Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T18:44:57.025Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An exploration of the motivational basis of take-some and give-some games

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

Tessa Haesevoets*
Affiliation:
Department of Developmental, Personality and Social Psychology, Ghent University, Henri Dunantlaan 2, B-9000, Ghent, Belgium
Alain Van Hiel
Affiliation:
Ghent University
Jasper Van Assche
Affiliation:
Ghent University
Dries H. Bostyn
Affiliation:
Ghent University
Chris Reinders Folmer
Affiliation:
Erasmus University Rotterdam
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Surprisingly little research has investigated the particular motives that underlie choice behavior in social dilemma situations. The main aim of the present research was to ask whether behavior in take-some games (such as the multiple-person Commons Dilemma Game and the two-person Bandit Game) and give-some games (such as the multiple-person Public Goods Dilemma Game and the two-person Dictator Game) is differently affected by proself and prosocial motives. Two experimental studies were conducted. Our first experiment used a trait-based assessment of the motives, whereas in our second experiment the motives were measured as state variables. The results of both experiments revealed that proself and prosocial motives did not explain much difference between taking and giving when comparing the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game. Yet, our second experiment revealed that these motives did differentiate choices in the Bandit Game and the Dictator Game. More specifically, prosocial motives are more strongly related to giving behavior in the Dictator Game than to taking behavior in the Bandit Game. As such, it can be concluded that in dyadic games (but not in multiple-person games) prosocial motives (but not proself motives) predict choice behavior in a game-specific way.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
The authors license this article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 License.
Copyright
Copyright © The Authors [2019] This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

1 Introduction

Social dilemmas are mixed-motive situations that confront people with a conflict between individual and collective interests: For each individual it is more profitable to act selfishly, but such behavior harms the collective (Reference DawesDawes, 1980; Reference Messick and BrewerMessick & Brewer, 1983). Reference Weber, Kopelman and MessickWeber, Kopelman and Messick (2004) aptly noted that “social dilemmas are everywhere” (p. 281). Indeed, it is difficult to imagine an aspect of social life that is not characterized by conflicting interests in terms of self-versus-other concerns. Typical examples of mixed-motive situations include the conservation of natural resources and volunteering behaviors. In order to be able to investigate social dilemmas empirically, researchers have modeled mixed-motive situations into a range of different mixed-motive games. In these games, people must choose between cooperation and defection, thereby benefiting either their own interests or those of the collective (for overviews, see Kollock, 1998; Reference Komorita and ParksKomorita & Parks, 1995; Reference VanLange, Joireman, Parks and VanDijkVan Lange, Joireman, Parks & Van Dijk, 2013).

The two main experimental paradigms used to investigate choice behavior in mixed-motive situations are the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game (Reference Rutte, Wilke and MessickRutte, Wilke & Messick, 1987; Van Dijk & Wilke, 1995, 2000). These two games are usually employed as models for the study of take-some and give-some dilemmas, respectively. In the Commons Dilemma Game, multiple players share a limited common resource pool from which everyone may take as many endowments as he or she wants. The potential danger is overuse, because the common good is in limited supply. It is thus in each player’s best interest to take as much as possible, but if the players collectively harvest too much, the common resource will be depleted and eventually get lost. Typical real-life examples of the Commons Dilemma Game concern the conservation of natural resources like water and clean air. The Public Goods Dilemma Game concerns a situation in which multiple players must choose between giving resources towards a public good from which all may benefit, or withholding them for private use. Players earn the most when they give nothing and profit from the donations of others (i.e., free riding). However, if players collectively give too little, the public good will cease to exist. Collective services provided by the government through taxation — such as public television, public roads, and national defense — can be seen as typical real-life examples of the Public Goods Dilemma Game.

A number of prior studies has examined the differences between Commons Dilemma Games and Public Goods Dilemma Games (e.g., Reference Au, Budescu, Foddy, Smithson, Schneider and HoggAu & Budescu, 1999; Reference DeDreu and McCuskerDe Dreu & McCusker, 1997; Reference McCarter, Budescu and ScheffranMcCarter, Budescu & Scheffran, 2011; Reference Poppe and ZwikkerPoppe & Zwikker, 1996; Reference Rutte, Wilke and MessickRutte et al., 1987; Van Dijk & Wilke, 1995, 2000). Most of this previous work has focused on when, and how, choice behavior alters if a game with the same payoff structure is framed as either a take-some or a give-some game. Yet, surprisingly little research has investigated how taking or giving impacts the motivational structure that underlies these games. Do both games capture the same motivational conflict? Or does the nature of their decisions alter how influential selfish and prosocial motives are? To illuminate these questions, the present research examines the motivational differences between take-some and give-some games.

1.1 Differential Motives Underlying Choice Behavior in Take-Some and Give-Some Games

Some prior studies have started to investigate the uniqueness and comparability of different mixed-motive games by exploring behavioral consistency levels across and within games. Because all mixed-motive games refer to a similar conflict in terms of selfish and other-related concerns (Reference Messick and BrewerMessick & Brewer, 1983; Reference Weber, Kopelman and MessickWeber et al., 2004), a certain degree of behavioral consistency across different mixed-motive games can be expected. However, previous research has found rather weak associations between behaviors across games (e.g., Haesevoets, Reinders Folmer & Van Hiel, 2015), and these associations were clearly weaker than the relationships which typically emerge between behaviors in repeated versions of the same game (e.g., Haesevoets, Reinders Folmer, Bostyn & Van Hiel, 2018). These findings thus suggest that, although the self-other conflict is at the core of each mixed-motive game, there may also be considerable differences among mixed-motive games; and these differences may possibly even overshadow the games’ common ground (see Reference Pruitt and KimmelPruitt & Kimmel, 1977; Reference VanLange, Joireman, Parks and VanDijkVan Lange et al., 2013).

