Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T11:52:40.293Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Is Energy Subsidy Reform in an Oil-Exporting Small Economy Beneficial to Trade? Illustrations from Kuwait

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 September 2020

Manal Shehabi*
Affiliation:
Oxford Institute for Energy Studies, and St. Antony's College, University of Oxford

Abstract

This article fills a gap in the literature by quantifying impacts of fossil fuel subsidy reform on trade (inflow and outflow) in an oil-producing, “almost small”, economy, using Kuwait as an example. It employs a two-region economy-wide model with oligopoly behaviour in a general equilibrium framework. The model embodies unique elements of Kuwait's economic structure, idiosyncratic rigidities, and distortions, including oligopolistic industrial structure and labour markets. Simulations show that energy subsidies have minimal effects on trade and on non-energy exports, largely due to the pervasiveness of oligopolies that sustain large markups and their collusive pricing. Reforming energy subsidies generates higher pro-trade effects if implemented during low (not high) oil prices because its negative effects are partially offset by efficiency gains and reduction in oligopoly markups. Yet, contrary to claims by proponents of reforms, these effects remain largely constrained unless appropriate incentives are introduced. These results have important policy implications. In developing oil-exporting economies with pervasive oligopolies, microeconomic reform can be a channel through which to achieve pro-trade effects of energy subsidy reform. Further, benefits beyond export expansion, such as higher economic efficiency, could be better motivators of energy subsidy reform in oil economies.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aghion, P and Howitt, P. (1992) A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Al-Kaisi, E. (1993) Population and Labour in Kuwait Economy: The Problems and the Policies. Kuwait Economic Association, Kuwait.Google Scholar
AlSabah, MSS (1985) General Equilibrium Analysis of Government Expenditures in an Oil Exporting Country: The Case of Kuwait. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Armington, PS (1969) A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. IMF Staff Papers 16, 159178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arze Del Granado, F, Coady, D, and Gillingham, R (2012) The Unequal Benefits of Fuel Subsidies: A Review of Evidence for Developing Countries. World Development 40(11), 22342248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asano, A and Tyers, R (2019) Japan's Oligopolies: Potential Economy Wide Gains from Structural Reforms. Economic Modelling 82, 361375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balistreri, EJ and Markusen, JR (2009) Sub-National Differentiation and the Role of the Firm in Optimal International Pricing. Economic Modelling 26(1), 4762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bazilian, M and Onyeji, I (2012) Fossil Fuel Subsidy Removal and Inadequate Public Power Supply: Implications for Businesses. Energy Policy 45, 15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
British Petroleum Company (BP) (2018) BP Statistical Review of World Energy. London: British Petroleum Co.Google Scholar
BuShehri, MAM and Wohlgenant, MK (2012) Measuring the Welfare Effects of Reducing a Subsidy on a Commodity Using Micro-Models: An Application to Kuwait's Residential Demand for Electricity. Energy Economics 34(2), 419425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dennis, A (2016) Household Welfare Implications of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reforms in Developing Countries. Energy Policy 96, 597606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Devarajan, S and Rodrik, D (1991) Pro-Competitive Effects of Trade Reform: Results from a CGE Model of Cameroon. European Economic Review 35(5), 11571184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixon, P, Parmenter, B, Sutton, J, and Vincent, D (1982) ORANI: A Multisectoral Model of the Australian Economy, Contributions to Economic Analysis. New York: North-Holland Publishing Company.Google Scholar
El-Katiri, L, Bassam, F, and Segal, P (2011) Anatomy of an oil-based welfare state: Rent distribution in Kuwait. Kuwait Programme on Development, Governance and Globalisation in the Gulf States research papers (13). The London School of Economics and Political Science, London.Google Scholar
EIA (Energy Information Administration) (2017) World Energy Outlook. Washington, DC: Author.Google Scholar
Fattouh, B and Mahadeva, L (2014) Price Reform in Kuwait's Electricity and Water Sector: Assessing the Net Benefits in the Presence of Congestion. OIES paper MEP 9. Oxford: Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gahvari, F and Taheripour, F (2011) Fiscal Reforms In General Equilibrium: Theory and an Application to the Subsidy Debate in Iran. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 11(1), 154.Google Scholar
