (2012): «La condena en costas en los procesos penales incoados ante jueces inferiores de algunas villas cercanas a la Corte (siglo XVIII)», in Sánchez-Arcilla Bernal (PI), J., El arbitrio judicial en el Antiguo Régimen. España e Indias, siglos XVI-XVIII. Madrid: Dykinson, pp. 719-748.Google Scholar
Morilla, J. (1978): Gran Capital y estancamiento económico en Andalucía: banca y ferrocarriles en Málaga en el siglo XIX. Córdoba: Instituto de Historia de Andalucía.Google Scholar
Musacchio, A., and Turner, J. D. (2013): «Does the Law and Finance Hypothesis Pass the Test of History?». Business History 55 (4), pp. 524-542.10.1080/00076791.2012.741976CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nadal, J. (2003): Atlas de la industrialización de España, 1750-2000. Barcelona: Crítica.Google Scholar
Nogueroles Peiró, N. (2007): «La implantación del registro inglés: enseñanza de una lenta conquista», in De Dios, S., Infante, J., Robledo, R., and Torijano, E. (eds), Historia de la Propiedad. Crédito y Garantía. Madrid: Fundación Registral, pp. 789-866.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1981): Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990): Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511808678CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C., and Thomas, R. P. (1973): The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511819438CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peña-Mir, J. L. (2016): «Financiación y especialización productiva: el mercado de crédito malagueño a finales del siglo XIX». Investigaciones de Historia Económica 12 (3), pp. 133-143.10.1016/j.ihe.2016.06.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pérez Picazo, M. T. (1987): «Crédito y usura en la región murciana durante el siglo XIX». Áreas. Revista Internacional de Ciencias Sociales 8, pp. 11-21.Google Scholar
Peset, M. (1982): Dos ensayos sobre la historia de la propiedad de la tierra. Madrid: Editorial Revista de Derecho Privado.Google Scholar
Pinto Crespo, V., and Madrazo Madrazo, S. (1995): Madrid, atlas histórico de la ciudad siglos IX-XIX. Madrid: Lunwerg.Google Scholar
Plaza Prieto, J. (1976): Estructura económica de España en el siglo XVIII. Madrid: Confederación Española de Cajas de Ahorro.Google Scholar
Porras Arboledas, P. A. (2004): «La documentación del derecho de propiedad y el delito de estelionato (Castilla, siglos XV-XVIII)». Cuadernos de Historia del Derecho vol. Extraordinario, pp. 249-278.Google Scholar
Reis, J. (2010): «Institutions and Economic Growth in the Atlantic Periphery: The Efficiency of the Portuguese Machinery of Justice, 1870-1910», in Esfahani, H., Facchini, G., and Hewings, G. (eds), Economic Development in Latin America. New York: Palgrave-Macmillan, pp. 73-101.Google Scholar
Ribalta Haro, J. (2007): «Una visión catalana de las instituciones de crédito hipotecario en la España de mediados del siglo XIX», in De Dios, S., Infante, J., Robledo, R., and Torijano, E. (eds), Historia de la Propiedad. Crédito y Garantía. Madrid: Fundación Registral, pp. 271-358.Google Scholar
Rivas Palá, M. (1978): «Los libros de registro de las antiguas contadurías de hipotecas». Boletín de la ANABAD 28 (1), pp. 57-83.Google Scholar
Robledo, R. (1991): «El crédito de los privilegiados durante la crisis del Antiguo Régimen», in Yun, B. (ed.), Estudios sobre capitalismo agrario, crédito e industria en Castilla (siglos XIX y XX). Salamanca: Junta de Castilla y León, pp. 237-266.Google Scholar
Roca Sastre, R. M. (1954): Derecho hipotecario. Barcelona: Bosch.Google Scholar
Rubio, L. (1989): «Deudores, rentistas y prácticas crediticias en la sociedad leonesa. El ejemplo de la sociedad de Astorga en los siglos XVII y XVIII». Revista de la Facultad de Geografía e Historia 4, pp. 551-584.Google Scholar
Ruíz Martín, F. (1970): «La banca en España hasta 1782», in El Banco de España. Una historia económica. Madrid: Banco de España, pp. 1-196.Google Scholar
