Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T17:58:53.317Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

From “Chinese Colonist” to “Yellow Peril”: Capitalist Racialization in the British Empire

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 November 2023

ONUR ULAS INCE*
Affiliation:
SOAS University of London, United Kingdom
*
Onur Ulas Ince, Associate Professor of Political Theory, Department of Politics and International Studies, SOAS University of London, United Kingdom, ulas.ince@soas.ac.uk.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The literature on “racial capitalism” exhibits a tension between the term’s evocative power and its conceptual imprecision. This article navigates this tension by developing the mid-level concept of “capitalist racialization,” which specifies the role of capitalist abstractions in the construction of racial hierarchies. I elaborate this notion around the racialization of Chinese migration in nineteenth-century Southeast Asia. I focalize the figure of the “Chinese colonist” as an index of the capitalist standards by which British observers ordered colonial populations in their reflections on imperial political economy. I argue that the racial stereotype of “the Chinese” as commercial, industrious, and “colonizing” people emerged from the subsumption of colonial land and labor under capital. Their “colonizing” capacity rendered Chinese migrants simultaneously an economic asset to the British Empire and a potential threat to the white world order. “Capitalist racialization” therefore highlights new inroads into the entwined histories of capitalism, racism, and empire.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

INTRODUCTION

The last decade has witnessed an explosion of scholarly interest in “racial capitalism” across the social sciences and humanities. Predictably, such wide-ranging appeal has raised doubts about conceptual rigor. Critics have queried whether one can discern a coherent understanding of “racial capitalism” across its manifold deployments and what is captured by the conjunction of “race” and “capitalism” that eludes the grasp of either concept taken in isolation (Go Reference Go2021; Hall Reference Hall2022; Omstedt Reference Omstedt2021; Ralph and Singhal Reference Ralph and Singhal2019; Subrahmanyam Reference Subrahmanyam2023; Wacquant Reference Wacquant2023b). Particularly controversial has been the oft-cited maxim that “all capitalism is racial capitalism,” leading some sceptics to question the soundness of a concept that lacks an inverse (qua “non-racial capitalism”) (Walzer Reference Walzer2020) and prompting others to dismiss the qualifier “racial” as redundant (Post Reference Post2020).Footnote 1 Even sympathetic commentators have expressed concern over the term’s imprecision, one baldly declaring, “[t]he problem is that the term racial capitalism does not refer to a ‘theory.’ … Nor does the literature offer uniform concepts or a shared conceptual apparatus” (Go Reference Go2021, 38–9). It is now clear that the disciplinary and thematic pluralism of the literature, not to mention the polysemy of “capitalism” and “race,” vitiates an exact definition of “racial capitalism.” At the same time, the latter’s generative potential has proven too obvious to abandon on account of definitional difficulties. The result has been a marked tension between theoretical innovation and conceptual clarity.

To address this tension, the present article proposes constructing mid-level concepts that mediate between “racial capitalism” as a general research agenda and historically specific configurations of capitalism and racism.Footnote 2 In this vein, the following discussion introduces the notion of “capitalist racialization.” As a mid-level concept, capitalist racialization denotes the elaboration of social difference into racial categories through civilizational hierarchies that are predicated on the dominance of capitalist social relations. The qualifier capitalist highlights the role of political economic arguments and capitalist abstractions (commodity, value, labor) in the construction of racial difference. It stresses above all how the semantic content and the ordering principle of racial hierarchies are shaped by capitalist agendas of commanding land, labor, and resources. Such mid-level concepts, I submit, promise greater explanatory traction on the “co-constitution” of racism and capitalism in their historical specificity, as “racial capitalism” itself originally did for South African apartheid’s political economy prior to its reinvention as a general concept. A key contribution of this approach is to retain and reroute, in a dialectical fashion, the theoretical energy generated by the generalization of “racial capitalism” back to the level of concrete analysis.Footnote 3

Instead of an abstract discussion, I develop this notion by examining the racialization of Chinese migration under British colonial capitalism in nineteenth-century Southeast Asia. My analysis pivots around the racial stereotype of “the Chinese” as uniquely commercial, industrious, and acquisitive people. This stereotype has widely featured in critical studies of indentured labor in the post-emancipation Caribbean (Jung Reference Jung2009; Kale Reference Kale1996; Reference Kale1998; Look Lai Reference Look Lai1993; Northrup Reference Northrup1995; Wilson Reference Wilson2004), anti-Asian racism in white settler colonies (Day Reference Day2016; Lake Reference Lake2004; Lake and Reynolds Reference Lake and Reynolds2008; Ngai Reference Ngai2021), and British colonial expansion into Southeast Asia (Bright Reference Bright, Fedorowich and Thompson2013; Look Lai Reference Look Lai, Tan and Look Lai2010; Neal Reference Neal2019).

I contend that the perceived Chinese traits of enterprise and industry explored in this scholarship were not contingent cultural attributes but indexed the priorities of British capital to extract commodifiable surplus from colonial production. These priorities surfaced in comparison of economic productivity across various ethnic groups in Southeast Asia. British colonial officials and merchants construed the purported productivity differentials between the Chinese, the Indians, and the Malays as reflecting their unequal degrees of “civilization,” thereby crafting the ideational precursors of racial classifications. The hierarchy that they projected drew much of its semantic content from the intersecting discourses of political economy and civilization and savagery. Together, these discourses informed a system of capitalist ordering, which differentiated colonial populations by coding them as unequal yet commensurable units of an imperial political economic matrix. The particularizing categories of “race,” I argue, crystallized within a totalizing theory of capitalist civilization that arbitrated colonial populations based on a logic of differentiation-in-commensurability. Colonial capitalism in Southeast Asia, in other words, was not so much racialized as racializing.

Judged by the capitalist standard of civilization, the Chinese diaspora’s perceived labor discipline and commercial acumen placed them above other non-European populations, presenting them as an ideal solution to colonial labor shortages across the British Empire. By the same token, it rendered them uncomfortably similar (if not superior) to the Europeans in their capacity for economic enterprise and competition, thereby endowing “the Chinese” with an expansionist character that anticipated the fears of an Asiatic threat to the white world order.

The resulting ambivalence, I argue, instantiated in the peculiar figure of the “Chinese colonist” that recurred in the writings of British colonial officials, merchants, and publicists. For British observers, the Chinese demographic and economic prominence in Southeast Asia was the proof of a “colonizing” capacity that the Europeans had hitherto reserved for themselves. The core of this colonizing capacity was relentless commercial energy and industrious character that drove the Chinese, much like the Europeans, to settle in distant lands and marginalize their native incumbents. Half a century before Anglo-Saxon triumphalism gave way to the trope of “white man under siege” (Lake Reference Lake2004), the ideological kernel of the “Asiatic hordes” had already been planted in the image of the “Chinese colonist.” The analysis thus suggests that even though the panic over the “yellow peril” was coded in the language of insurmountable difference, that is, race, the social logic of that threat was one of equivalence, that is, capital.

The article makes three contributions to the study of capitalism and race. First, “capitalist racialization” highlights the processual and recombinant mechanisms of racially coding social difference according to capital’s way of viewing and ordering the world. By explicating the semantic content of racial categories as an index of capitalist social relations that render these categories intelligible, capitalist racialization moves beyond an instrumental conceptualization of the race–capital nexus and illuminates its internal constitution. Second, capitalist expansion and racial stratification in Southeast Asia widen the sociohistorical aperture beyond the Atlantic settler–slave formation that continues to frame much of the scholarship on racial capitalism. The workings of capitalist racialization in an imperial economic project that explicitly rejected native dispossession and bonded labor, such as examined here, invites comparative and connected histories of capitalism, colonialism, and racism. Finally, the study’s emphasis on political economy and Enlightenment ethnography draws attention to the historically specific political languages that mediate capitalist racialization, thereby introducing an irreducible historical element to the study of racial capitalism.

In developing these arguments, the article combines an analysis of primary texts, including nineteenth-century colonial correspondence, pamphlets, and monographs, with insights from secondary literature on British imperial history, political economy, and intellectual history. Of the primary texts, the practical political theorizing of colonial officials, travelers, and publicists familiar with colonial Southeast Asia is accorded particular weight.

The article proceeds in four parts. The first section defines “capitalist racialization” and situates it in a transimperial frame of analysis. “Capitalist racialization” highlights the constitutive role of capitalist categories (labor, value, commodity) in racial stratification, critically complementing the recent theorizations of racism as a sociopolitical infrastructure of capital accumulation. The second section contextualizes the racialization of Chinese migration within British colonial capitalism in Southeast Asia, which was shaped by the nineteenth-century project of transforming Britain’s imperial peripheries into commercial agrarian satellites. This capitalist project generated various pressures and possibilities for ordering colonial populations, from which “the Chinese” emerged as a salient racial type. The third section reconstructs the commercial and expansionist attributes of this racial type from British observations on the Chinese capacity to “colonize” foreign lands. From the endorsements of Chinese migration across the empire to warnings about the ascendancy of the “yellow races,” this section traces the figure of the “Chinese colonist” and its vicissitudes across the nineteenth century. The final section returns to the discussion of capitalist racialization to interpret these observations. It shows that although the favorable comparisons of the “Chinese” to the “Malay” or the “Hindoo” ostensibly started from a priori ethno-cultural categories, the effective lines of racialization materialized in the colonial agenda of pressing land and labor into the service of commodity and capital. The article concludes on the merits of expanding the scope of analysis beyond “methodological Atlanticism” and placing the study of colonialism, capitalism, and race in a transimperial framework. The conclusion also highlights the productive potential of cross-fertilization between the study of racial capitalism and the political theory of empire.

RECONSIDERING RACIAL CAPITALISM: TOWARD A TRANSIMPERIAL FRAME

The ecumenical appeal of “racial capitalism” derives largely from Robinson’s (Reference Robinson2000) generalization of the term, which unmoored it from South African apartheid and rendered it coterminous with capitalism as such.Footnote 4 While Robinson’s intervention has inspired an outpouring of scholarship, his particular way of elaborating it has introduced its own methodological problems. Most immediately for our analysis, his civilizational critique of racism envisions an external and instrumental relationship between racism and capitalism, which bypasses their internal configuration that the notion of capitalist racialization here aims to elucidate.