Why might people make more consistent decisions in different versions of the same mixed-motive game than across different games? In response to this question, we suggest that games that involve taking and games that involve giving might be differently affected by proself and prosocial motives, thus undermining behavioral consistency across these two types of games. More specifically, we argue that, although each mixed-motive game brings the conflict between selfish interests and concern for others to the fore, the relative weight of these two conflicting motivational dimensions (proself and prosocial) might actually differ across different games. That is, in some games, behavior might be more strongly driven by the proself dimension; whereas in other games, behavior might be more strongly driven by the prosocial dimension. This reasoning is in line with the slot-machine model of interpersonal orientation of Van Lange, De Cremer, Van Vugt and Van Dijk (2007), which assumes that situational differences can alter the weight that people assign to their own interests and the interests of others.

Which motivational dimension (proself or prosocial) might be activated most strongly by games that involve taking behavior and by games that involve giving behavior? Take-some games concern decisions to harvest resources from a collectively owned resource pool. In this vein, Fleishman (1988, p. 176) has argued that “people might view the act of taking as ethically improper or exploitative.” As such, the defective behavior of taking many resources can be interpreted as a typical manifestation of a selfish act. Because of this, we expect that behavior in take-some games will be most strongly affected by proself motives. Give-some games, on the other hand, concern decisions to contribute personally owned resources to a public good. And, it has been argued that “people may view the act of giving as inherently positive, as an altruistic, morally desirable act” (Reference FleishmanFleishman, 1988, p. 176). In a giving context, cooperative behavior (i.e., giving many resources) can be seen as a typical prosocial act. Therefore, we expect that in give-some games behavior will be most strongly affected by prosocial motives. Taken together, we thus expect that taking will be more strongly driven by proself motives, whereas giving will be more strongly driven by prosocial motives (also see Rutte et al., 1987; Van Dijk & Wilke, 1995, 2000).

1.2 The Present Studies

To explore these predictions, we examined the association between proself and prosocial motives and decisions in the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game (Experiment 1), as well as in other games that involve taking or giving (Experiment 2).

In Experiment 1, motives underlying choice behavior were measured as trait variables. Doing so removes the need to solicit them repeatedly, and, moreover, is in line with prior research that suggests that individuals’ orientation on these motivations represent enduring personality characteristics (Reference Kuhlman and MarshelloKuhlman & Marshello, 1975; Reference LiebrandLiebrand, 1984; Reference Messick and McClintockMessick & McClintock, 1968). In Experiment 2 we shifted towards a state-based approach, in which the motives were assessed in relationship with the task itself. That is, after each game, we asked participants to answer some questions about their decision. These questions assessed the extent in which each motive played a role in participants’ decision.

In both experiments, we solicited a wide range of motives that have been linked to choice behavior in mixed-motive games in recent theorizing (i.e., the conceptual motivational model of Thielmann, Böhm & Hilbig, 2015) or research (i.e., the empirical study on within-game behavioral consistency of Haesevoets et al., 2018). Critically, instead of pitting these motivations against each other in hypothetical decisions (which has previously been done in measures of Social Value Orientation; e.g., Reference Murphy, Ackermann and HandgraafMurphy, Ackermann & Handgraaf, 2011; Reference VanLangeVan Lange, 1999), we measured each motive with a separate questionnaire. As prosocial motives, we included fairness (which is characterized by the desire to reach equality in outcomes), altruism (which reflects the motivation to maximize the benefit of others, regardless of the outcome for oneself), concern for others (which refers to the extent individuals are concerned with the interests of others), and social welfare concerns (which comprises the preference for maximizing the welfare of the collective). As proself motives, we included greed (which mirrors the motivation to maximize one’s own outcome), competitiveness (which reflects the desire to maximize one’s relative advantage over the outcome of others), and entitlement (which reflects the belief that one deserves preferential treatment). In addition to these prosocial and proself motives, in our first experiment we also included two fear-related motives, namely, fear (which consists of uncertainty about other people’s intentions) and risk aversion (which reflects a preference for a guaranteed outcome over a probabilistic one).

2 Experiment 1

2.1 Method

2.1.1 Sample and Procedure

A sample of 225 undergraduate students of a Belgian University participated in this study in exchange for partial fulfillment of course credit for a Social Psychology course (i.e., students could earn a total of 20 points for this course; participation in the experiment counted for 1 point). Participants were invited to the laboratory in groups of 35 to 45 persons. Participants were seated in a large room, each on a separate desk in front of a computer. During the experimental session, participants played 16 games. First, they played eight variants of the Commons Dilemma Game, followed by eight variants of the Public Goods Dilemma Game.Footnote 1 We used such game repetitions to obtain a more stable behavioral index for each game type. Participants were told that they would interact with each interaction partner only once. In reality, however, participants were not directly connected to each other during the study, but were randomly paired at the end of the experimental session, and paid according to the outcome that resulted from each player’s decision in one randomly selected game variant.Footnote 2 To avoid that participants’ decisions would be influenced by the choices of the other players, no feedback on the other players’ decisions was provided during the experiment. In the week after the experimental session, participants were asked to complete an online survey, in which the motivational traits were measured.Footnote 3 Participants were required to complete both the experimental session and the online survey in order to receive their course credit. Forty-four participants were excluded from the analyses because they failed to answer our check questions correctly, and an additional three participants because they did not complete the online survey.Footnote 4 As such, our final sample consisted of 178 participants (19.7% men, M age = 18.55, SD = 1.97).

2.1.2 Mixed-Motive Games

Commons Dilemma Game

Participants were first presented with the Commons Dilemma Game (Reference HardinHardin, 1968). In this game, four players had to simultaneously decide how many resources they wanted to take from a group resource. In order to create eight different variants of this take-some game, the endowment size of the group resource (low vs. high) and the magnitude of the multiplier (low vs. medium vs. high vs. very high) were orthogonally manipulated (see Table 1). In the high endowment condition, the resource pool from which participants could harvest consisted of double the resources as in the low endowment condition. In the low multiplier condition, participants were told that the endowments that were not taken by the players would to be multiplied by factor 1.5. The multiplication factor was 2 in the medium multiplier condition, 2.5 in the high multiplier condition, and 3 in the very high multiplier condition. The participants were informed that the resulting resources (after multiplication) would we divided equally among the four players, regardless of how many chips they took.

