Is support for Donald Trump, Brexit, and other populist parties and movements driven by economic grievances, or are these votes the result of concerns about the nature and pace of cultural change? How can we bridge the gap between research that finds a strong association between local economic performance and aggregated support for populism, but stronger individual-level evidence of the effects of concerns related to immigration? These questions are central to understanding recent political developments in Britain and the United States, and the rise of populist movements and parties in Western Europe and further afield. They raise conceptual questions about measurement and causal inference, as well as substantive questions about the historic political consequences of major economic and policy shifts.
This article puts forward a conceptualization of the economic vote for populism, Group-Based Economics, which we test in the context of Britain's support for leaving the European Union (Brexit). Our theory draws on evidence about the potential for people to care about the economic gains and losses of groups (Mutz and Mondak Reference Mutz and Mondak1997). However, rather than focusing on economic inequalities between the rich and poor, we build on connections between sources of economic resentment and populism (Cramer Reference Cramer2016; Gest, Reny and Mayer Reference Gest, Reny and Mayer2018; Gidron and Hall Reference Gidron and Hall2017; Gest Reference Gest2016), often through forces of globalization, immigration and economic grievance (Becker, Fetzer and Novy Reference Becker, Fetzer and Novy2017; Carreras, Carreras and Bowler Reference Carreras, Carreras and Bowler2019; Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Jennings and Stoker Reference Jennings and Stoker2017; Margalit Reference Margalit2012; Pardos-Prado and Xena Reference Pardos-Prado and Xena2019). Using a novel conceptualization, we theorize about the importance of economic group-based comparisons constructed by ethnicity – the economic evaluations of ethnic minorities, and comparisons of ethnic minorities with the white population. We also extend this reasoning to group-based comparisons based on geography – contrasting the economic standing of one's local community with that of metropolitan cities. We argue that perceptions of economic gains for ‘out-groups’ (Kinder and Kam Reference Kinder and Kam2009) – particularly relative to one's ‘in-group’ – are key to understanding the basis of economic grievances. Such relative gains motivate people to vote against the status quo, in favour of causes and campaigns that advocate improving the conditions of in-groups.
Insofar as their messages appeal to group-based winners relative to losers, economic group-based assessments are especially important for levels of support for populist causes and candidates. Our argument about relative economic experiences leads to a new individual-level measure of economic perceptions. This approach is consistent with claims about both the geographic bases of populism and about race and cultural resentment. It allows direct comparison with existing measures of economic voting, attitudes towards immigration and other factors driving political behaviour.
We find support for our group-based economic voting argument, which focuses primarily on distinctions based on immigration (comparing the perceived economic gains of minorities and white Britons) and geography (contrasting the perceived economic gains of Londoners and the respondent's local community). Our analyses draw on new survey questions fielded in a large nationally representative survey, the British Election Study (BES) Internet Panel, and are supported by a research design that takes advantage of the BES panel design. The results hold when we control for prior Brexit vote choice in a previous survey wave, are not fully accounted for by attitudes about immigration, authoritarian values or national identity, and extend across income groups and strength of British identity. Our group-based economic variables outperform standard income, household- and national-level economic evaluations, and provide insight into the relevant measures of economic voting that are needed in a specification of an economic vote for Brexit that can potentially be applied more generally.
This study offers a way to bridge existing explanations for Trump voting and Brexit voting that correlates geographically with various economic indicators (for example, Adler and Ansell Reference Adler and Ansell2020; Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Fetzer Reference Fetzer2019), but typically exhibits a stronger relationship at the individual level with concerns about immigration (Clarke, Goodwin and Whiteley Reference Clarke, Goodwin and Whiteley2017; Donovan and Redlawsk Reference Donovan and Redlawsk2018; Goodwin and Milazzo Reference Goodwin and Milazzo2017; Hobolt Reference Hobolt2016; Iakhnis et al. Reference Iakhnis2018; Kaufmann Reference Kaufmann2016; Mutz Reference Mutz2018; Norris and Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2018; Schaffner, MacWilliams and Nteta Reference Schaffner, MacWilliams and Nteta2018). More fundamentally, it moves us beyond an overly simplistic divide between the economy and immigration concerns as independent explanations, and beyond a variable race approach to assessing economic and cultural explanations. Our article combines economic and in/out group-based grievances, recognizing that cultural and economic factors are interdependent. In so doing, it helps to build bridges across perspectives in the wider populism literature and foster better cross-disciplinary understanding.