Pivotal to Robinson’s generalizing move was his reconceptualization of capitalist expansion as a socially differentiating, rather than homogenizing, process. In contrast to the Eurocentric Marxist proclivity to posit capital as a universalizing force that dissolved social difference into class antagonism, Robinson recast capitalism as a project that reified ethnic, religious, and regional disparities into racial ones (Robinson Reference Robinson2000, 26). In reclaiming “race” from class reductionism, he posited “racialism” as a mode of domination that historically preceded capitalism.Footnote 5 In Black Marxism, he averred that racialism had its roots in the feudal relations of premodern Europe and stamped “European civilization” from is very beginnings (Robinson Reference Robinson2000, 2, 9, 10, 28).Footnote 6 Initially an affliction confined to medieval Europe, racialism was unleashed upon the rest of the planet by the European agents of colonial and capitalist expansion (soldiers, settlers, planters), who drew upon a pre-Columbian ideological inventory for justifying their conquest, slavery and depredation overseas.Footnote 7

The theoretical implication of viewing racialism as a feudal phenomenon with a post factum colonial career is to cast the race–capital nexus in an ultimately external and instrumental mold. On this account, while capitalism has always been racial, this racial character has little to do with capitalism’s internal dynamics and instead follows from its contingent origins in an already racialized social order. The historical and lexical priority of racialism suggests that one can grasp its ontology independent of an analysis of capitalism, whereas to invoke capitalism without racialism (“non-racial capitalism”) amounts to a category error. The analytic purchase flows one way from racialism to capitalism, thereby obscuring the “inherently racializing capacities of capitalism” (Virdee Reference Virdee2019, 9).

A corrective elucidation of the reciprocal relationship between racism and capitalism has been to conceive of racial stratification as a structuring principle of capitalist exploitation and expropriation. Du Bois (Reference Du Bois, Getachew and Pitts2022) had flagged early on the modernity of racism as a distinct system of domination conditioned by capitalism and imperialism. Contemporary scholars have expanded on this line of argument with considerable ingenuity, locating racialized difference squarely in processes of capitalist reproduction and accumulation (Burden-Stelly Reference Burden-Stelly2018; Dawson Reference Dawson2016; Fraser Reference Fraser2016; Gorup Reference Gorup2023; Issar Reference Issar2021; Jenkins and Leroy Reference Jenkins and Leroy2021; Moore Reference Moore2017; Roediger Reference Roediger2017; Singh Reference Singh2016; Virdee Reference Virdee2014).Footnote 8 Racialism in these accounts derives its theoretical significance from its indispensable sociopolitical functions under capitalism, above all, from underwriting the uneven distribution of wealth, power, vulnerability, and violence. In Melamed’s (Reference Melamed2015, 77) exemplary formulation, “antinomies of accumulation require loss, disposability, and the unequal differentiation of human value, and racism enshrines the inequalities that capitalism requires.”

While these contributions repudiate the analytic priority of racialism, they do not entirely dispense with its instrumental conceptualization.Footnote 9 Put simply, establishing racism’s enabling and justificatory functions for capitalism is necessary but not sufficient to open the black box of “racialization” itself. It does not elucidate how the concrete content and the ordering principle of racial hierarchies are structured in and through capitalist strategies for commanding land, labor, and resources. In other words, an account of the function of racial hierarchies under capitalism remains to be complemented by an account of their constitution. Addressing this lacuna requires unpacking the ways in which racialization is not only for capitalism but also of capitalism: that is, how the specific terms of classifying and racially encoding social difference derive from capital’s way of viewing and ordering the world. Capitalist racialization, as a process of differentiation-in-commensurability, sails into this gap.

The notion of capitalist racialization proposed here builds on Wolfe’s (Reference Wolfe2006, 10) definition of “racialization” as a colonial ordering principle, “an assortment of local attempts to impose classificatory grids on a variety of colonized populations, to particular though coordinated ends.” The arbitration of colonial populations for purposes of political control, social stability, and economic exploitation was the mainstay of five centuries of European imperialism. Devised to govern social multiplicities, colonial classificatory schemes variously leveraged and repurposed existing lines of differentiation or fabricated entirely new categories that called into being the objects they purported to describe—from mestizos, mulattos, and quarterons under blood quanta laws in the Americas to the brahmins, martial races, and hill tribes under the British rule in South Asia. Racism as a colonial modality of power took shape in these classificatory projects that borrowed metaphors, concepts, theories, and techniques from each other across imperial spaces. The term “racialization” captures the processual-recursive nature of this modality, offering greater room for analyzing, on the one hand, the iterations, erasures, and exaggerations of social difference in the making of racial categories, and on the other, the social conditions and political economic agendas that overdetermined them (Winant and Omi Reference Winant and Omi2014, 109–10; Wolfe Reference Wolfe2001).

By further conceptual refinement, capitalist racialization highlights the process whereby racial classificatory grids receive their semantic content and evaluative standards from the degree of subordination of social production to capital accumulation. Its key methodological premise is to grasp the colonial empire as the political and institutional framework within which capitalist relations historically developed (Ince Reference Ince2018b). This perspective focalizes the emergence of capitalist relations through imperial webs of commodities, people, and practices that connected heterogeneous sites of production into a global archipelago of accumulation. Subsuming colonial land, labor, and resources into circuits of capital often involved violently restructuring local property, exchange, and work regimes, coalescing into a global process of primitive accumulation that proceeded through settler colonialism, plantation slavery, and commercial imperialism (Ince Reference Ince2018a). What united these heterogeneous systems of production and appropriation was their mediation by the capitalist forms of commodity, labor, and value. Their integration to the world market brought ostensibly noncapitalist (i.e., unfree and/or unwaged) laboring processes, such as enslaved or peasant labor, under the abstract dynamics of surplus value extraction, thereby transforming their social character by rendering them an organic moment of capitalist valorization.Footnote 10

The same process also introduced a corresponding system of signification for categorizing and ordering different places, populations, institutions, and practices. In Quijano’s (Reference Quijano2000, 540) words, “the incorporation of such diverse and heterogeneous cultural histories into a single world dominated by Europe signified a cultural and intellectual intersubjective configuration equivalent to the articulation of all forms of labor control around capital, a configuration that established world capitalism.” Central to this configuration was the translation of social difference into deficit whereby various property and labor regimes were recoded as unequal yet commensurate units of a single evaluative matrix. The translation of societal plurality into hierarchy took place in multiple, intersecting, and shifting political languages. In the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, “civilization” and later “race” emerged as the principal ideological paradigms for ordering and judging human diversity.Footnote 11

The British Empire in this period offers a propitious context for studying the capitalist ordering of colonial difference and its civilizational and racial articulations. First, as the first “self-conscious commercial society” (Pincus Reference Pincus1998, 707), Britain was the locus classicus of the language of political economy and the correlate understanding of civilization and empire in economic terms (Armitage Reference Armitage and Armitage1998; Reference Armitage2000; Hont Reference Hont2005). By the early nineteenth century, “the British authorities defined civilization” according to a “[value] system honed over the past century as Britons shaped and were shaped by a capitalist political economy” (Holt Reference Holt1992, 76). Second, the unrivaled geographic expanse and heterogeneity of the British Empire rendered the question of governing social difference integral to the imperial economic project. Emigration to settler colonies, commercial development of tropical possessions, and imperial labor allocation all called for classificatory grids for mapping and matching empire’s subjects to political and economic ends, rendering the “[e]veryday administration of the British Empire … completely saturated with racial differentiation” (Lester, Boehme, and Mitchell Reference Lester, Boehme and Mitchell2021, 10).

The ethnographic paradigm of civilization and savagery proved critical in mediating between the discourses of political economy and race science. It did so by historicizing political economy’s universal tenets on the division of labor, market exchange, and capital accumulation into particularist and gradated categories of savage, barbarous, agricultural, and commercial societies (Berry Reference Berry1997; Pocock Reference Pocock2005; Skinner Reference Skinner1965; Reference Skinner1967). While the ethnographic paradigm reached its intellectual consummation in eighteenth-century Scottish Enlightenment stadial theory (O’Brien Reference O’Brien1997; Whelan Reference Whelan2009), it found a practical field of application in nineteenth-century colonial knowledge production, as imperial administrators, missionaries, and merchants trained the taxonomical frame of savagery and civilization on the British Empire’s non-European subjects in the Asia-Pacific (Bayly Reference Bayly, Daunton and Halpern1998; Moloney Reference Moloney2001). Over the Victorian period, the analytic nuance and fluidity of late-Enlightenment classifications yielded to more rigid and imperious assessments of the non-Europeans, inspired in part by renewed imperial confidence during Britain’s political and economic ascendancy and in part by the perceived recalcitrance of the “natives” to the empire’s civilizing mission (Cannadine Reference Cannadine2017; Hall Reference Hall2002; Mantena Reference Mantena2010; Pitts Reference Pitts2005). Especially in the latter half of the century, explanations of “savagery” and “oriental despotism” increasingly moved away from historical and environmental factors to innate and hereditary properties, and “Eurocentric institutionalism” hardened into “scientific racism” (Hobson Reference Hobson2012). As ethnographic categories increasingly came to represent inherent and immutable capacities for civilization, the capitalist standards of commodity, labor, and value that shaped their semantic and normative freight sedimented into emphatically racial hierarchies.

Following this thread, the next two sections contend that the British notions of an innate “Chinese character” grew out of the capitalist racialization of colonial populations in British Southeast Asia.Footnote 12 Before they assumed a racial valence, the attributes of industry and commercial energy that rendered the Chinese “colonizing” people were articulated in the language of civilization and savagery. These attributes sharpened the image of the industrious Chinese against the “lazy native” in the Malay Archipelago (Alatas Reference Alatas1977) and explained why “Chinese colonists” were “displacing the natives” in the region.