Table 1: Overview of the game variants and descriptive statistics of the game behaviors (Experiment 1)

Note. N = 178. The endowment size manipulation reflects how many resources the participants could maximally take (in the Commons Dilemma Game) or give (in the Public Goods Dilemma Game). The multiplication factor manipulation reflects with which number the remaining resources (in the Commons Dilemma Game) or the given resources (in the Public Goods Dilemma Game) were multiplied.

Public Goods Dilemma Game

Next, participants were presented with the Public Goods Dilemma Game (Reference Allison and KerrAllison & Kerr, 1994; Reference OlsonOlson, 1965), in which four players had to simultaneously decide how many of their individually owned resources they wanted to give to the group resource. Here too, eight game variants were created by orthogonally manipulating the endowment size and the magnitude of the multiplier (see Table 1). In the high endowment condition, participants’ individual resources at the start of the game were double to that in the low endowment condition. Endowments that were given to the collective good were said to be multiplied by a multiplication factor of 1.5 (low multiplier), 2 (medium multiplier), 2.5 (high multiplier), or 3 (very high multiplier). The resulting resources (after multiplication) were said to be divided equally among the four players (regardless of how many chips they gave).

2.1.3 Motivational Traits

The online survey measured individual differences in the following motivational traits: Fairness, altruism, social welfare concerns, concern for others, greed, competitiveness, entitlement, fear, and risk aversion. It was administered one week after the experimental session took place. Table 2 presents an overview of the scales that were employed to measure these trait motivations; the full item list is included in Appendix A.

Table 2: Overview of the motivational trait scales (Experiment 1)

Note. N = 178. The motivational traits were all measured using seven-point Likert scales ranging from (1) strongly disagree to (7) strongly agree. The attribution scales were slightly adapted in order to measure individual differences in the relevant motivational trait.

2.2 Results

2.2.1 Game Data

The means and standard deviations of the game behaviors can be found in Table 1. Across the eight Commons Dilemma Games, participants took on average 76 resources from the group resource (and thus left 164 in the common pool). Across the eight Public Goods Dilemma Games, participants gave on average 125 resources to the group resource (and thus kept 115 for themselves). These findings indicate that participants acted more cooperatively in the Commons Dilemma Game than in the Public Goods Dilemma Game (i.e., they left more resources in the Commons Dilemma Games than that they gave in the Public Goods Dilemma Games).

Manipulation of game features

We subsequently asked whether our manipulations of the game features affected choice behavior. To do so, we conducted a 2 (game type: commons vs. public good) × 2 (endowment size: low vs. high) × 4 (multiplier: low vs. medium vs. high vs. very high) repeated measures analysis of variance (ANOVA), with all factors being within-participant. The results of this analysis showed that the three main effects, the three two-way interactions, and the three-way interaction were all highly significant (all Fs ≥ 4.98, ps < .003). These findings imply that the game type, the size of the endowments, and the magnitude of the multiplication factor all have a significant influence on participants’ choices — which indicates that our manipulations were indeed successful for inducing variations in choice behavior.

Factor structure of the games

We conducted a factor analysis (Principal Axis Factoring) to investigate if the two games load on different underlying factors. Two factors were extracted from the inter-correlations among the scores on the 16 game behaviors: The eight Public Goods Dilemma Games loaded on a first factor (initial eigenvalue = 8.98; after rotation = 7.57), whereas the eight Commons Dilemma Games constituted a second factor (initial eigenvalue = 2.73; after rotation = 6.99). Most importantly, the primary factor loadings were all larger than .72, while the cross-loadings were all smaller than |.09|; indicating a clean factor structure.

The results of this factor analysis hence indicate that choice behavior is particularly contingent on the type of decision that has to be made (take or give). Accordingly, we created an index score for choice behavior in either game, by aggregating participants’ (standardized) scores in the eight game variants. We reversed the scores of the Commons Dilemma Game index, so that the two game indices both pointed in the same direction. We used these created index scores as our measure of choice behavior in our subsequent analyses.Footnote 5

2.2.2 Motivational Data

Reduction of the motivations

Table 3 shows the correlation matrix of the motivational traits. To reduce these motivations to a limited number of indicators of the underlying motivational conflict, we conducted a factor analysis (again using the Principal Axis Factoring method) to extract underlying factors form the inter-correlations among the motivational items. Three motivational factors were extracted; Appendix B shows their factor loadings after Oblimin rotation. The first extracted factor (initial eigenvalue = 9.86; after rotation = 7.40) consisted of four of the six greed items, the ten competiveness items, and the nine entitlement items; hence, we labeled this the proself motivational factor. The second factor (initial eigenvalue = 8.03; after rotation = 7.40) consisted of the nine fear items and five of the six risk aversion items; thus, we labelled it the fearful motivational factor. Finally, the third factor (initial eigenvalue = 4.48; after rotation = 7.42) included the five fairness items, the three altruism items, the four social welfare concerns items, and the five concern for others items; accordingly, it was labeled the prosocial motivational factor. Note that two greed items (items 5 and 6) and one risk aversion item (item 5) had their primarily loadings on the wrong factor and were therefore discarded from this analysis.

Table 3: Correlation matrix of the motives (Experiment 1)

Note. N = 178. CDG = Commons Dilemma Game. PGDG = Public Goods Dilemma Game. For both games, we used the created index scores. For the Commons Dilemma Game, the signs of the correlations were reversed. p < .01. for all correlations of .20 or more; p < .05, for correlations from .16 to .19.