Economic and racial grievances
The literature identifies three grievances that typify the campaigns of populists: (1) those concerned with the economy; (2) those stemming from race, immigration and national identity and (3) those targeted at the political system (Ivarsflaten Reference Ivarsflaten2008). However, while the way in which populists try to win votes is accepted, the relative weight of these different grievances in voting for populism is the subject of ‘a major debate about the drivers of populist appeal’ (Adler and Ansell Reference Adler and Ansell2020, 2).
Economic explanations focus on the substantial changes in economic inequality and globalization that have taken place over time. These include the consequences of deindustrialization as well as the decline of domestic manufacturing, traditional industries and jobs, out-sourcing and increases in cheaper imports. These changes have been coupled with a rise in high-tech industries and markets to which lower-skilled manual workers cannot readily gain access. Prosperity has been concentrated in major metropolitan high-skilled areas (with higher-than-average proportions of graduates and minorities) at the expense of traditional industries and areas of the country that have been ‘left behind’ (Ford and Goodwin Reference Ford and Goodwin2014). Conceived in this way, a vote for Donald Trump was – at least in part – a vote to restore American jobs and working-class status, and to revitalize parts of the country that were once the beneficiary of the manufacturing industry. Tankersley (Reference Tankersley2016) points to the importance of globalization, de-industrialization and inequalities in patterns of voting for Trump, and exposes regional and sub-regional differences between cities and suburban and rural towns.Footnote 1 Similar patterns have been observed for the Brexit vote. Support for the Leave campaign followed a geographically uneven pattern that was consistent with the impacts of the economic and social consequences of globalization (Jennings and Stoker Reference Jennings and Stoker2017). Colantone and Stanig (Reference Colantone and Stanig2018) show a relationship between support for Leave and Chinese import shocks, and Adler and Ansell (Reference Adler and Ansell2020) reveal the importance of variations in wealth, captured by housing prices, on votes to leave the European Union (EU) and also on support for Marine Le Pen in France. Fetzer (Reference Fetzer2019; Fetzer, Becker and Novy Reference Fetzer, Becker and Novy2018) finds that local variation in the outcomes of British austerity measures affected support for Leave.
However, while prior studies have demonstrated statistical relationships between localized economic variation and electoral behaviour, estimating economic effects at the individual level has been less conclusive. Surveys typically provide measures of egocentric economic conditions (the risk of losing a job, becoming unemployed, household economic circumstances) and measures of the national economy. Yet egocentric measures are unanchored in the larger context, while national performance indicators fail to capture people's perceptions about places and groups that enjoy economic prosperity and wealth, and those that have been ‘left behind’. Cramer (Reference Cramer2016), importantly, shows how local communities in parts of rural America compare perceptions of the fairness of government investment in cities (where deprivation and racial diversity is higher and where economic opportunity and prosperity also tends to be higher) with relatively smaller investments in rural towns and communities (where economic growth is weaker and economic opportunities fewer). Cramer demonstrates that people in those communities feel betrayed, as though unfair advantages paid for by their ‘tax dollars’ benefit other groups and areas. It follows that people see greater economic opportunities and gains in areas other than their own, and among some social groups in relation to their own. These perceptions drive political resentments.