Gelan, A (2018) Economic and Environmental Impacts of Electricity Subsidy Reform in Kuwait: A General Equilibrium Analysis. Energy Policy 112, 381398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, GM and Helpman, E (2014) Growth, Trade, And Inequality. NBER working paper No. w20502. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. www.nber.org/papers/w20502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gunasekera, HD and Tyers, R (1990) Imperfect Competition and Returns to Scale in a Newly Industrialising Economy: A General Equilibrium Analysis of Korean Trade Policy. Journal of Development Economics 34, 223247.Google Scholar
Harris, R (1984) Applied General Equilibrium Analysis of Small Open Economies with Scale Economies and Imperfect Competition. American Economic Review 74(5), 1016.Google Scholar
Horridge, M (1987) The Long Term Costs of Protection: Experimental Analysis with Different Closures of an Australian Computable General Equilibrium Model. Doctoral dissertation. The University of Melbourne, Melbourne, Australia.Google Scholar
International Energy Agency (IEA) (2018) Outlook for Producer Economies 2018: What Do Changing Energy Dynamics Means for Major Oil and Gas Exporters? Paris: EIA.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2013) Kuwait: Selected Issues. IMF Country Report No. 13/337. Washington, D.C.: IMF.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, J and Tarr, D (2003) Trade, Exchange Rate, and Energy Pricing Reform in Iran: Potentially Large Efficiency Effects and Gains to the Poor. Review of Development Economics 7(4), 543562.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khorshid, M (1990) A Dynamic Macroeconomic Model for Kuwait: Analysis of the Medium-Term Path. Energy Economics 12(4), 289301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khorshid, M (1991) A Social-Accounting-Matrix-Based Long-term Model for a Gulf Cooperation Council Country: The Kuwaiti Case. Economic Systems Research 3(3), 299314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuwait Central Statistical Bureau (2017a) Annual General Statistics. Kuwait City: State of Kuwait. Kuwait Central Statistical Bureau.Google Scholar
Kuwait Central Statistical Bureau (2017b) Foreign Trade Statistics. Kuwait City: State of Kuwait.Google Scholar
Kuwaiti Stock Exchange (2013) Dalīl al-mustathmīr (Industry reports – the Investor's guide) Kuwait City.Google Scholar
Lin, B and Li, A (2012) Impacts of Removing Fossil Fuel Subsidies on China: How Large and How to Mitigate? Energy 44(1), 741749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Y, Shi, X, and Su, B (2017) Economic, Social and Environmental Impacts of Fuel Subsidies: A Revisit of Malaysia. Energy Policy 110, 5161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lofgren, H, Harris, RL, and Robinson, S (2002) A Standard Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Model in GAMS. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.Google Scholar
Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (2017) OPEC Annual Statistical Bulletin. Vienna, Austria. www.opec.org/opec_web/static_files_project/media/downloads/publications/ASB2017_13062017.pdf.Google Scholar
Public Authority for Civil Information (2018) Altaqār īr al-ʾiḥṣāʾiyya (The Statistical Reports). Kuwait City, Kuwait.Google Scholar
Rentschler, J (2016) Incidence and Impact: The Regional Variation of Poverty Effects Due to Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform. Energy Policy 96, 491503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roos, L and Adams, P (2019) The Economy-Wide Impact of Subsidy Reform: A CGE Analysis. (Centre of Policy Studies/IMPACT Centre working paper g-293). Melbourne, Victoria: Victoria University, Centre of Policy Studies/ IMPACT Centre.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, JA (1942) Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. London, UK: Routledge (1976).Google Scholar
Segerstrom, PS, Anant, TC, and Dinopoulos, E (1990) A Schumpeterian Model of the Product Life Cycle. The American Economic Review 8(5),10771091.Google Scholar
Shehabi, M (2017) Assessing Kuwaiti Energy Pricing Reforms. OIES Paper MEP 117. Oxford Institute for Energy Studies. Oxford. DOI: 10.26889/9781784670931. www.oxfordenergy.org/wpcms/wp-content/uploads/2017/11/Assessing-Kuwaiti-Energy-Pricing-Reforms-MEP-17.pdf.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
SWF Institute (n.d.) Sovereign Wealth Fund Rankings. www.swfinstitute.org/sovereign-wealth-fund-rankings/ (accessed 2 January 2018).Google Scholar
Tyers, R (2005) Trade Reform and Manufacturing Pricing Behavior in Four Archetype Asia–Pacific Economies. Asian Economic Journal 19(2), 181203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyers, R (2015) Service Oligopolies and Australia's Economy-Wide Performance. Australian Economic Review 48(4): 333356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank (2017) Energy Use, DataBank. World Bank: District of Columbia, USA.Google Scholar