2.2.3 Motivational Differences between the Games

We next explored our prediction that behavior in the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game are differently affected by proself and prosocial motives. Towards this end, we computed correlations between the three extracted motivational factors (proself, fearful, and prosocial) and choice behavior in the two games (using the standardized index scores of the games). This analysis revealed that decisions in both games correlated significantly with the proself and the prosocial motivational factors, but not with the fearful factor. More specifically, the correlation between the Commons Dilemma Game and the proself factor was r = −.27, while the correlation between the Public Goods Dilemma Game and the proself factor was r = −.17. We calculated the difference between these two correlation coefficients using the cocor package in R (Reference Diedenhofen and MuschDiedenhofen & Musch, 2015); this test revealed that the difference between these two correlation coefficients did not reach statistical significance (Z = 1.41, p = .159). The correlation between the Public Goods Dilemma Game and the prosocial factor was r = .20, whereas the Commons Dilemma Game correlated r = .16 with the prosocial factor. These correlations coefficients also did not differ significantly in magnitude (Z = 0.56, p = .577).

Subsidiary canonical correlations

The correlation analyses reported above seem to indicate that there might be some specificity (i.e., the proself dimension is more influential in the Commons Dilemma Game, while the prosocial dimension is more influential in the Public Goods Dilemma Game). To test if this specificity is statistically significant, we have conducted a canonical correlation analysis between the two games and the two motivational factors using the yacca package in R (Reference ButtsButts, 2018). Canonical correlations are used to identify and measure the associations among two sets of variables. It determines a set of canonical variates, orthogonal linear combinations of the variables within each set that best explain the variability both within and between sets. The results of this analysis revealed that only the first (but not the second) canonical correlation was significant (first canonical correlation: r = .30, χ2(4) = 18.83, p < 001; second canonical correlation: r = .10, χ2(1) = 1.92, p = .166); which indicates that decisions in the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game can both be predicted from the two motivational factors, but not in a way that is specific to each game.

2.3 Discussion

Based on the findings of Experiment 1, it can be concluded that choice behavior in the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game did not show significantly differing associations to the proself and prosocial motivational dimensions. A possible explanation for this lack of specificity, however, is that the trait motives that we employed in Experiment 1 may be only distantly related to choice behavior. To explore this possibility, we conducted a second experiment in which the motives were measured as states.

Experiment 1 explored how taking and giving impacts the motivational structure of the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game. To further illuminate this question, Experiment 2 expanded our focus to other mixed-motive games. Specifically, in addition to the multiple-person Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game, Experiment 2 also included the Bandit Game and the Dictator Game – which involve taking and giving in a dyadic setting, without partner dependence (Reference Weber, Kopelman and MessickWeber et al., 2004). By doing so, Experiment 2 enables us to investigate not only motivational differences between taking and giving in the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game (Comparison 1), but also whether such differences may be enhanced in the dyadic Bandit Game and Dictator Game (Comparison 2). Thus, Experiment 2 enables us to explore two theoretically relevant comparisons.

3 Experiment 2

3.1 Method

3.1.1 Sample and Procedure

A total of 247 US and UK adult participants — recruited through the online platform Prolific Academic (http://www.prolific.ac) — participated in the present study for payment (£1.60). Participants played four games: One Commons Dilemma Game, one Public Goods Dilemma Game, one Bandit Game, and one Dictator Game. These four games were presented in a randomized order. Each game was played only once. The instructions were identical to Experiment 1. That is, participants were told that, in each game, they would be connected to one or more fellow participants, and that they would interact with each partner only once. They were also informed that they would receive a bonus payment based on one randomly selected game. In reality, however, participants were not directly connected to each other during the study and each participant received a fixed bonus payment of £0.40. Again, participants received no information on the other players’ decisions during the experiment. After each of the four games, we measured the extent to which different motives played a role in participants’ decision. Eighteen participants failed to answer our included check questions correctly, and were therefore excluded from the analyses.Footnote 6 Our final sample thus consisted of 229 participants (34.1% men, M age = 33.07, SD = 12.42). When inquired about their highest educational level, 5.2% reported no degree, 37.6% mentioned a high school diploma; 40.6% reported a Bachelor’s degree, 14.8% a Master’s degree, and 1.7% a PhD degree.

3.1.2 Mixed-Motive Games

Commons Dilemma Game

In the Commons Dilemma Game, four players had to simultaneously decide how much to take from a collective resource that consisted of 160 chips (each chip being worth £0.01). By means of a slider (beginning at 0 and moving up to 40), participants indicated how many chips they wanted to take from the group resource. Participants were told that the chips that were not taken by the players would to be multiplied by factor 2.5, and that the resulting number of chips (after multiplication) would then be divided equally among the four players, regardless of how many chips they took.Footnote 7

Public Goods Dilemma Game

In the Public Goods Dilemma Game, four players had to simultaneously decide how much of their 40 individually owned chips they wanted to give to the group resource. Participants were again presented by a slider which started at 0 and moved up to 40. Participants were informed that the chips that were given by the players would to be multiplied by factor 2.5, and then equally divided between the four players.

Bandit Game

The Bandit Game reflects a two-person take-some game (Reference Eichenberger and Oberholzer-GeeEichenberger & Oberholzer-Gee, 1998). At the start of this game, the participants possessed 0 chips while the other player possessed 100 chips. By means of a slider (beginning at 0 and moving up to 100), the participants had to decide how many of the other player’s chips they wanted to take for themselves. The participants were informed that the other player has no influence, and thus must accept their decision.

Dictator Game

The Dictator Game is a two-person give-some game (Reference Kahneman, Knetsch and ThalerKahneman, Knetsch & Thaler, 1986). At the start of this game, the participants possessed 100 chips while the other player possessed 0 chips. During the task, the participants must decide how many of their own chips they wanted to give to the other player. Again, we presented participants with a slider which started at 0 and moved up to 100. Here too, participants were informed that the other player has no influence on their decision.