Another economic explanation also points to the importance of social groups. Changes in the status of social classes and racial groups have arisen, in part, because of the changing nature of the economy over time. Hofstadter (Reference Hofstadter1967) first argued that the American radical right emerged in response to perceived drops in, and threats to, social status. Olson (Reference Olson2008, 708) described whiteness as a status in the social hierarchy, ‘a glass floor below which the white citizen could see but never fall’. Perceptions about the direction of relative economic gains and losses between groups implies a potential threat to social status, which in turn evokes feelings of hostility to out-groups (Tajfel Reference Tajfel1978; Tajfel and Turner Reference Tajfel, Turner, Austin and Worchel1979). The impacts of deindustrialization and globalization on social status loss have been especially concentrated among working-class men without college degrees (Gidron and Hall Reference Gidron and Hall2017). These individuals tend to be more anti-elitist, anti-immigrant and anti-globalization. Gest (Reference Gest2016; Gest, Reny and Mayer Reference Gest, Reny and Mayer2018) also emphasizes the role of relative social status decline among white working-class men, particularly in relation to the economic status ascendance of ethnic minorities over time.
Group-based comparisons relate to the economic- and immigration-based grievances on which populists campaign. Populism evokes ‘claims of speaking for “regular people” anxious about social, cultural and economic change that is often attributed to the presence and social ascendance of racial and ethnic minorities’ (Donovan and Redlawsk Reference Donovan and Redlawsk2018, 192). Populist appeals portray unfair economic benefits bestowed on migrants – such as access to housing, benefits, public services and jobs – and suggest that migrants benefit from unfair economic prosperity at the expense of white natives. The role of the economy and immigration become two sides of the impact of globalization, or of broader long-term social and economic change. Note that it is the perception of relative gains and losses that is crucial, and whether those relative gains and losses pass a person's threshold to motivate their political resentments or grievances. Many would strongly disagree with assertions that, across class classifications or economic sectors, minorities are afforded more (or too many) status and economic opportunities than the white native population.
If concerns about immigration are based partly on economic worries, it is methodologically difficult to separate concerns related to the economy, race, immigration and identity from possible economic sources of concern about immigration. Economic drivers of immigration sentiment and nativism arise in two distinguishable ways. The first is through economic competition, as minorities enter the workforce in greater numbers with increased migration over time and sector, which is consistent with realist inter-racial threat theory (Stephan and Renfro Reference Stephan, Renfro, Mackie and Smith2002; Stephan and Stephan Reference Stephan and Stephan1985). Pardos-Prado and Xena (Reference Pardos-Prado and Xena2019) find a link between skills-based economic competition and concerns about immigration, and Hays et al. (Reference Hays, Spoon and Lim2019) maintain that import shocks produce a broad-based response at the regional level, which is mediated through xenophobic beliefs about immigrants and translated into populist support. Another arises due to the experience of economic distress. This is demonstrated by Carreras, Carreras and Bowler (Reference Carreras, Carreras and Bowler2019), who show that long-term economic decline has led to a rise in resentment about immigration in Britain, which in turn motivated support for Brexit.