COLONIAL SOUTHEAST ASIA: CHINESE MIGRATION AND BRITISH EXPANSION

The favorable reputation of the Chinese among British colonial officials dated back to the eighteenth century (Allen Reference Allen2014, 333–4). However, it was Lt. William Layman’s proposal to replace Trinidad’s enslaved labor force with Chinese emigrants that set in motion a growing web of colonial exchanges through which the trope of “Chinese colonization” materialized. Motivated by the impending abolition of the slave trade and submitted to the Colonial Office in Layman Reference Layman1802, Layman’s proposal directly informed the Trinidadian experiment in 1806 (Layman Reference Layman1802; Reference Layman1807). The Trinidadian experiment failed, as did several others, but Layman’s portrayal of the Chinese as ideal colonists not only survived but flourished in the British imperial imaginary (Bischof Reference Bischof2016; Higman Reference Higman1972). In defending the singular suitability of the Chinese to colonial plantation economies, Layman drew his proof from Southeast Asia: “The Islands of Java and Luconia [Luzon] are in great measure indebted to their [Chinese] industry for the superior production of sugar, Indigo, Cotton, Coffee &c and Pulo Penang or Prince of Wales’s Island has in a short period been converted from a jungle or wood into valuable plantations of Pepper, Beetlenut, Nutmegs & other Spices, by Chinese who from the strong motive of acquiring property have been induced to colonize there” (Layman Reference Layman1802 in Look Lai Reference Look Lai1998, 24). The passage condenses several themes that will be examined later: the capitalist agenda of turning British Asia into cash crop plantations, the modern conception of colonization as the settlement and improvement of “waste” lands, and the leitmotif of industry and acquisitiveness as the driver of Chinese colonization. An investigation of these themes in colonial discourse must be prefaced by an overview of the social and economic positions of the Chinese in maritime Southeast Asia and its inflection of British colonial capitalism in the region.

Historians of Southeast Asia have drawn attention to the region’s longstanding migration patterns and the resulting demographic, economic, and geopolitical structures that conditioned European colonialism. Look Lai (Reference Look Lai, Tan and Look Lai2010, 37) reminds that “much of the seasonal and long-term migration within South and Southeast Asia was not new, and indeed its origins preceded the arrival of the West in the region by several centuries.” The infrastructure of intra-Asian migration comprised the mercantile networks stretching from China to the Indian Ocean and onward to the Red Sea, with the Nanyang (“South Sea”) and especially the Melaka Straits representing a critical trading hub and waypoint between East and South Asia (Frost Reference Frost2005; Lockard Reference Lockard2009; Reid Reference Reid1988; Reference Reid1993). “Between the 11th and the 15th century,” Lockard (Reference Lockard2013, 766) writes, “China-based private traders were among those who developed a complex maritime system, allowing many Chinese to sojourn or settle abroad.” The majority of emigrants set out as sojourners hoping to build wealth before returning home; many ended up settling permanently in Southeast Asia and forming distinct local identities like Baba and Peranakan.

Whether they settled or sojourned, the Chinese in Southeast Asia stood out by their prominence in commercial sectors, having already established trading houses in Batavia, Saigon, and Bangkok as early as the fifteenth century (Lockard Reference Lockard2013, 767). The arrival of the Europeans and the articulation of regional trade circuits with the Atlantic economy gave fresh stimulus to Chinese mercantile activity. “In response to this early regional stimulus, spontaneous Chinese migrations of traders and artisans to Thailand and the Philippines, and to Indonesia and Malaya gave rise to a Chinese middleman sector within these local economies well before the century of the industrial revolution” (Look Lai Reference Look Lai, Tan and Look Lai2010, 37). Chinese commercial ventures usually took place under the institutional umbrella of the “kongsi,” a lineage-based communal organization. In addition to their strong presence in maritime trade, the kongsi managed much of the mining and plantation operations in the region, producing the tin, gold, sugar, pepper, gambier, and rice destined for local and overseas markets. The British perceptions of Chinese business acumen and entrepreneurial energy would reflect the specialized commercial position of the Straits Chinese in Southeast Asian economies.

Chinese-managed mines and plantations employed a nominally free but structurally captive labor force recruited from China. The centerpiece of the labor regime was the “credit-ticket system,” whereby labor brokers contracted out migrant workers to local employers in return for the costs of passage. The arrangement was vital for the plantation and mining economy, given the extreme difficulty of securing cheap and reliable labor locally (Alatas Reference Alatas1977). The indentured Chinese migrants, in Trocki’s (Reference Trocki2002, 300) words, represented the “first real source of wage labor in Southeast Asia” powering the “mining and planting operations … in Malaya, Sumatra, southern Siam, Tonkin, and Borneo.” Not incidentally, the arrangement frequently descended into debt peonage. As most employers also supplied food, shelter, and opium to laborers against their wages, they could extend the term of the contract beyond its original term, minimize production costs by intensifying exploitation, and turn a profit at low price levels (Trocki Reference Trocki1999). The provenance of the fabled Chinese industriousness that would at once excite colonial planters and haunt white settlers lay in an indigenous system of debt bondage.

The economics of British expansion into Southeast Asia was proceeded by British capital’s insertion into the existing trade, migration, and production networks. The key agents of capitalist expansion were the Anglo-Indian merchant community organized in “agency houses” in Calcutta and later Singapore. In addition to finance, shipping, and trade, these agencies invested in commercial agriculture and mining ventures, articulating the economy of Southeast Asia to global circuits of capital as a primary-commodity exporting region (Cain and Hopkins Reference Cain and Hopkins2015; Chaudhuri Reference Chaudhuri1966; Webster Reference Webster1998). Crucially, the agency houses themselves did not directly own the land or recruit the labor needed to produce the commodities they exported. For productive functions, British capital depended on the intermediation of the kongsi to whom they extended credit and commissioned exports (Frost Reference Frost2005, 35–6; Trocki Reference Trocki2002, 299). The same British merchant interests also nudged the East India Company to extend its political clout across the Melaka Straits (Webster Reference Webster1998, 127–8, 154–5, 259). The decisive moments were the establishment of Singapore in 1819 as a free British port and the consolidation of the British Straits Settlements in 1826, giving merchant capital a territorial foothold in the region.Footnote 13

The Straits Settlements in the 1830s and 1840s formed the stage where the scattered though consonant remarks about Chinese industry and enterprise that had been circulating in colonial papers and correspondence coalesced into a coherent notion of the “Chinese character.” Like Layman, figures active in the construction and dissemination of this notion through the print medium were colonial officials, merchants, missionaries, and travelers with direct experience of the Southeast Asian contact zone. Their self-avowed regional expertise gave their representations of the Chinese character an air of objectivity, while couching their arguments in the Victorian language of civilization rendered the knowledge of the exotic intelligible to their metropolitan audiences. Crucially, as Bischoff (Reference Bischof2016, 143) and Neal (Reference Neal2019, 24) and have argued, these figures increasingly distinguished between the Manchu state established by nomadic northern invaders and the authentic Han Chinese. The Chinese state/society distinction enabled ethnographers like Crawfurd (Reference Crawfurd1820, 169, 185–6) to represent the Straits Chinese as manifesting the true Chinese character that came into its own under British institutions. The combination of British rule and Chinese enterprise in turn evolved into an “Anglo-Chinese model” that administrators hoped to transplant across the British Empire, from Assam to Ceylon to Australia (Liu Reference Liu2020; Neal Reference Neal2019; Sharma Reference Sharma2009). The Chinese diaspora was thereby released from the odium oriental despotism and stagnation that came to epitomize mainland China in nineteenth-century European narratives of progress (Blue Reference Blue, Brook and Blue1999a).

The transvaluation of the Chinese character into a commercial, energetic, and relentless type, however, would eventually render it much more menacing in the Western imaginary than other allegedly less civilized and more pusillanimous Asian peoples. Once again, the dynamics of imperial political economy, and especially the transformation of Britain’s settler colonies, provide a useful perspective for assessing the ambivalence of the Chinese stereotype. In the early-nineteenth century, high land/labor ratios and high wages in settler colonies were the bane of colonial capitalists who decried the expense and irregularity of labor supply. In this context, many observers looked favorably upon Chinese migration as a solution to the colonial labor problem, not only in the tropical plantation belt but also in the temperate zone. Even a stalwart of white settler colonization such as Edward Gibbon Wakefield eventually conceded to importing Chinese indentured labor into Australia and New Zealand (Prichard Reference Prichard1968, 67), thus upholding the priority of low wages over racial homogeneity in the colonies. However, the “Chinese solution” would morph into the “Chinese question” in the last third of the century when massive British emigration to settler colonies and the consolidation of “settler capitalist” economies tightened competition in colonial land and labor markets (Beilharz and Cox Reference Beilharz and Cox2007; Denoon Reference Denoon1983; McMichael Reference McMichael1984).Footnote 14 Against this backdrop, the perceived industry and enterprise of the Chinese migrant turned from an asset to the empire into a threat to the colonists, engendering racially inflected arguments on Chinese economic competition that would feed into the panic over the “yellow peril.”

THE “CHINESE COLONIST”: FROM IMPERIAL PANACEA TO IMMIGRATION PANIC

By the time Layman revised his 1802 memorandum into a publication in 1807, he could draw for empirical evidence on a growing body of writings by diplomats, naval officers, and colonial administrators who served in Southeast Asia. In Batavia, “every manufacture is managed by the Chinese,” remarked one observer, “what land is tilled is owing to the industry and perseverance of the Chinese who are settled there.” Commenting on Java, another wrote, “These people are skilled in almost every handicraft business, carry on an extensive commerce, cultivate the sugar cane, coffee, and indigo” (Layman Reference Layman1807, 24, 25). William Marsden, the Company secretary in Bencoolen, noted the failure of sugar cultivation there until the work was delegated to Chinese superintendents, while George Leith, the Lt. Governor of Penang, admitted that “without them [the Chinese] it [Penang] would have little or no cultivation” (Layman Reference Layman1807, 25, 30). The consensus was unambiguous. The Chinese had transformed the tropical wastes of the Malay Archipelago into commercially valuable settlements, thanks to a deep-seated “hope of gain” and “temperance and regular manner of living” (Layman Reference Layman1807, 23, 25, 30, 61). Layman’s (Reference Layman1807, 79–80) proposal to adopt the “system of the East in the West Indies” by “the introduction of Chinese colonists” thus grew directly out of the Southeast Asian commercial and migratory patterns outlined earlier.