Serna Vallejo, M. (1995): La propiedad inmobiliaria en el derecho hipotecario histórico español. Universidad de Cantabria, PhD dissertation.Google Scholar
Sola, J. C. (2000): «El mercado de crédito en Madrid (1750-1808)», in Torres Sánchez, R. (ed.), Capitalismo mercantil en la España del siglo XVIII. Pamplona: Ediciones Universidad de Navarra, pp. 211-246.Google Scholar
Spamann, H. (2010): «Legal Origins, Civil Procedure, and the Quality of Contract Enforcement». Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 166, pp. 149-165.10.1628/093245610790711591CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sudrià, C., and Blasco-Martel, Y. (2016): La pluralidad de emisión en España, 1844-1874. Bilbao: Fundación BBVA.Google Scholar
Tello, E. (1994): «El papel del crédito rural en la agricultura del Antiguo Régimen: desarrollo y crisis de las modalidades crediticias (1600-1850)». Noticiario de Historia Agraria 7, pp. 9-37.Google Scholar
Tello, E. (2007): «Crisis del Antiguo Régimen y crisis del sistema crediticio: el fin de los censos consignativos en España (1705-1885)», in De Dios, S., Infante, J., Robledo, R., and Torijano, E. (eds), Historia de la Propiedad. Crédito y Garantía. Madrid: Fundación Registral, pp. 237-270.Google Scholar
Van Bochove, C., Deneweth, H., and Zuijderduijn, J. (2015): «Real Estate and Mortgage Finance in England and the Low Countries, 1300–1800». Continuity and Change 30 (1), pp. 9-38.10.1017/S0268416015000107CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Zanden, J. L., Zuijderduijn, J., and De Moor, T. (2012): «Small is Beautiful: The Efficiency of Credit Markets in the Late Medieval Holland». European Review of Economic History 16, pp. 3-22.10.1093/ereh/her007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Villalón Barragán, S. (2008): «Els problemes de la informació en una societat d´antic règim. Els notaris Catalans davant la creació del register d'hipoteques», in Congost, R. (ed.), Dels capbreus al registre de la propietat. Drets, títols y usos socials de la informació a Catalunya (segles XIV-XX). Girona: Documenta Universitaria, pp. 241-274.Google Scholar
Villar García, Mª. B. (1982): Los extranjeros en Málaga en el siglo XVIII. Córdoba: Publicaciones del Monte de Piedad-Caja de Ahorros de Córdoba.Google Scholar
Vizcaíno Pérez, V. (1766): Discursos políticos sobre los estragos que causan los censos, felicidades y medios de su extinción. Madrid: Imprenta de Antonio Marín.Google Scholar
Wasserman, M. (2018): Las obligaciones fundamentales. Crédito y consolidación económica durante el surgimiento de Buenos Aires. Buenos Aires: Prometeo Libros.Google Scholar
Yun, B. (1998): «The American Empire and the Spanish Economy: An Institutional and Regional Perspective». Revista de Historia Económica 16 (1), pp. 123-156.Google Scholar
Zegarra, L. F. (2017a): «Private Lenders, Banks and Mortgage Credit in Peru. Evidence from Notarised Loans». Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 35 (1), pp. 105-146.10.1017/S0212610916000082CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zegarra, L. F. (2017b): «Usury Laws and Private Credit in Lima, Peru. Evidence from Notarial Records». Explorations in Economic History 65, pp. 68-93.10.1016/j.eeh.2017.02.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

TABLE 1. IMPORTANT EVENTS IN MORTGAGE REGISTRATION LEGISLATION BEFORE 1768

Figure 1

TABLE 2. LEGAL COSTS AND TAXES ASSOCIATED WITH A TWO-PAGE MORTGAGE OBLIGATION CONTRACT

Figure 2

TABLE 3. REGISTRATION COSTS IN DIFFERENT EUROPEAN MUNICIPALITIES IN THE 18TH CENTURY. EQUIVALENT VALUE: NUMBER OF DAYS' WAGES OF AN UNSKILLED WORKER

Figure 3

TABLE 4. NOTARIAL RECORDS DRAWN UP BY NOTARIES OF MALAGA IN 1784

Figure 4

TABLE 5. PERCENTAGE OF CONTRACTS AND AMOUNTS SUPPORTED WITH SPECIAL MORTGAGES IN 1764 AND 1784

Figure 5

TABLE 6. OLS REGRESSION RESULTS: IMPACT OF THE MORTGAGE REGIME AND THE STATUS OF THE BORROWER ON THE CAPITAL