Nevertheless, the economic bases of immigration concerns are not without critique. Sniderman, Hagendoorn and Prior (Reference Sniderman, Hagendoorn and Prior2004) find that national identity, rather than economic advantage, leads to exclusionary reactions to ethnic minorities. Hainmueller and Hopkins (Reference Hainmueller and Hopkins2014) similarly conclude that the bulk of scientific evidence suggests that the primacy of identity concerns, rather than the national economic effects of immigration, fuels anti-immigration attitudes. These studies support the view that people are concerned mostly about the cultural consequences of immigration. Analysis of the 2016 US presidential election finds overwhelming evidence of the importance of immigration- and race-related concerns and prejudices at the individual level, and only weak evidence of the role of the economy, operationalized in different ways (Donovan and Redlawsk Reference Donovan and Redlawsk2018; Mutz Reference Mutz2018; Schaffner, MacWilliams and Nteta Reference Schaffner, MacWilliams and Nteta2018).Footnote 2 Norris and Inglehart (Reference Norris and Inglehart2018) discuss the predominant role of cultural threats in their explanation of populism, including in the votes for Trump and Brexit. While noting that economics had some effect on Brexit vote choice, the majority of individual-level evidence on the results of the referendum points to the dominant role of immigration concerns, alongside wider concerns about multiculturalism and cosmopolitanism (Clarke, Goodwin and Whiteley Reference Clarke, Goodwin and Whiteley2017; Goodwin and Milazzo Reference Goodwin and Milazzo2017; Hobolt Reference Hobolt2016; Iakhnis et al. Reference Iakhnis2018). As Kaufmann (Reference Kaufmann2016, Reference Kaufmann2018) surmises, ‘It's NOT the economy, stupid’.Footnote 3
Studies that focus on individual-level determinants of support for populist parties and causes tend to find that cultural drivers dominate, whereas analyses of local-level relationships reveal the importance of economic hardship and variation. One means of reconciling these contradictory findings points to an ecological fallacy: economic accounts supply strong evidence at the local level, but immigration does the bulk of explanatory work at the individual level. Another possible explanation is that local economic variation corresponds more strongly to individual-level immigration concerns due to relationships among economic experience, skills-based competition, economic and status loss, and attitudes about immigration. This means that any ‘variable race’ approach at the micro level will underestimate the indirect effects of economics. This has important implications. If economic and racial grievances are – at least in part – explained by economic inequalities, that highlights clear policy drivers and policy consequences. If such grievances are driven by racial resentment, the policy implications become targeted at the politicization of messages about race and immigration, which are concerned either with better integration or with slowing the pace of immigration.
A more promising explanation, we propose, is that voters focus less on their own economic fortunes and more on those of their communities, groups and people like themselves, and on the economic gains and relative losses of ‘out-groups’ (Kinder and Kam Reference Kinder and Kam2009). An important analytic step is therefore required. We need to measure economic conditions in a way that captures the relevant economic assessments – of groups and areas – that are argued to be important in an economic grievance explanation of populism. Specifically, an economic vote for populism should be conceptualized by a group-based economic vote.
Who gets what: group-based winners and losers
Groups provide an important way of organizing people's relevant perceptions about the economy. Voters do not only consider their own personal economic interests; they also take into account the national economy (Kinder and Kiewiet Reference Kinder and Kiewiet1981), regional economic performance (Ansolabehere, Meredith and Snowberg Reference Ansolabehere, Meredith and Snowberg2014; Pattie and Johnston Reference Pattie and Johnston1995), economic outcomes in local communities (Rogers Reference Rogers2014), and the relative gains and losses of groups. As Mutz and Mondak (Reference Mutz and Mondak1997, 286) put it, ‘private economic experience is not, by itself, politically potent’; however, ‘groups may serve as essential mediating entities, making it possible for people to politicize the economic interests of those like them without necessarily relying directly on personal economic experience’. Political decisions benefit the interests of different groups and areas; this is the very basis of political competition and representation (Thau Reference Thau2019). Groups provide a way for voters to learn about the outcomes of government policy, a means through which voters can reward or punish a government for its advocacy for or against different groups, and they provide a heuristic for wider assessments. Voters evaluate the national economy, for example, based on information on the economic experiences of people like themselves (Ansolabehere, Meredith and Snowberg Reference Ansolabehere, Meredith and Snowberg2014).
In terms of driving resentments or grievances, group-based assessments and comparisons should matter in several ways relating to in-groups and out-groups (Kinder and Kam Reference Kinder and Kam2009). Individuals may primarily care about the gains or losses of a group to which they identity (the in-group), the gains or losses of a group to which they do not belong (an out-group), and/or the relative gains and losses of an out-group relative to an in-group. Social dominance theory predicts that some people have preferences for group-based dominance and social hierarchy – a preference for group-based inequalities maintained by hierarchy-enhancing ideologies and social policies (Ho et al. Reference Ho2012; Reference Ho2015; Mutz Reference Mutz2018; Sidanius and Pratto Reference Sidanius and Pratto1999). Social dominance orientation would predict opposition to affirmative action policies, which would be viewed as giving unfair economic advantages against a dominant group, and this increases when people feel threatened (Morrison and Ybarra Reference Morrison and Ybarra2008). When a group's status is threatened, it can respond with actions that seek to promote social change that preserves the existing hierarchy (Hogg and Abrams Reference Hogg and Abrams1988).