3.1.3 Motivational States

In Experiment 2, we adopted a state-based approach to the motivations. As such, following each of the four games, we assessed to which extent each motive played a role in participants’ decision. We included the same prosocial (fairness, altruism, social welfare concerns, and concern for others) and proself (greed, competitiveness, and entitlement) motives as in the previous study (the fearful motives were no longer included). To assess these motives as states, we utilized the interpersonal orientation measures of Van Lange and colleagues (2007; also see Klapwijk & Van Lange, 2009; Reference Tazelaar, VanLange and OuwerkerkTazelaar, Van Lange & Ouwerkerk, 2004). The items of all motive scales are listed in Appendix C.

3.2 Results

3.2.1 Game Data

The means, standard deviations, and inter-correlations between the four game behaviors are displayed in Table 4. This table shows that the four game behaviors were all significantly correlated with each other. In the Commons Dilemma Game, participants took on average 12 chips from the group resource (and thus left 28 chips in the group resource). In Public Goods Dilemma Game, participants gave on average 26 chips to the group resource (and thus kept 14 chips for themselves). In the Bandit Game, participants took on average 51 chips from the other player (and thus left 49 chips for the other player). In the Dictator Game, participants gave on average 41 chips to the other player (and thus kept 59 chips for themselves). As in Experiment 1, these findings indicate that participants acted more cooperatively in the take-some situations than in the equivalent give-some situations.

Table 4: Descriptive statistics and correlations between the game behaviors (Experiment 2)

Note. N = 229. For the Commons Dilemma Game and the Bandit Game, the signs of the correlations were reversed (so that all game behaviors point in the same direction). p < .01 for all correlations.

3.2.2 Motivational Data

Reduction of the motivations

Appendix D shows the correlation matrix of the motivational states, separately for each of the four mixed-motive games. For each of these four games, we conducted a factor analysis to extract two motivational factors from the inter-correlations among the motivational items (extraction method: Principal Axis Factoring; rotation method: Oblimin). For each of the four games, we were able to extract a prosocial motivational factor (which consists of the fairness, altruism, social welfare concerns, and concern for others items) and a proself motivational factor (which consists of the greed, competitiveness, and entitlement items). Appendix E provides an overview of the factor loadings of these two factors, separately for each of the four games. Note that for the Bandit Game, the three altruism items and the first two concern for others items had their primarily loadings on the wrong factor and were therefore discarded from the analysis in Model B.

Factor congruence

We subsequently calculated the degree of congruence between the sets of factor loadings reported in Appendix E. More specifically, following Harman’s (1976) empirical rule, we computed correlations among the factor loadings that were obtained in each of the four games (for the Bandit Game, we used the two factors that were extracted in Model B). The result of this analysis indicates that the four extracted prosocial factors show high congruence (i.e., the correlations among their factor loadings ranged from r = .96 to r = .98). Similarly, the four extracted proself factors were also highly congruent (i.e., correlations among their factor loadings ranged from r = .96 to r = .99).

3.2.3 Motivational Differences between the Games

As in Experiment 1, we first examined if games that involve taking behavior and games that involve giving behavior are differently affected by proself and prosocial motivations, by comparing the motivational profile of the Commons Dilemma Game with that of the Public Goods Dilemma Game (Comparison 1). Similar analyses were also conducted for the Bandit Game versus the Dictator Game comparison (Comparison 2). Before conducting these analyses, we first reversed the scores of the two take-some games (Commons Dilemma Game and Bandit Game), so that the scores of all four games pointed in the same direction.

Commons Dilemma Game versus Public Goods Dilemma Game

We first computed correlations between the two extracted motivational factors (proself and prosocial factor) and choice behavior in the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game. As in Experiment 1, decisions in both games correlated significantly with both motivational factors. More precisely, the correlation between the Commons Dilemma Game and the proself factor was r = −.38, while the correlation between the Public Goods Dilemma Game and the proself factor was r = −.27. We again tested the statistical significance of the difference between these two correlations. The test showed that the difference between these two correlation coefficients did not reach statistical significance (Z = 1.50, p = .135). For the prosocial factor, we found a correlation r = .45 with behavior in the Public Goods Dilemma Game, while the Commons Dilemma Game correlated r = .41. Here too, these two correlation coefficients did not differ significantly (Z = 0.71, p = .481).

Bandit Game versus Dictator Game

We next computed correlations between the two extracted motivational factors and choice behavior in the Bandit Game and the Dictator Game. Decisions in both of these games showed significant associations with both the proself and the prosocial factor. Yet, when comparing the strength of these associations, the proself factor was not associated more strongly (Z = 1.57, p = .116) with decisions in the Bandit Game (r = −.71) than with decisions in the Dictator Game (r = −.63). However, the prosocial factor did show a significantly stronger association (Z = 6.25, p < .001) with decisions in the Dictator Game (r = .67) than with decisions in the Bandit Game (r = .29). This latter finding seems to indicate that, in line with our predictions, prosocial motives are more strongly related to giving behavior in the Dictator Game than to taking behavior in the Bandit Game.

Subsidiary canonical correlations

The correlation analyses for our first comparison indicate that the proself motivational factor is more strongly related to taking behavior in the Commons Dilemma Game, whereas the prosocial motivational factor is more strongly associated with giving behavior in the Public Goods Dilemma Game. To test if this specificity is statistical significant, we again conducted canonical correlation analysis. Towards this end, we first created a sum score of the proself factors of the two games as well as a sum score of the prosocial factors of the two games. The analysis (using these sum scores) revealed that the first canonical correlation did reach statistical significance (first canonical correlation: r = .50, χ2(4) = 65.37, p < .001), but the second one did not reach statistical significance (second canonical correlation: r = .05, χ2(1) = 0.50, p = .479). As in Experiment 1, choice behavior in multiple-person games can be predicted from the two motivational dimensions, but not in a game-specific way.