Layman’s routine reference to the Chinese in Southeast Asia as “colonists” was neither fortuitous nor anomalous, though it might puzzle the contemporary scholarship’s habitual equation of “colonization” with white settler colonialism (Arneil Reference Arneil2023). In fact, many nineteenth-century commentators invoked “colonization” to describe Chinese settlement overseas. To unravel this puzzle, one has to cut through the layered semantic composition of the term in nineteenth-century British political discourse.

The modern understanding of colonization had its roots in the seventeenth-century notion of settlement and agricultural “improvement” of sparsely populated lands, as famously codified by John Locke’s theory of property (Tully Reference Tully1993). This hard core of the definition endured into the nineteenth century but accrued two additional thematic layers based on the historical experience of colonialism and capitalism. First, the record of American and Australian settler colonialism added to the conceptual definition of colonization the extirpation or extreme marginalization of native inhabitants of colonized territories. The demographic replacement or resilience of the indigenous peoples would give rise to the discourse of the “dying races” (Brantlinger Reference Brantlinger2003) and the influential if fraught distinction between “colony” and “dependency” (Bell Reference Bell2016, 32–47). Second, the consolidation of capitalist relations in Britain, along with the newfound aspiration to become the “workshop of the world,” redefined colonization proper as not only settlement and cultivation but export-oriented commercial agriculture. Colonial reformers like Wakefield and Charles Buller pressed for the active creation a capitalist division of labor in Australia and New Zealand, while Indian reformers like Crawfurd and James Silk Buckingham stretched the definition of colonization to encompass the export of British capital and capitalists to India (Ince Reference Ince2022). Albeit from different angles, both positions pursued the colonial capitalist agenda of “the great specialization” (Findlay and O’Rourke Reference Findlay and O’Rourke2009, 365–428), namely, transforming empire’s peripheries into specialized pools of raw materials and foodstuffs to feed the industrializing metropole. In these visions, the term “colonization” occupied the center of a powerful semantic constellation comprising settlement, improvement, commerce, and capital.

The perceived alignment of the Straits Chinese with this constellation cast them as quintessential colonists in nineteenth-century British colonial discourse. Particularly illustrative are the arguments of colonial administrator-historians like Stamford Raffles, the founder of colonial Singapore, and Crawfurd, the colony’s second resident. Both Raffles and Crawfurd openly analogized the Chinese in Southeast Asia to the European colonists in North America. Under the liberal British rule, Raffles averred in 1823, “Borneo and the Eastern Islands may become to China what America is already to the nations of Europe. The superabundant and overflowing population of China affords an almost inexhaustible source of colonization, while the new and fertile soil of these Islands offers the means of immediate and plentiful subsistence to any numbers who may settle in them” (quoted in Neal Reference Neal2019, 40).Footnote 15 Crawfurd emphatically grounded the parallel in the political economy of colonization. In an 1833 essay, he wrote “[t]he sugar manufacture of Siam, of Cochin China and Tonquin, of Java, and of the Philippines, is entirely conducted by the Chinese colonists of those countries. … The natives of these countries furnish nothing by cheap labour. The Chinese supply the place of the European colonists in America;—the natives, the place of the negroes of the west, without stripes or bondage” (Crawfurd and Thompson Reference Crawfurd and Thompson1833, 251–2). Central to Crawfurd’s analogy was his assignment of the Chinese to an advanced position in the stadial schema of savagery and civilization, which had placed them ahead of other peoples of South and Southeast Asia (Crawfurd Reference Crawfurd1830, 390; also see Bischof Reference Bischof2016). Their status exempted them from the paternalism that colonial officials, and indeed Crawfurd himself, readily reserved for the Malays or the Indians. In a memorandum to the Colonial Land and Emigration Committee in 1843, Crawfurd advised that the “Chinese colonists” to be recruited to the West Indies “must be treated with the same consideration as any class of British labourers … must be paid the full value of their labour … [and] must be left at perfect liberty” (in Look Lai Reference Look Lai1998, 54).

The concatenation of colonization with commerce, industry, and civilization also surfaced in the correspondence of James White, a labor recruitment agent for British Guiana, who “consider[ed] the Chinese as being very superior to the Bengalese in every point of view with reference to colonization.” Like others, White took his cue from the Straits Settlements. “Of the three races who form the principal inhabitants of Singapore,” he reported in 1851, “the Chinese are the most numerous, and are beyond all comparison the most laborious and industrious. They are here the pioneers of civilization … I think it very probable that in time they will, by their superior industry and energy, entirely displace the other races” (quoted in Neal Reference Neal2019, 141). White’s report is notable for insinuating the trope of indigenous displacement into the conception of Chinese colonization, thus leveling it fully with the understanding of European settler colonialism elsewhere. It also indicates the shifting modes of theorizing social difference in the mid-nineteenth century, when the relatively fluid ethnographic categories of Scottish social theory began hardening into theories of race war and racial extinction (Barder Reference Barder2021; Brantlinger Reference Brantlinger2003).

White would not be the last to view Southeast Asia as the testing grounds of the Chinese capacity to colonize and displace. John Bowring, free trader and erstwhile governor of Hong Kong, struck a similar note in his autobiography when he reminisced about his 1849 visit to Singapore. Though not employing the language of scientific racism, his depiction of the population dynamics in the region forecast an impending race war. “Immigration of the black-haired races is changing the whole character of society, the Indian Archipelago being the field where the battle of the nationalities is constantly fought, and where the expulsion of the less civilised by the more civilised may be studied” (Bowring Reference Bowring1877, 213–4). In Bowring’s estimation, the Chinese were commercially and demographically dominating the Archipelago because they were “far more industrious and economical, and with far more temperate habits than their predecessors.” Second only to the English, their ascendancy reflected the maxim that “in proportion to the civilization is the growth of wealth and influence” (Bowring Reference Bowring1877, 214). Echoing Bowring, Meadows ([1856] Reference Meadows2015, 41), British Sinologist and diplomat to Hong Kong and Shanghai, observed that “by force of superior moral civilization and industrial energy, [the Chinese] are gradually ousting the savage Malays from the Indian Archipelago.” Such statements are significant for encapsulating the nineteenth-century opinion that national power and civilizational superiority manifested itself not only or even primarily in martial prowess but in the capacity for commercial and industrial development. Over the course of the century, the idea of historical progress assumed distinctly capitalist standards (Bowden Reference Bowden, Bowden and Seabrooke2007), giving shape to civilizational hierarchies that would eventually be essentialized by scientific racism.

The scientific racist and conservative thinker Arthur de Gobineau’s writings opens a brighter window to the association of capitalism and civilization, not least because Gobineau despised this association as a feature of the Chinese racial character. Drawing an explicit parallel between the Chinese and the Swiss, he wrote, “[Chinese] religion is a résumé of practices and maxims strongly reminiscent of what the moralists of Geneva and their educational books are pleased to recommend as the nec plus ultra of the good: economy, moderation, prudence, the art of making a profit and never a loss” (quoted in Blue Reference Blue1999b, 109–10). Gobineau’s disdain of commercial character led him to avow what other thinkers mostly intimated, namely that the Chinese and the modern Europeans were alike in their commercial disposition. Such social affinity underpinned the aforementioned analogy between the Chinese and the Europeans as colonists, but it also complicated the claims about the Europeans’ civilizational and racial superiority over the Asiatic races.Footnote 16

The second notable point in Gobineau’s position is the racialization of Chinese traits such that they remained constant irrespective of social context. “Chinaman, though far from his native land, has become the object of horror and fear in all these countries because people do not know how to answer the industry, application, persistence, and, ultimately, the unparalleled cheapness of his labor” (Gobineau Reference Gobineau and Biddiss1971, 242). The idea of unvarying character traits implicit in this passage contrasted with eighteenth-century theories of national character as a function of environmental and institutional variation (Sebastiani Reference Sebastiani2013). As Blue (Reference Blue, Brook and Blue1999a, 91) notes, while the antiquity of the Chinese civilization was a fixture of eighteenth-century European thought, China could still find a place in the universalist stadial theory that located it at the agrarian stage of historical development. The Chinese state/society distinction that emerged in the Southeast Asian contact zone opened the way for the decontextualization and racialization of the features of “the Chinaman.” The perceived resilience of Chinese skill, enterprise, and industry exhibited in as diverse places as Penang, Siam, Australia, Calcutta, and California bore witness to an immutable, racial character.

These thematic threads entwined in the writings of Henry Charles Pearson, British-born Australian settler, historian, and politician. Pearson made a name for himself with his National Life and Character (Pearson [1893] Reference Pearson1915), which shook the public opinion in settler colonies around the Pacific rim. The book is often cited as the ideological manifesto of defensive white supremacy, a wake-up call for closing white ranks against the Asian hordes (Lake Reference Lake, Burton and Hofmeyr2014). Much has been made of Pearson’s ([1893] Reference Pearson1915, 89–90) disquieting premonition that “The day will come, and perhaps is not far distant, when the European observer will look round to see the globe girdled with a continuous zone of black and yellow races, no longer too weak for aggression or under tutelage, but independent, or practically so, in government, monopolising the trade of their own regions, and circumscribing the industry of the Europeans.” Less attention has been paid to the rationale behind this prognosis, especially as regards the “yellow races.” A closer look reveals all the ideological antecedents examined so far to converge in Pearson’s work, disclosing the more complicated lineage of National Life’s main argument.

First, Pearson supported his observations about the impending Chinese expansion with reference to the Straits Settlements. “The history of our Straits Settlements will afford a familiar instance how the Chinese are spreading. They already form half the population predominating in Singapore and Perak, and the best observers are agreed that the Malay cannot hold his own against them. They are beginning to settle in Borneo and Sumatra, and they are supplanting the natives in some of the small islands of the Pacific, such as Hawaii” (Pearson [1893] Reference Pearson1915, 50). The leitmotif of indigenous elimination was thus integral to Pearson’s depiction of Chinese settlement. After noting that the “natives are giving way to the Chinese in the Malay Peninsula,” he surmised that the Chinese in Borneo “may not destroy the early settlers, but they will reduce them to the position of the Hill tribes in India, or of the Ainos in Japan” (Pearson [1893] Reference Pearson1915, 51).