Research on the economic sources of populism suggests that group-based resentments turn on ethnic and geographic comparisons in relation to racial and economic status (Cramer Reference Cramer2016; Gest Reference Gest2016; Gest, Reny and Mayer Reference Gest, Reny and Mayer2018; Gidron and Hall Reference Gidron and Hall2017). Central to this is the notion of relative gains and losses. ‘Because social status is based on a rank ordering, it is somewhat like a positional good, in the sense that, when many others acquire more status, the value of one's own status may decline’ (Gidron and Hall Reference Gidron and Hall2017, 66). Zero-sum thinking predicts that if people perceive that some groups have enjoyed gains, they will believe other groups have experienced losses (Bobo and Hutchings Reference Bobo and Hutchings1996; Norton and Sommers Reference Norton and Sommers2011). It follows that if people perceive minorities to be gaining economically, some are also more likely to see the white majority doing relatively worse. The same may apply to geography: if one part of the country is perceived to be doing well, other areas are doing relatively worse. Tapping perceptions of group gains or losses over time, this relative group-based focus is different from relative economic inequalities between rich and poor, or of one's own finances vs. those of the national economy (Burgoon et al. Reference Burgoon2019; Clarke, Goodwin and Whiteley Reference Clarke, Goodwin and Whiteley2017).
We consider the relative perceived gains and losses across relevant social groups. This relates to whether groups are doing better or worse than they were, rather than absolute comparisons, because we should be most interested in the relative direction of change. Such perceptions lead to politically potent resentments when voters are presented with options to revert to a previous economic and cultural status quo, epitomized in the ‘Make America Great Again’ rallying cry and the EU Leave campaign's slogan of ‘Take Back Control’. These campaigns promise change for people who have experienced losses in their cultural and economic status. They increase awareness and information, and heighten people's perceptions of the relative gains and losses of groups, priming their salience for subsequent political choices.Footnote 4
We apply these arguments and expectations to the campaign for Britain to leave the European Union (Brexit). Our argument predicts that support for Brexit will be higher if people perceive their in-group to be doing worse, when they perceive an out-group to be doing better over time, and when they perceive the out-group to be doing better relative to the in-group. Specifically, given the salience of immigration during the relevant period in British politics (Fieldhouse et al. Reference Fieldhouse2019a), we expect Leave support to be predicted by perceptions that ethnic minorities are doing better economically, and by perceptions that white British people are doing less well relative to ethnic minorities. Furthermore, following the literature, we also expect Leave support to be predicted by perceptions that Londoners are doing relatively better than people in respondents’ local communities (those outside London). We break this down into the following Group-Based Economics hypotheses.
Hypothesis 1: Negative economic assessments of a person's in-group predicts voting Leave in the EU referendum.
Hypothesis 2: Positive economic assessments of a person's out-group predicts voting Leave in the EU referendum.
Hypothesis 3: Negative economic assessments of a person's in-group relative to one's out-group predict voting Leave in the EU referendum.
Measurement and methods
We devised new survey questions which were fielded in the BES Internet Panel (Fieldhouse et al. Reference Fieldhouse2019b). The group-based economic evaluations battery was asked in Wave 11, between 24 April and 3 May 2017. Along with standard items about the state of the national economy and personal finances, respondents were asked to evaluate the financial situation of social groups. These included ‘white British people’, ‘ethnic minority immigrants’, ‘people in your local community’ and ‘people in London’. For each group, respondents assessed the group's current situation compared to that of 12 months ago with responses categories of ‘got a lot worse’, ‘got a little worse’, ‘stayed the same’, ‘got a little better’ and ‘got a lot better.’