For our second comparison, the reported correlations also seem to indicate that there might be some specificity, as the proself factor is more influential in the Bandit Game and the prosocial factor in the Dictator Game. To test the statistical significance of this specificity, we again conducted a canonical correlation analysis (in which we again used combinations of the motive factors). The results of this analysis revealed that both resulting canonical correlates were highly significant (first canonical correlation: r = .74, χ2(4) = 203.83, p < .001; second canonical correlation: r = .31, χ2(1) = 23.41, p < .001). This finding indicates that taking and giving in the Bandit Game and the Dictator Game are associated with similar motives, yet considerable differences exist between the strength of the association of these motives with choice behavior. Or stated differently, the significance of the second canonical correlation reveals that, for these two games, the motives predict choice behavior in a game-specific way. When taking a closer look at the raw correlations (with the motive factors combined over both games), it is apparent that prosocial motives more strongly predict giving behavior in the Dictator Game (r = .62) than taking behavior in the Bandit Game (r = .34), while proself motives are about equally strongly related to taking and giving in both games (r = −.60 and r = −.65, for respectively the Bandit Game and the Dictator Game).

3.3 Discussion

In Experiment 2, we employed a state-based approach to measure the motivations and included two additional mixed-motive games. An interesting observation is that, in the present study, the correlations between the motives and the game behaviors were considerably larger than in Experiment 1. Despite these larger correlations, the results of the present experiment revealed, similar to the prior study, no substantial motivational differences between the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game. When comparing the motivational profile of the Bandit Game with that of the Dictator Game, we found specificity, but largely for the prosocial motives — which were more influential in the Dictator Game than in the Bandit Game.

4 General Discussion

Many conflicts in daily life arise from competing interests in terms of selfish versus prosocial concerns. In research, various mixed-motive games have been developed to study these conflicting interests. Although the basis of all mixed-motive games resides in this self-other conflict, these games also seem to exhibit unique elements. To gain more insight into the motivational basis of different mixed-motive games, we conducted two experimental studies. The main aim of these studies was to investigate if games that involve taking behavior show differing associations to proself and prosocial motivations than games that involve giving behavior. We predicted that taking and giving might modulate the importance of proself and prosocial motives between structurally equivalent games (as in the “slot-machine model” of interpersonal orientation of Van Lange et al., 2007). Our results illustrate that motivational differences between taking and giving only occur in games that are characterized by lower interdependence and greater simplicity, that is, in dyadic games.

4.1 Differential Effects of Proself and Prosocial Motives

In Experiment 1, no significant differences between the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game in the association between motives and choice behavior were observed. However, given that the associations between the trait motives and the choice behaviors were generally low, we complemented this study with a second experiment in which the studied motives were measured as states, and taking and giving was also examined in dyadic settings.

Experiment 2 revealed stronger associations between the motives and the choice behaviors. However, when comparing the Commons Dilemma Game to the Public Goods Dilemma Game, as in the first experiment, no significant motivational differences were observed. Yet, when comparing taking and giving in the two dyadic games, giving behavior in the Dictator Game was associated more strongly with prosocial motives than taking behavior in the Bandit Game. The proself motives were about equally strongly related with choice behavior in both games. As such, Experiment 2 provides evidence that prosocial motives may be associated more with giving than with taking; but this evidence for specificity was observed only in dyadic games.

How can we understand these findings? The results of our studies suggest that motivational differences between taking and giving may be observed more readily in situations that are characterized by lower complexity and interdependence. In multi-person games, such differences seem to be obscured by the greater social complexity of decision-making. In such settings, choice behavior is likely to be shaped by other factors such as expectations about the other players’ behavior (see Reference FleishmanFleishman, 1988; Reference VanDijk and WilkeVan Dijk & Wilke, 2000; Reference Weber, Kopelman and MessickWeber et al., 2004), which may attenuate the impact of the measured motivations. Indeed, a number of studies has shown that expectations about how other people will behave strongly affect people’s choices in social dilemma situations (e.g., Dawes, McTavish & Shaklee, 1977; Reference Kelley and StahelskiKelley & Stahelski, 1970; Reference Schroeder, Jensen, Reed, Sullivan and SchwabSchroeder, Jensen, Reed, Sullivan & Schwab, 1983). In this vein, it is possible that our measurements of the motives might have missed the relevance of expectancies with respect to the other players’ behavior, which can also help us explain why no differential effects of the motives were found when comparing the two multiple-person games with each other. Note that such considerations about the other players’ behavior are strongly reduced in our dyadic games, where participants can decide unilaterally. In this setting, the impact of our motivational measures seems to be more pronounced, and some indications for distinct motivational bases for taking and giving can be observed.

4.2 Limitations and Future Research Suggestions

When moving from Experiment 1 to Experiment 2, two major changes were implemented. That is, in our second experiment the motives were measured as states (instead of traits), and we included two additional mixed-motive games (i.e., the Bandit Game and the Dictator Game). As a result of this, it is unclear whether the motivational traits that we measured in our first experiment also relate to behavior in the Bandit Game and the Dictator Game. Future research in this domain is therefore encouraged to investigate if the motivational differences that we found between these two dyadic games also hold true with a trait-based assessment of the motivations.

Another important avenue for future research is to gain more understanding of the processes that underlie taking and giving behavior, and the factors that may modulate their associations to choice behavior. Take-some dilemmas concern decisions to take resources from a collectively owned resource pool (in case of the Commons Dilemma Game) or another person (in case of the Bandit Game). Because childhood socialization practices generally define giving as “good” and taking form others as “bad” (for a similar argument, see Fleishman, 1988, p. 176), it can be expected that, in the context of take-some games, people will refrain from taking a lot of resources (as this is considered bad behavior). In accordance with this reasoning and the results of Reference Brewer and KramerBrewer and Kramer (1986), our experimental studies revealed that participants indeed displayed greater cooperation when the games were framed in terms of taking than when they were framed in terms of giving.