Second, that demographic inundation and racial replacement was driven by a socioeconomic thrust was also evident. Southeast Asia attracted the Chinese “because the circumstances are specially favourable: administrations guided by commercial principles, and population too weak to resist immigration” (Pearson [1893] Reference Pearson1915, 53). It was not difficult to divine that the commercial principles of white settler colonies similarly attracted the Chinese. As for the relative strength of contending races, the Chinese had the economic upper hand over the Europeans. “No one in California or Australia, where the effects of Chinese competition have been studied, has, I believe, the smallest doubt that Chinese labourers, if allowed to come in freely, could starve all the white men in either country out of it, or force them to submit to harder work and a much lower standard of wages” (Pearson [1893] Reference Pearson1915, 132). The competitive edge was not only the cheapness of Chinese laborers (which they had in common with Indian laborers) but their commercial energy and potential for industrial development. Echoing Bowring’s argument about the economic basis of geopolitical power, Pearson wrote, “[t]he military aggrandisement of the [Chinese] Empire, which would provoke general resistance, is, in fact, less to be dreaded than its industrial growth, which other nations will be, to some extent, interested in maintaining” (Pearson [1893] Reference Pearson1915, 141). When the Chinese “have borrowed the science of Europe, and developed their still virgin worlds, the pressure of their competition upon the white man will be irresistible” (Pearson [1893] Reference Pearson1915, 137).

Since Western economic superiority could no longer be presumed, the bulwark against Chinese expansion had to be political in nature and defensive in posture. Pearson’s example came from his adopted homeland. “Nothing but the vigilant opposition of the Australian democracies has kept the Chinese from becoming a power on that more remote continent” (Pearson [1893] Reference Pearson1915, 53; cf. Meadows Reference Meadows2015, 41). The anti-Asian exclusion acts around the Pacific rim might have given the “white man under siege” provisional respite, but they also signaled a major loss of faith in nineteenth-century Anglo-Saxon triumphalism that had confidently claimed for the Anglo-Saxon race the exclusive capacity of “making and taking worlds” (Bell Reference Bell, Moyn and Sartori2013; Reference Bell2016, 182–210). Notwithstanding the popular iconography of barbarous hordes, the fear of the Chinese grew out of their purported ability to outcompete the Europeans in their own game of commerce and industry. Even though the perceived existential threat was coded in the language of insurmountable difference, that is, race, the social logic of that threat was one of equivalence, that is, capital.

“ONE CHINESE THAN TWO COOLIES”: CAPITALIST RACIALIZATION

Grasping the Chinese stereotype as an outcome of capitalist racialization reveals the particularizing thrust of racialism to be continuous, rather than at odds with the universal horizon of capital. A key theoretical insight here comes from Sartori’s (Reference Sartori2014; Reference Sartori2021) investigations into the embeddedness of political languages in historically determinate socioeconomic formations that furnish those languages with the grounds of their circulation and resonance. Of special import here is the discourse of political economy, understood as at once the self-styled science of commercial society and a language of imperial administration (Travers Reference Travers and Kelly2009), which found its conditions of possibility in the generalization of the capitalist forms of commodity, value, and abstract labor. On this account, abstract political economic categories applied to colonial social practices were not entirely alien impositions but corresponded to the existing or emergent “real abstractions” generated by capitalist social relations. “If political economy has emerged into epistemic significance in different places at different points in time, then it might well serve as an index of a much broader set of practical transformations in the constitution of collective life” (Sartori Reference Sartori2021, 3).

The epistemic significance of political economy in Southeast Asia has been extensively demonstrated by Quilty’s (Reference Quilty2001) study of British colonial arguments on land, labor, population, trade, money, taxation, colonization, and improvement. I argue that political economic concepts lent themselves to reflecting on Southeast Asian societies in part because of the ongoing transformation of social and economic life in the region with the advent of Dutch and then British colonial capitalism. It has already been noted that the subsumption of the preexisting production, labor, and commodity networks into global circuits of capital effected a major change in the character of these networks: acceleration of commodity production, consolidation of a regime of migrant wage labor, diversion of land to plantations and mines, and the pressures of merchant capital on the regional economy. With the generalization of commodity production and wage labor in an increasingly export-oriented economy, one would expect the value form and abstract labor time to increasingly mediate relations of social interdependence. While it is impossible to conclusively demonstrate this point in the span of an article, the recurrence of an abstract labor calculus in colonial writings on Southeast Asia allows for a symptomatic identification of the capitalist abstractions that shaped racial categories.

An early indication of this social and conceptual transformation can be found in the controversy over the labor force of the Company’s Bencoolen factory. In 1786, Calcutta’s concern with the expense of maintaining slaves there “prompted a proposal to sell these slaves at public auction and then hire them back as “coolies” because such a measure would allow the company to “pay ‘for real Labour only’” (Allen Reference Allen2014, 338). During his brief reign in Java, Raffles would observe with disapproval the “liberal allowance” lavished on slaves by their Dutch masters and suggest the economy of freeing the slaves immediately and “paying the local coolies more” (Allen Reference Allen2014, 338). In these proposals, one can see the equation of “real labor” to wage-labor (“paid labor”), even though the wage relation was mediated by local forms of indenture (“coolies”) (cf. Banaji Reference Banaji2003). From the perspective of merchant capital, the measure of “real labor” emerged by its abstraction from its bearer and his concrete needs and by rendering the reproduction of the laborer conditional upon his profitable employment.

A second expression of the value form in mapping colonial Southeast Asia took the form of comparing and ranking different populations based on their average labor productivities. These comparisons were formulated with varying degrees of theoretical sophistication. Cruder accounts attached differences in labor productivity to physical strength and work habits; more rarefied explanations referred to division of labor, skill, and civilization. The common assumption, however, remained the commensurability of laborers with different regional and ethnic backgrounds based on abstract labor time, allowing the crude and the refined judgments alike to strike numerical ratios between these groups’ relative economic values. In these comparisons, the workings of capitalist racialization (qua differentiation-in-commensurability) crystallize with remarkable clarity.

Gordon Forbes Davidson, an Australian settler and planter who unsuccessfully attempted to recruit Chinese laborers in the 1840s, advised against the allure of cheap labor pools in India. “Many gentlemen have turned their attention to Bengal for a supply of labour. The men procurable from that country, are not equal in physical strength to the Chinamen, nor are they to be had for lower pay. I had six Bengal Coolies in my employ in the Bush, and have no hesitation in saying, that three China-men would have done their work” (Davidson Reference Davidson1846, 205). In an 1854 article published in Trinidad’s Royal Gazette, Trinidadian planters struck the same ratio when they declared that they would “rather have one Chinese than two Coolies, as they consider their physical strength greater” (Lee‐Loy Reference Lee‐Loy2003, 211). James White, whom we encountered earlier, followed suit. “They [the Chinese] are hardworking and industrious; and in physical ability for labour, and the endurance of toil, I should consider one Chinese equal to two of the inhabitants of Bengal” (quoted in Neal Reference Neal2019, 141). In his report to British Guiana’s governor, White quantified the superiority of Chinese labor by conveying an account he had read in the liberal Calcutta paper, Bengal Hurkaru. While a little convoluted, the passage is worth quoting at length:

“[A local planter] employed a number of labourers from different parts of the country, Bengalees, Dangars, and Chamars, in addition to whom he had a gang of 20 Chinese. The rate at which each of these classes were employed was Rs 2.12 per month to the Bengalees, Rs 2 to the Dangars, and Rs 4 to the Chamars, the Chinese being engaged at Rs 8 each…. he began to make comparisons, the land and labour generally that was allotted to each being precisely similar; and the result showed more exactly than he could have well conceived that the Dangars did as much as 2 Bengalees, the Chamars equal to the Dangars, and the Chinese overran 2 Chamars; the result fully proving the greater economy of the higher paid [Chinese] labourer, his 8 rupees a month being equivalent to 12 rupees to the Dangars, or 38 rupees to the Bengalee” (quoted in Kale Reference Kale and van der Veer1995, 79–80).

White’s account is notable for several reasons. The first is the a priori classification of laborers by caste (Dhangar, Chamar), region (Bengali), and racial identity (Chinese) and the presumed validity of these categories irrespective of social context. The second is the systematic method of uncovering labor productivities by holding everything but the identity of the laborer constant, thereby explaining variation in output exclusively by the laborer’s inherent qualities. The third is the designation of the market as the medium in which one uncovers the essential knowledge about each category of laborer, as it is the interplay of wages and output that enables the measurement and comparison of unit labor productivity across diverse groups. Even if the story is apocryphal, White’s citation of it to advocate the superiority of the Chinese over other colonial groups signals credence in the ability of these categories to capture something essential about these groups that can be objectively revealed, verified, and quantified through the market. The upshot is the lexical weight of capitalist abstractions in establishing the essential characteristics of differentiating categories. Although ethnic and caste identities are the ostensible starting point of analysis, the concrete determination of these categories is revealed post factum as a function of their position in an abstract matrix of average labor productivities. In other words, the substantive elaboration of social difference into proto-racial qualities follows the universalizing logic of capital, rather than deviates from it.

Crawfurd’s writings on political economy and ethnography offer an even clearer illustration of the logic of capitalist racialization (Ince Reference Ince2022). Crawfurd, too, viewed differential wages paid to various colonial groups for the same work as reflecting differential labor productivities. The real sources of enhancing productivity were the division of labor, labor-saving technology, and economies of scale. Continuous with the Scottish theory of commercial society, Crawfurd (himself a Scot trained at the University of Edinburgh) predicated civilizational progress on the attainment of these forms of socioeconomic organization. The resulting productivity gains to labor were captured by what he called “skill.” High value-added commodities, Crawfurd wrote, “cannot be produced in any perfection considerable civilization, or which is one and the same thing, considerable skill and ingenuity” (Crawfurd and Thompson Reference Crawfurd and Thompson1833, 251). The laborer’s “skill” thus gauged the civilizational standing of the society to which he belonged, creating a correspondence between individual and collective indicators of development.