Our primary focus is on group-based economic evaluations based on ethnicity.Footnote 5 Figure 1 shows how economic perceptions vary across in-groups and out-groups, where 0 = financial situation had ‘got a lot worse’ compared to 12 months ago, 1 = ‘got a lot better’ and 0.5 = ‘stayed the same’. The group means are presented alongside views about national and personal economies. The sample is confined to white British respondents (93 per cent of the total sample); as such, ‘white British people’ are the in-group and ‘ethnic minority immigrants’ the out-group. Figure 1 shows that, overall, respondents hold negative perceptions. The most negative assessments are assigned to the nation as a whole and to white British people (the in-group), while views of one's own economy and, critically, the immigrant out-group, are viewed more positively.
From these variables we create a relative group-based economic perceptions measure by subtracting respondents' perceptions of ethnic minorities from those of white British people. People who evaluate the out-group financial performance identically to that of the in-group receive a value of 0. Values greater than 0 indicate that the in-group has done better, and less than 0 where the out-group has done better. We also create the same comparisons for the respondent's own economic situation relative to the perceived economic situation of the out-group.
Table 1 reports the distribution of these responses (Appendix Table A1 provides details of the coding of these and other variables used in our analyses). Cells on the left-hand side compare personal financial perceptions with the ethnic minority out-group, and those on the right-hand side draw the in-group–out-group comparison. Perceptions vary widely. Most importantly, large shares of respondents evaluated the economic situation of the groups differently. If everyone assessed their own financial gains and those of the group identically, then the on-diagonal cells would sum to 100 per cent. Yet only 52 per cent assigned the same evaluations to ethnic minority immigrants as to themselves, and 58 per cent did so with respect to immigrants and ‘white British people’.
Note: cells report the percent that evaluated the groups according to the combinations of worse, same and better. Shaded cells highlight the on-diagonal values which together sum to lower than 100. Ethnic white British respondents only. N for comparison to self = 20,782; N for comparison to white British people = 20,117.
Source: Fieldhouse et al. (Reference Fieldhouse2019b).
Large shares of the population viewed one group as gaining and another losing. Fewer than 3 per cent replied that white British people and ethnic-minority immigrants were doing better. The majority believed that ethnic-minority immigrants were doing the same or better, compared to both self-ratings and ratings of white British people. Note that this is contrary to the facts, which show that ethnic minorities are doing worse.Footnote 6
Our chief dependent variable is support for Britain's exit from the EU (Brexit). We use responses to the survey item ‘If there was another referendum on EU membership, how do you think you would vote?’ taken from BES panel Wave 11 to pair with the group economic evaluations items. Those who responded that they would vote Leave are coded 1 and Remain 0.
Comparing vote preferences to group economic perceptions lends initial support to the importance of relative group evaluations. Among white British people, respondents are equally likely to say they would choose Remain as they would to opt for Leave, at 46 per cent each.Footnote 7 If we consider only white British respondents who believed the financial situation of ethnic minority out-groups had improved over the past year, then the share of Leavers increases to 56 per cent. Support for Brexit increases still more, to 68 per cent, among those in the latter group who also maintain that their own in-group of white British people had fared worse financially relative to 12 months previous. These survey marginals lend initial support to our group-based economic hypothesis (Hypothesis 3).
We use the panel structure of the data to address sources of bias owing to response endogeneity. Models include the respondent's prior vote in the EU referendum. For most respondents this comes from Wave 9 (immediately after the referendum in June 2016), but for those new to the panel in Waves 10 and 11, this variable represents the earliest available recall measure.Footnote 8 Including 2016 EU referendum vote controls for the possibility that preferences about Brexit – and corresponding beliefs about the group-based economic outcomes of Brexit – lead to perceptions of group-based gains and losses.Footnote 9 If this endogeneity were to exist, and for any bias to lead to findings that could explain our hypothesized expectations, Leave voters would need to believe that ethnic minorities were doing better and white British worse as a result of Brexit, whereas we suggest that the reverse should be the case. Also, to isolate the influence of group-based evaluations, we include standard retrospective national economic perceptions.