Importantly, in addition to prosocial and proself motives (on which we focused in the present research), differences between taking and giving are likely to also be rooted in other processes, including partner expectations, accountability, perceived norms, and efficacy (Reference Kopelman, Weber, Messick, Ostrom, Dietz, Dolsak, Stern and WeberKopelman, Weber & Messick, 2002; Reference Weber, Kopelman and MessickWeber et al., 2004). Furthermore, differences between taking and giving could also be explained by endowment effects (Reference Kahneman, Knetsch and ThalerKahneman, Knetsch & Thaler, 1991), such that people feel more entitled to resources that they regard as their property (Reference Leliveld, VanDijk and VanBeestLeliveld, Van Dijk & Van Beest, 2008). Future research may build on the present findings to identify an expanded profile for taking and giving behavior, as well as its dependence on other structural features (such as provision point, group size, etc.). By doing so, we may better understand how take-some and give-some games shape people’s mindset – and discover avenues by which socially beneficial mindsets may be activated, so that the collective interest can be promoted.

Footnotes

This research was supported by the Special Research Fund (BOF) of Ghent University (Grant number: BOF.PDO.2017.0017.01).

1 We also included eight Prisoner’s Dilemma Games in our first experiment. The data of these games are not included in the present manuscript for two reasons. First, to create eight different versions of the Prisoner’s Dilemma Game, we could not manipulate the same variables as those manipulated to create the different versions of the Commons Dilemma Game and Public Goods Dilemma Game. Secondly, the decision that participants had to make in the Prisoner’s Dilemma Game did not consist of either taking behavior or giving behavior. We plan to use the data of the Prisoner’s Dilemma Games in another manuscript that deals with real-life prosocial behavior.

2 When the experiment was finished, participants were asked whether they wanted to keep their earnings or donate their earnings to a noble cause. Of all participants, 94% indicated that they wanted to donate their money to a charity.

3 This online survey also measured Social Value Orientation, Right-Wing Authoritarianism, Social Dominance Orientation, and dispositional trust, but these data are not used in the present paper. We plan to use these personality data in another manuscript.

4 In each part of the study, participants had to answer some check questions. Participants who were unable to answer — in each part of the study — at least n−1 (i.e., the number of checks minus one) check questions correctly were excluded from further analyses. More information on these check questions is provided on our OSF webpage (https://osf.io/jrqxb).

5 For both games, the extracted factor score and the created index score were almost perfectly correlated (Commons Dilemma Game: r = .996 and Public Goods Dilemma Game: r = .996; both ps < .001). Moreover, the correlation between the two created index scores was also rather high (r = .53, p < .001).

6 After each of the four game instructions, participants were asked to answer two comprehension questions. Participants who were unable to answer six out of eight (n−2) check questions correctly were excluded from further analyses (more information on these check questions can be found on our OSF webpage: https://osf.io/jrqxb).

7 To represent the Commons Dilemma Game and the Public Goods Dilemma Game in Experiment 2, we utilized the version that displayed the highest factor loading in Experiment 1 (i.e., game variant 7).