Collectively, Chinese preeminence in Southeast Asian plantation agriculture, mining, and commerce indicated their civilizational superiority over the Indians and the Malays. Individually, the effects of capitalist civilization manifested in the higher wages paid to the Chinese labor for the same type of work. Crawfurd estimated the “… average value of the labour, skill, and intelligence of a Chinese to be in the proportion of three to one to those of native of the continent of India.” Accordingly, in the Straits Settlement, “the wages of other classes of inhabitants are much lower than those of the Chinese, being proportionate to the value of their labour” (Crawfurd Reference Crawfurd1834, 384–5). In his 1843 memo, he reported that “[i]n Singapore a Chinese labourer will earn as much as two natives of Coromandel, as three Bengalese, and as four Malays” (in Look Lai Reference Look Lai1998, 55). Elsewhere, he expressed his “so high an opinion of the industry, skill and capacity of consumption of the Chinese, that I consider one Chinaman equal in value to the state to two natives of the Coromandel coast and to four Malays at least” (quoted in Neal Reference Neal2019, 85).

The foregoing discussion throws into relief the modus operandi of capitalist racialization, qua differentiation-in-commensurability, whereby civilizational and racial striations derived their benchmarks from capitalist social forms. In the arc of the arguments examined earlier, one can detect the growth of particularizing categories out of the cosmopolitan framework of political economy, whereby capitalist civilization shaded from a dynamic historical process into an essentializing grid that assigned different “races” to different levels of development. The taxonomical categories of the “Chinese,” the “Hindoo,” and the “Malay” were therefore not arbitrary artifacts of a colonial will to knowledge but emerged from real abstractions of colonial capitalism at work in Southeast Asia. The capitalist standards that ranked the non-Europeans among themselves were continuous with those that ranked them below the Europeans, and it was this continuity that would eventually render the Chinese threatening to the white world order. From imperial panacea to immigration panic, one can follow the thread of capitalist racialization across the vicissitudes of the “Chinese colonist” in the nineteenth century.

CONCLUSION: COMPARATIVE AND CONNECTED HISTORIES

The arguments developed here hold broader implications for theorizing the historical articulations of capitalism, colonialism, and race. The first concerns concept formation in the study of racial capitalism, which stands to benefit from mid-level concepts that connect overarching questions about the capital–race nexus to detailed investigations of concrete social formations. In this spirit, the notion of “capitalist racialization” has reconstructed the ideological mechanism between the universal horizon of capitalist abstractions and the particularizing categories of race in the Victorian languages of political economy and ethnography. While space constraints allowed only a passing reference in the final section, this theoretical approach could potentially contribute to analyzing if, how, and to what extent other lexicons of differentiation such as caste or ethnicity in colonial and postcolonial formations have obtained their semantic content from capitalist standards (Cheng Reference Cheng2013; Chhabria 2023; Khan Reference Khan, Jenkins and Leroy2021; Koshy Reference Koshy2001; Lowe Reference Lowe, Chuh and Shimakawa2001).Footnote 17 The point of foregrounding the political economy of social stratification is not to understate other (post)colonial agendas and contingencies that have conditioned social hierarchies but instead to delineate the specifically capitalist logics that interlace them.

The second implication is the prospect of writing comparative and connected histories of capitalism and race by tracing the circulation of institutional and ideological forms across imperial connections. To revisit our historical study, European assumptions about agricultural productivity in Southeast Asia were no doubt modeled on the capitalist plantation that had assumed its defining features in the seventeenth-century Caribbean. Yet, the direction of influence was not one way. Excepting an early and brief experiment with indenture, the notion of unenslaved labor was alien to the Atlantic plantation. The inspiration for reimagining the plantation as an economic unit powered by free labor came from Asia, specifically from the Chinese-managed plantations of cash crops cultivated by indentured migrants. Layman’s proposal to adopt the “system of the East in the West Indies” or Crawfurd’s designation of the Southeast Asian plantation as the free-labor version of the American model evidences the insights to be gained from placing the Atlantic and Indo-Pacific littorals within the same analytic frame (Bowen, Mancke, and Reid Reference Bowen, Mancke and Reid2015; Hofmeyr Reference Hofmeyr2007). Although the transimperial approach sketched here has no quarrel with the attention to modalities of racial capitalism rooted in the Atlantic, it does caution against the methodological Atlanticist tendency to frame the study of racial capitalism as such with the experience of the Atlantic settler–slave complex (Jenkins and Leroy Reference Jenkins and Leroy2021; Koshy et al. Reference Koshy, Cacho, Byrd and Jefferson2022; cf. Subrahmanyam Reference Subrahmanyam2023; Wacquant Reference Wacquant2023b).

Thirdly, the construction of the Chinese as a “colonizing” people invites a reconsideration of the notion of “settler colonialism.” As a contemporary analytic, settler colonialism critically dissects nineteenth-century projects of “colonization” and their afterlives, focalizing the invasive structures of eliminativism and settler contract underwritten by a white supremacist ideology (Veracini Reference Veracini2010). The figure of the “Chinese colonist” complicates this understanding by reaffirming its invasive and eliminative aspects but historicizing its association with white supremacy. As we have seen, British observers invoked “Chinese colonization” as neither a metaphor nor a copy of an authentic (i.e., white, European, or Anglo-Saxon) original. The term instead expressed an instance of the general phenomenon of expansion and displacement driven by commercial energy. The recognition of the Chinese as an essentially colonizing (because essentially commercial and industrious) people suggests that the racial categories of settler/native could cut across the white/non-white binary.Footnote 18 Expressed in terms of political economy of race, while settler colonialism proceeded by the invention and elaboration of social difference, the terms of difference did not derive from a priori racial categories but crystallized in the colonial projects of pressing land and labor into the service of capital. Contemporary settler colonial studies, with its fixation on white supremacist eliminativism in North America and South Pacific, looks past the “Chinese colonist” in Southeast Asia and its theoretical implications for the study of race and capital (cf. Davies Reference Davies2023). Recovering this figure opens up a new window to the institutional and ideological terrain of colonial capitalism on which the hierarchies of race were configured.

Finally, the theoretical dividends of placing racial capitalism in an imperial framework do not exclusively accrue to studying racial capitalism. One scholarly field where the racial capitalism paradigm can make a timely and singular methodological contribution is the political theory of empire and imperialism (Marwah et al. Reference Marwah, Pitts, Vasko, Ince and Nichols2020). Primarily concerned with imperial ideologies of expansion and rule, this scholarship has adopted a largely culturalist perspective that views the politics of empire through the representational asymmetries between the colonizer and the colonized. Demoted, if not overlooked, in these analyses are the imperial political economic agendas that modulated the ordering of colonial difference into civilizational hierarchies (Ince Reference Ince2018b). Insofar as “racial capitalism” presents an openly materialist research agenda, preoccupied as much with economic exploitation and expropriation as with cultural degradation and political subjugation, its insights can be harnessed for theorizing the imperial context of political ideas in a socioeconomic register.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055423001260.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I would like to thank Jennifer Pitts and Andrew Sartori for their comments on an earlier draft of this article. I have presented some of the arguments advanced here in various workshops held at the University of Oxford, University of Chicago, and Johns Hopkins University. The organizers and the participants have my thanks for their time and engagement.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

The author declares no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

ETHICAL STANDARDS

The author affirms this research did not involve human subjects.

Footnotes

1 See responses by Táíwò and Bright (Reference Táíwò and Bright2020) and Virdee (Reference Virdee2021).

2 For a kindred methodological orientation, see Wacquant (Reference Wacquant2023a).

3 Two recent examples are Hall (Reference Hall2022) and Johnson (Reference Johnson2022).

4 For critical appraisals, see Al-Bulushi (Reference Al-Bulushi2022), Hudson (Reference Hudson2018), Johnson (Reference Johnson2022), Omstedt (Reference Omstedt2021) and White (Reference White2020).

5 Here, I use the “racialism” and “racism” interchangeably since the essentialization of social difference in imperial discourse (racialism) was almost always accompanied by its deployment for political and economic purposes (racism).

6 The feudal racialism thesis has since been amplified by Gilmore (Reference Gilmore, Johnson and Lubin2017; Reference Gilmore2021), Robin Kelley (Reference Kelley2000; Reference Kelley2017), and Virdee (Reference Virdee2023).

7 For an incisive critique of Robinson’s civilizational argument, see Subrahmanyam (Reference Subrahmanyam2023).

8 For an overview of the main arguments in this literature, see the note “Debating the capital-race nexus“ in the Supplementary material.

9 Critics have treated this instrumental bent under the rubric of “functionalism” (Go Reference Go2021; Johnson Reference Johnson2022).

10 For a detailed overview, see the note “Capital, race, and difference” in the Supplementary material.

11 See Sebastiani (Reference Sebastiani2013) on civilization and Barder (Reference Barder2019) on race, who nonetheless accord capitalism a perfunctory position in their analyses.

12 Neal (Reference Neal2019) convincingly demonstrates the incubation of the Chinese racial type in the British Straits Settlements. However, his analysis misses the trope of the “Chinese colonist” as the crux of anti-Asian racism and the distinctly capitalist logic behind it.

13 For a more detailed discussion, see the note “British expansion in Southeast Asia” in the Supplementary material.

14 Especially relevant here are the economic patterns of “boom, bust, and export rescue” that correlated with the fluctuating demand, tolerance, and antipathy for Chinese migrant labor (Belich Reference Belich2009, 308).

15 Even though China’s population density routinely appeared as an explanatory variable in these accounts, it was secondary to the Chinese character. Contemporaries also frequently noted India’s “teeming” population without tying it to colonization, despite substantial long- and short-term migration from South Asia to the Straits.

16 See Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1986) for a discussion.

17 For a brief summary, see the note on “capital, race, and difference” in the Supplementary material.

18 For a discussion, see the note “colonists and immigrants in the empire” in the Supplementary material.

References

REFERENCES

Alatas, Hussein. 1977. The Myth of the Lazy Native. London: F. Cass.Google Scholar
Al-Bulushi, Yousuf. 2022. “Thinking Racial Capitalism and Black Radicalism from Africa: An Intellectual Geography of Cedric Robinson’s World-System.” Geoforum 132: 252–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Richard B. 2014. “Slaves, Convicts, Abolitionism and the Global Origins of the Post-Emancipation Indentured Labor System.” Slavery & Abolition 35 (2): 328–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armitage, David. 1998. “Introduction.” In Theories of Empire, 1450-1800, ed. Armitage, David. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate.Google Scholar
Armitage, David. 2000. The Ideological Origins of the British Empire. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arneil, Barbara. 2023. “Colonialism versus Imperialism.” Political Theory, 131. https://doi.org/10.1177/00905917231193107.Google ScholarPubMed
Banaji, Jairus. 2003. “The Fictions of Free Labour: Contract, Coercion, and So-Called Unfree Labour.” Historical Materialism 11 (3): 6995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barder, Alexander D. 2019. “Scientific Racism, Race War and the Global Racial Imaginary.” Third World Quarterly 40 (2): 207–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barder, Alexander D. 2021. Global Race War: International Politics and Racial Hierarchy. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayly, Christopher. 1998. “The British and Indigenous Peoples, 1760—1860: Power, Perception, and Identity.” In Empire and Others, eds. Daunton, Michael and Halpern, Rick, 1941. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Beilharz, Peter, and Cox, Lloyd. 2007. “Review Essay: Settler Capitalism Revisited.” Thesis Eleven 88 (1): 112–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belich, James. 2009. Replenishing the Earth: The Settler Revolution and the Rise of the Anglo-World, 1783-1939. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, Duncan. 2013. “Making and Taking Worlds.” In Global Intellectual History, eds. Moyn, Samuel and Sartori, Andrew, 254–81. New York: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, Duncan. 2016. Reordering the World: Essays on Liberalism and Empire. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Berry, Christopher J. 1997. Social Theory of the Scottish Enlightenment. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
Bischof, Christopher. 2016. “Chinese Labourers, Free Blacks, and Social Engineering in the Post-Emancipation British West Indies.” Past & Present 231 (1): 129–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blue, Gregory. 1999a. “China and Western Social Thought in the Modern Period.” In China and Historical Capitalism: Genealogies of Sinological Knowledge, eds. Brook, Timothy and Blue, Gregory, 57109. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blue, Gregory. 1999b. “Gobineau on China: Race Theory, the “Yellow Peril” and the Critique of Modernity.” Journal of World History 10 (1): 93139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowden, Brett. 2007. “Civilization, Standards, and Markets.” Chapter 2 in Global Standards of Market Civilization, eds. Bowden, Brett and Seabrooke, Leonard. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bowen, Huw V., Mancke, Elizabeth, and Reid, John Graham, eds. 2015. Britain’s Oceanic Empire: Atlantic and Indian Ocean Worlds, c. 1550-1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bowring, John. 1877. Autobiographical Recollections of Sir John Bowring. London: Henry S. King & Co.Google Scholar
Brantlinger, Patrick. 2003. Dark Vanishings: Discourse on the Extinction of Primitive Races, 1800-1930. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Bright, Rachel. 2013. “Asian Migration and the British World, c.1850–c.1914.” In Empire, Migration, and Identity in the British World, eds. Fedorowich, Kent and Thompson, Andrew S., 128–49. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Burden-Stelly, Charisse. 2018. “The Capitalist Foundations of Racialization.” AAIHS. April 30. https://www.aaihs.org/the-capitalist-foundations-of-racialization/. Accessed: 15/10/2022.Google Scholar
Cain, P. J., and Hopkins, A. G.. 2015. British Imperialism: 1688-2015. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Cannadine, David. 2017. Victorious Century: The United Kingdom, 1800-1906. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Chaudhuri, K. N. 1966. “India’s Foreign Trade and the Cessation of the East India Company’s Trading Activities, 1828–40.” The Economic History Review 19 (2): 345–63.Google Scholar
Cheng, Wendy 2013. “Strategic Orientalism: Racial Capitalism and the Problem of ‘Asianness.’” African Identities 11 (2): 148–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chhabria, Sheetal. 2023. “Where Does Caste Fit in A Global History of Racial Capitalism?Historical Materialism 32 (2–3), 125.Google Scholar
Crawfurd, John. 1820. History of the Indian Archipelago. Edinburgh: Archibald Constable and Co.Google Scholar
Crawfurd, John. 1830. Journal of An Embassy from the Governor General of India to the Courts of Siam and Cochin China. London: Henry Colburn and Richard Bentley.Google Scholar
Crawfurd, John. 1834. “New South Australian Colony.” The Westminster Review 21: 441–76.Google Scholar
Crawfurd, John, and Thompson, Perronet. 1833. “Sugar Without Slavery.” The Westminster Review 19: 247–62Google Scholar
Davidson, Gordon F. 1846. Trade and Travel in the Far East. London: Madden and Malcolm.Google Scholar
Davies, Jack. 2023. “The World Turned Outside In.” Historical Materialism 32 (2–3): 197235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawson, Michael C. 2016. “Hidden in Plain Sight: A Note on Legitimation Crises and the Racial Order.” Critical Historical Studies 3 (1): 143–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, Iyko. 2016. Alien Capital: Asian Racialization and the Logic of Settler Colonial Capitalism. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Denoon, Donald. 1983. Settler Capitalism: The Dynamics of Dependent Development in the Southern Hemisphere. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Du Bois, W. E. B. 2022. “Of the Culture of White Folk.” In W.E.B. Du Bois: International Thought, eds. Getachew, Adom and Pitts, Jennifer, 36–49. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Findlay, Ronald, and O’Rourke, Kevin. 2009. Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World Economy in the Second Millennium. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fraser, Nancy. 2016. “Expropriation and Exploitation in Racialized Capitalism: A Reply to Michael Dawson.” Critical Historical Studies 3 (1): 163–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frost, Mark Ravinder. 2005. “Emporium in Imperio: Nanyang Networks and the Straits Chinese in Singapore, 1819–1914.” Journal of Southeast Asian Studies 36 (1): 2966.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilmore, Ruth Wilson. 2017. “Abolition Geography and the Problem of Innocence.” In Futures of Black Radicalism, eds. Johnson, Gaye Theresa and Lubin, Alex, 225–40. New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Gilmore, Ruth Wilson. 2021. “Geographies of Racial Capitalism.” Antipode Online (blog). https://antipodeonline.org/geographies-of-racial-capitalism/. Accessed: 10/07/2022Google Scholar
Go, Julian. 2021. “Three Tensions in the Theory of Racial Capitalism.” Sociological Theory 39 (1): 3847.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gobineau, Arthur de. 1971. Selected Political Writings, ed. Biddiss, Michael D.. London: Cape.Google Scholar
Gorup, Michael. 2023. “Not Subjects of the Market, but Subject to the Market: Capitalist Slavery as Expropriation.” Political Theory 51 (6): 981–1007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Catherine. 2002. Civilising Subjects: Metropole and Colony in the English Imagination, 1830-1867. Cambridge: Polity.Google Scholar
Hall, Catherine. 2022. “Racial Capitalism: What’s in a Name?History Workshop Journal 94: 521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Higman, B. W. 1972. “The Chinese in Trinidad, 1806-1838.” Caribbean Studies 12 (3): 2144.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Charles. 1986. “The Making of Race in Colonial Malaya: Political Economy and Racial Ideology.” Sociological Forum 1 (2): 330–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobson, John M. 2012. The Eurocentric Conception of World Politics Western International Theory, 1760-2010. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hofmeyr, Isabel. 2007. “The Black Atlantic Meets the Indian Ocean: Forging New Paradigms of Transnationalism for the Global South – Literary and Cultural Perspectives.” Social Dynamics 33 (2): 332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, Thomas. 1992. The Problem of Freedom: Race, Labor, and Politics in Jamaica and Britain, 1832 - 1938. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Hont, Istvan. 2005. Jealousy of Trade: International Competition and the Nation State in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hudson, Peter James. 2018. “Racial Capitalism and the Dark Proletariat.” Boston Review. February 20. http://bostonreview.net/forum/remake-world-slavery-racial-capitalism-and-justice/peter-james-hudson-racial-capitalism-and. Accessed: 05/03/2020Google Scholar
Ince, Onur Ulas. 2018a. “Between Equal Rights: Primitive Accumulation and Capital’s Violence.” Political Theory 46 (6): 885914.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ince, Onur Ulas. 2018b. Colonial Capitalism and the Dilemmas of Liberalism. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ince, Onur Ulas. 2022. “Deprovincializing Racial Capitalism: John Crawfurd and Settler Colonialism in India.” American Political Science Review 116 (1): 144–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Issar, Siddhant. 2021. “Theorising ‘Racial/Colonial Primitive Accumulation’: Settler Colonialism, Slavery and Racial Capitalism.” Race & Class 63 (1): 2350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenkins, Destin, and Leroy, Justin, eds. 2021. Histories of Racial Capitalism. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Johnson, David Kenneth. 2022. “Walter Rodney and the Method of Political Economy: Retrieving a Critical-Historical IPE.” Review of International Political Economy 30 (2): 421–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jung, Moon-Ho. 2009. Coolies and Cane: Race, Labor, and Sugar in the Age of Emancipation. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Kale, Madhavi. 1995. “Projecting Identities.” In Nation and Migration, ed. van der Veer, Peter, 7392. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kale, Madhavi. 1996. “‘Capital Spectacles in British Frames’: Capital, Empire and Indian Indentured Migration to the British Caribbean.” International Review of Social History 41 (4): 109–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kale, Madhavi. 1998. Fragments of Empire: Capital, Slavery, and Indian Indentured Labor Migration in the British Caribbean. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelley, Robin D. G. 2000. “Foreword.” In Black Marxism: The Making of the Black Radical Tradition, xi–xxvi. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Kelley, Robin D. G. 2017. “What Did Cedric Robinson Mean by Racial Capitalism?” Boston Review. January 12. http://bostonreview.net/race/robin-d-g-kelley-what-did-cedric-robinson-mean-racial-capitalism. Accessed: 17/03/2019.Google Scholar