References

5 References

Allison, S. T., & Kerr, N. L. (1994). Group correspondence biases and the provision of public goods. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 66, 688-698.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Au, W., & Budescu, D. V. (1999). Sequential effects in give-some and take-some social dilemmas. In Foddy, M., Smithson, M., Schneider, S., & Hogg, M. (Eds.), Resolving social dilemmas: Dynamic, structural, and intergroup aspects (pp. 87-99). Philadelphia, PA: Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Brewer, M. B., & Kramer, R. M. (1986). Choice behavior in social dilemmas: Effects of social identity, group size, and decision framing. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 50, 543-549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Butts, C. T. (2018). yacca: Yet Another Canonical Correlation Analysis Package. R package version 1.1.1.Google Scholar
Campbell, W. K., Bonacci, A. M., Shelton, J., Exline, J. J., & Bushman, B. J. (2004). Psychological entitlement: Interpersonal consequences and validation of a self-report measure. Journal of Personality Assessment, 83, 2945.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dawes, R. M. (1980). Social dilemmas. Annual Review of Psychology, 31, 169193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R. M., McTavish, J., & Shaklee, H. (1977). Behavior, communication, and assumptions about other people’s behavior in a commons dilemma situation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35, 111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeDreu, C. K., & McCusker, C. (1997). Gain–loss frames and cooperation in two-person social dilemmas: A transformational analysis. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 72, 10931106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diedenhofen, B. & Musch, J. (2015). cocor: A comprehensive solution for the statistical comparison of correlations. PLoS ONE, 10(4): e0121945.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Eichenberger, R., & Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1998). Rational moralists: The role of fairness in democratic economic politics. Public Choice, 94, 191210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleishman, J. A. (1988). The effects of decision framing and others’ behavior on cooperation in a social dilemma. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 32, 162-180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haesevoets, T., ReindersFolmer, C., Bostyn, D. H., & VanHiel, A. (2018). Behavioural consistency within the prisoner’s dilemma game: the role of personality and situation. European Journal of Personality, 32, 405-426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haesevoets, T., ReindersFolmer, C., & VanHiel, A. (2015). Cooperation in mixed-motive games: the role of individual differences in selfish and social orientation. European Journal of Personality, 29, 445-458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243-1248.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harman, H. H. (1976). Modern factor analysis (3rd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. (1986). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. American Economic Review, 76, 728741.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5, 193206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelley, H. H., & Stahelski, A. J. (1970). Social interaction basis of cooperators’ and competitors’ beliefs about others. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 16, 6691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klapwijk, A., & VanLange, P. A. (2009). Promoting cooperation and trust in “noisy” situations: The power of generosity. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 96, 83103.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kollock, P. (1998). Social dilemmas: The anatomy of cooperation. Annual Review of Sociology, 24, 183214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Komorita, S. S., & Parks, C. D. (1995). Interpersonal relations: Mixed-motive interaction. Annual Review of Psychology, 46, 183-207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kopelman, S., Weber, J. M., & Messick, D. M. (2002). Factors influencing cooperation in commons dilemmas: A review of experimental psychological research. In Ostrom, E., Dietz, T., Dolsak, N., Stern, P. C., S. Stonich, & Weber, E. U. (Eds.), The Drama of the Commons (pp. 113156). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
Krekels, G., & Pandelaere, M. (2015). Dispositional greed. Personality and Individual Differences, 74, 225230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhlman, D. M., & Marshello, A. F. (1975). Individual differences in game motivation as moderators of preprogrammed strategy effects in prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 32, 922931.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Leliveld, M. C., VanDijk, E., & VanBeest, I. (2008). Initial ownership in bargaining: Introducing the giving, splitting, and taking ultimatum bargaining game. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 34, 12141225.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Liebrand, W. B. (1984). The effect of social motives, communication and group size on behaviour in an N-person multi-stage mixed-motive game. European Journal of Social Psychology, 14, 239-264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mandrik, C. A., & Bao, Y. (2005). Exploring the concept and measurement of General Risk Aversion. Advances in Consumer Research, 32, 531539.Google Scholar
McCarter, M. W., Budescu, D. V., & Scheffran, J. (2011). The give-or-take-some dilemma: An empirical investigation of a hybrid social dilemma. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 116, 8395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Messick, D. M., & Brewer, M. B. (1983). Solving social dilemmas: A review. Review of Personality and Social Psychology, 4, 1144.Google Scholar
Messick, D. M., & McClintock, C. G. (1968). Motivational bases of choice in experimental games. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 4, 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, R. O., Ackermann, K. A., & Handgraaf, M. (2011). Measuring social value orientation. Judgment and Decision making, 6, 771-781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poppe, M., & Zwikker, M. (1996). The effect of threshold level on greed, fear, and cooperation in step-level give-some and take-some dilemmas. In Frontiers in social dilemmas research (pp. 185-204). Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pruitt, D. G., & Kimmel, M. J. (1977). Twenty years of experimental gaming: Critique, synthesis, and suggestions for the future. Annual Review of Psychology, 28, 363392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutte, C. G., Wilke, H. A., & Messick, D. M. (1987). The effects of framing social dilemmas as give-some or take-some games. British Journal of Social Psychology, 26, 103108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schroeder, D. A., Jensen, T. D., Reed, A. J., Sullivan, D. K., & Schwab, M. (1983). The actions of others as determinants of behavior in social trap situations. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 19, 522539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selenta, C., & Lord, R. G. (2005). Development of the levels of self-concept scale: measuring the individual, relational, and collective levels. Working paper, University of Akron.Google Scholar
Tazelaar, M. J. A., VanLange, P. A. M., & Ouwerkerk, J. W. (2004). How to cope with “noise” in social dilemmas: the benefits of communication. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87, 845859.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Thielmann, I., Böhm, R., & Hilbig, B. E. (2015). Different games for different motives: Comment on Haesevoets, Folmer, and Van Hiel (2015). European Journal of Personality, 29, 506508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
VanDijk, E., & Wilke, H. (1995). Coordination rules in asymmetric social dilemmas: A comparison between public good dilemmas and resource dilemmas. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 31, 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
VanDijk, E., & Wilke, H. (2000). Decision-induced focusing in social dilemmas: Give-some, keep-some, take-some, and leave-some dilemmas. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 78, 92104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
VanHiel, A., Vanneste, S., & DeCremer, D. (2008). Why did they claim too much? The role of causal attributions in explaining level of cooperation in commons and anticommons dilemmas. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 38, 173197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
VanLange, P. A. (1999). The pursuit of joint outcomes and equality in outcomes: An integrative model of social value orientation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 77, 337-349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
VanLange, P. A., DeCremer, D., VanDijk, E., & VanVugt, M. (2007). Self-interest and beyond: basic principles of social interaction. In Kruglanski, A. W. & Higgins, E. T. (Eds.), Social psychology: Handbook of basic principles (2nd ed.). (pp. 540561). New York, NY, US: Guilford Press.Google Scholar
VanLange, P. A., Joireman, J., Parks, C. D., & VanDijk, E. (2013). The psychology of social dilemmas: A review. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 120, 125141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, J. M., Kopelman, S., & Messick, D. M. (2004). A conceptual review of decision making in social dilemmas: Applying a logic of appropriateness. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 8, 281307.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Xie, X., Yu, Y., Chen, X., & Chen, X. P. (2006). The measurement of cooperative and competitive personality. Acta Psychologica Sinica, 38, 116125.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1: Overview of the game variants and descriptive statistics of the game behaviors (Experiment 1)

Figure 1

Table 2: Overview of the motivational trait scales (Experiment 1)

Figure 2

Table 3: Correlation matrix of the motives (Experiment 1)

Figure 3

Table 4: Descriptive statistics and correlations between the game behaviors (Experiment 2)

Supplementary material: File

Haesevoets et al. supplementary material

Haesevoets et al. supplementary material 1
Download Haesevoets et al. supplementary material(File)
File 133.3 KB
Supplementary material: File

Haesevoets et al. supplementary material

Haesevoets et al. supplementary material 2
Download Haesevoets et al. supplementary material(File)
File 146.4 KB
Supplementary material: File

Haesevoets et al. supplementary material

Experiment 1: List of Variables
Download Haesevoets et al. supplementary material(File)
File 11.4 KB
Supplementary material: File

Haesevoets et al. supplementary material

Experiment 2: List of Variables
Download Haesevoets et al. supplementary material(File)
File 12.1 KB
Supplementary material: File

Haesevoets et al. supplementary material

Supplementary materials
Download Haesevoets et al. supplementary material(File)
File 445.6 KB