Khan, Mishal. 2021. “The Indebted Among the ‘Free’: Producing Indian Labor through the Layers of Racial Capitalism.” Chapter 3 in Histories of Racial Capitalism, eds. Jenkins, Destin and Leroy, Justin. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Koshy, Susan. 2001. “Morphing Race into Ethnicity: Asian Americans and Critical Transformations of Whiteness.” Boundary 2 28 (1): 153–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koshy, Susan, Cacho, Lisa Marie, Byrd, Jodi A., and Jefferson, Brian Jordan, eds. 2022. Colonial Racial Capitalism. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Lake, Marilyn. 2004. “The White Man under Siege: New Histories of Race in the Nineteenth Century and the Advent of White Australia.” History Workshop Journal, 58: 4162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lake, Marilyn. 2014. “‘The Day Will Come’: Charles H. Pearson’s National Life and Character: A Forecast.” In Ten Books That Shaped the British Empire, eds. Burton, Antoinette and Hofmeyr, Isabel, 90111. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Lake, Marilyn, and Reynolds, Henry. 2008. Drawing the Global Colour Line: White Men’s Countries and the International Challenge of Racial Equality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Layman, William. 1802. Hints for the Cultivation of Trinidad. London: Public Record Office.Google Scholar
Layman, William. 1807. Outline of a Plan for the Better Cultivation, Security & Defence of the British West Indies. London: Black, Perry, and Kingsbury.Google Scholar
Lee‐Loy, Anne‐Marie. 2003. “‘The Chinese Are Preferred to All Others’: Nineteenth‐century Representations of the Chinese in Trinidad and British Guiana.” Asian Studies Review 27 (2): 205–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lester, Alan, Boehme, Kate, and Mitchell, Peter. 2021. Ruling the World: Freedom, Civilisation and Liberalism in the Nineteenth-Century British Empire. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, Andrew B. 2020. Tea War: A History of Capitalism in China and India. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lockard, Craig A. 2009. Southeast Asia in World History. The New Oxford World History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lockard, Craig A. 2013. “Chinese Migration and Settlement in Southeast Asia Before 1850: Making Fields From the Sea: Chinese Migration and Settlement.” History Compass 11 (9): 765–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Look Lai, Walton. 1993. Indentured Labor, Caribbean Sugar: Chinese and Indian Migrants to the British West Indies, 1838 - 1918. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Look Lai, Walton, ed. 1998. The Chinese in the West Indies, 1806-1995: A Documentary History. Kingston, Jamaica: University of the West Indies Press.Google Scholar
Look Lai, Walton. 2010. “Asian Diasporas And Tropical Migration In The Age Of Empire: A Comparative Overview.” In The Chinese in Latin America and the Caribbean, eds. Tan, Chee-Beng and Look Lai, Walton, 3363. Boston, MA: Brill.Google Scholar
Lowe, Lisa. 2001. “Epistemological Shifts: National Ontology and the New Asian Immigrant.” In Orientations: Mapping Studies in the Asian Diaspora, eds. Chuh, Kandice and Shimakawa, Karen, 267–76. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Mantena, Karuna. 2010. Alibis of Empire: Henry Maine and the Ends of Liberal Imperialism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marwah, Inder S., Pitts, Jennifer, Vasko, Timothy Bowers, Ince, Onur Ulas, and Nichols, Robert. 2020. “Empire and Its Afterlives.” Contemporary Political Theory 19 (2): 274305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMichael, Philip. 1984. Settlers and the Agrarian Question: Foundations of Capitalism in Colonial Australia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meadows, Thomas Taylor. [1856] 2015. The Chinese and Their Rebellions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melamed, Jodi. 2015. “Racial Capitalism.” Critical Ethnic Studies 1 (1): 7685.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moloney, Pat. 2001. “Savagery and Civilization: Early Victorian Notions.” New Zealand Journal of History 35 (2): 131–52.Google Scholar
Moore, Jason W. 2017. “The Capitalocene, Part I: On the Nature and Origins of Our Ecological Crisis.” The Journal of Peasant Studies 44 (3): 594630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neal, Stan. 2019. Singapore, Chinese Migration and the Making of the British Empire, 1819-67. Rochester, NY: The Boydell Press.Google Scholar
Ngai, Mae M. 2021. The Chinese Question: The Gold Rushes and Global Politics. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Northrup, David. 1995. Indentured Labor in the Age of Imperialism, 1834-1922. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
O’Brien, Karen. 1997. Narratives of Enlightenment: Cosmopolitan History from Voltaire to Gibbon. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Omstedt, Mikael. 2021. “Provincialising American Capitalism: From Universal Instance to Contingent Case.” Antipode 53 (4): 1206–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearson, Charles H. [1893] 1915. National Life and Character: A Forecast. London: MacMillan & Co.Google Scholar
Pincus, Steve. 1998. “Neither Machiavellian Moment nor Possessive Individualism: Commercial Society and the Defenders of the English Commonwealth.” The American Historical Review 103 (3): 705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pitts, Jennifer. 2005. A Turn to Empire: The Rise of Imperial Liberalism in Britain and France. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pocock, John G. A. 2005. Barbarism and Religion, Vol. 4. Barbarians, Savages and Empires. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Post, Charlie. 2020. “Beyond ‘Racial Capitalism’: Towards a Unified Theory of Capitalism and Racism.” Brooklyn Rail, October. https://brooklynrail.org/2020/10/field-notes/Beyond-Racial-Capitalism-Toward-A-Unified-Theory-of-Capitalism-and-Racial-Oppression. Accessed: 20/05/2021.Google Scholar
Prichard, Muriel F. Lloyd, ed. 1968. The Collected Works of Edward Gibbon Wakefield. Glasgow: Collins.Google Scholar
Quijano, Anibal. 2000. “Coloniality of Power, Eurocentrism, and Latin America.” Nepantla: Views from South 1 (3): 533–80.Google Scholar
Quilty, Mary. 2001. “British Economic Thought and Colonization in Southeast Asia, 1776-1850.” PhD diss. University of Sydney.Google Scholar
Ralph, Michael, and Singhal, Maya. 2019. “Racial Capitalism.” Theory and Society 48 (6): 851–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reid, Anthony. 1988. Southeast Asia in the Age of Commerce, 1450 - 1680. Volume 1: The Lands below the Winds. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Reid, Anthony. 1993. Southeast Asia in the Age of Commerce, 1450 - 1680. Volume 2: Expansion and Crisis. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Robinson, Cedric J. 2000. Black Marxism: The Making of the Black Radical Tradition. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Roediger, David R. 2017. Class, Race, and Marxism. New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Sartori, Andrew. 2014. Liberalism in Empire: An Alternative History. Oakland: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Sartori, Andrew. 2021. “Empire, Sociality, and Political Economy in Colonial Bengal.” International Journal of Asian Studies 18 (2): 173–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sebastiani, Silvia. 2013. The Scottish Enlightenment: Race, Gender, and the Limits of Progress. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sharma, Jayeeta. 2009. “‘Lazy’ Natives, Coolie Labour, and the Assam Tea Industry.” Modern Asian Studies 43 (6): 1287–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, Nikhil Pal. 2016. “On Race, Violence, and So-Called Primitive Accumulation.” Social Text 34 (3 128): 2750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. 1965. “Economics and History: The Scottish Enlightenment.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 12 (1): 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. 1967. “Natural History in the Age of Adam Smith.” Political Studies 15 (1): 3248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Subrahmanyam, Sanjay. 2023. “Revisiting ‘Racial Capitalism.” European Journal of Sociology 64 (2): 173–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Táíwò, Olúfẹ́mi O., and Bright, Liam Kofi. 2020. “A Response to Michael Walzer.” Dissent Magazine. August. https://www.dissentmagazine.org/online_articles/a-response-to-michael-walzer. Accessed: 28/08/2021Google Scholar
Travers, Robert. 2009. “British India as a Problem of Political Economy: Comparing James Steuart and Adam Smith.” Chapter 6 in Lineages of Empire: The Historical Roots of British Imperial Thought, ed. Kelly, Duncan. Oxford : Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Trocki, Carl A. 1999. Opium, Empire, and the Global Political Economy: A Study of the Asian Opium Trade, 1750-1950. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Trocki, Carl A. 2002. “Opium and the Beginnings of Chinese Capitalism in Southeast Asia.” Journal of Southeast Asian Studies 33 (2): 297314.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tully, James. 1993. An Approach to Political Philosophy: Locke in Contexts. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veracini, Lorenzo. 2010. Settler Colonialism: A Theoretical Overview. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Virdee, Satnam. 2014. Racism, Class and the Racialized Outsider. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Virdee, Satnam. 2019. “Racialized Capitalism: An Account of Its Contested Origins and Consolidation.” The Sociological Review 67 (1): 327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Virdee, Satnam. 2021. “The Longue Durée of Racialized Capitalism.” The Brooklyn Rail. February 2. https://brooklynrail.org/2021/02/field-notes/The-Longue-Dure-of-Racialized-Capitalism-A-Response-to-Charlie-Post. Accessed: 20/05/2021Google Scholar
Virdee, Satnam. 2023. “Racism and State Formation in the Age of Absolutism.” Historical Materialism 31 (2): 104–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wacquant, Loïc. 2023a. “Racial Capitalism Decoupled: A Rejoinder and Reformulation.” European Journal of Sociology 64 (2): 183–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wacquant, Loïc. 2023b. “The Trap of ‘Racial Capitalism’.” European Journal of Sociology 64 (2): 153-62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walzer, Michael. 2020. “A Note on Racial Capitalism.” Dissent Magazine. July. https://www.dissentmagazine.org/online_articles/a-note-on-racial-capitalism. Accessed: 28/08/2021.Google Scholar
Webster, Anthony. 1998. Gentlemen Capitalists: British Imperialism in South East Asia, 1770-1890. London: Tauris Academic Studies.Google Scholar
Whelan, Frederick G. 2009. Enlightenment Political Thought and Non-Western Societies: Sultans and Savages. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Hylton. 2020. “How Is Capitalism Racial? Fanon, Critical Theory and the Fetish of Antiblackness.” Social Dynamics 46 (1): 2235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Andrew R., ed. 2004. The Chinese in the Caribbean. Princeton, NJ: M. Wiener Publishers.Google Scholar
Winant, Howard, and Omi, Michael. 2014. Racial Formation in the United States. 3rd edition. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Wolfe, Patrick. 2001. “Land, Labor, and Difference: Elementary Structures of Race.” The American Historical Review 106 (3): 866905.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfe, Patrick. 2006. “Settler Colonialism and the Elimination of the Native.” Journal of Genocide Research 8 (4): 387409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Ince supplementary material

Ince supplementary material
Download Ince supplementary material(File)
File 25.6 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.