We include a set of additional variables to address alternative explanations. We capture immigration attitudes using answers to the question ‘Do you think that immigration undermines or enriches Britain's cultural life?’Footnote 10 This item, Anti-immigration Sentiment, controls for attitudes that could be downstream of economic evaluations of different groups and, hence, provides a strict test of our expectations. To account for general feelings of ethnic identity, models include British National Sentiment, produced by combining responses to five items (Heath et al. Reference Heath1999), as well as Authoritarianism – tapping authoritarian tendencies identified as an antecedent of intergroup threat (Altemeyer Reference Altemeyer1981; Heath, Evans and Martin Reference Heath, Evans and Martin1994). To avoid bias arising from post-treatment measurement (Montgomery, Nyhan and Torres Reference Montgomery, Nyhan and Torres2018), each of these control variables is measured in previous waves. Models also include demographic items: age, gender, education level, income. All controls are rescaled to 0–1. Table A1 provides all details and A2 the descriptive properties for each variable.
To assess the effects of group economic performance on Brexit support, we regress referendum vote intention on economic evaluations of in-groups and out-groups. Our statistical models are of the form:
where Y it is Brexit support for individual i at wave t, Y it−1 is past Brexit support in the form of reported vote asked in the post-referendum wave, and E it is i's retrospective economic perceptions measured at wave t.Footnote 11 Control variables are of two types: C ij,t−1 is a set of j cultural variables tapping immigration attitudes, authoritarianism and British national sentiment measured in previous waves, and D ik,t is a set of k demographic attributes for age, gender, education and income.
Table 2 reports the results. Model 1 is a baseline specification that examines the influence of the respondent's own personal financial situation, as commonplace. In place of personal finances, Model 2 includes perceptions of the financial situation of white British people. The coefficient is imprecisely estimated: for white Britons, perceptions of in-group economic standing – on its own – does not shape positions on Brexit. Model 3, however, implies that out-group economic perceptions do matter: those who perceive that the economic status of the out-group has improved are substantially more likely to vote Leave. Model 4 shows that this finding is robust to the inclusion of in-group perceptions, and is indeed driven primarily by out-group perceptions, rather than the relative evaluations of in-groups and out-groups (see Arel-Bundock, Blais and Dassonneville Reference Arel-Bundock, Blais and Dassonneville2020).Footnote 12 Model 5 shows that the relative measure of in-group and out-group economic evaluations is significant when modelled on its own. The negatively signed coefficient indicates that support for Leave is greater among those who report that the economic situation of white British people is worse relative to the ethnic-minority immigrant out-group. All of these effects are replicated in models that do not control for the lagged dependent variable (see Table A3).
Notes: cells report logit coefficients with standard errors in parentheses; 1 = Leave, 0 = Remain. White British respondents only. Weighted by weight_w10w11. **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05, two-tailed test
Source: Fieldhouse et al. (Reference Fieldhouse2019b).
Table 2 (Model 4) and Figure 2 demonstrate that a large part of this effect is driven by the economic evaluation of the out-group – in this case, the economic evaluations of ethnic minorities. Figure 2 summarizes the results from Table 2 using predicted probabilities. We see that when taken alone, perceptions of one's own financial situation and one's in-group have no bearing on support for Brexit. The latter non-finding suggests a failure to support Hypothesis 1. However, consistent with Hypothesis 2, Figure 2c shows that economic conditions have an impact when compiled in terms of the out-group's performance (Figure 2c). Furthermore, this effect is strongest when assessed relative to in-group performance perceptions (2D), as Hypothesis 3 predicts. We next draw further on the BES panel to assess the robustness of the results, and to examine potential extensions.
Relative Group-Based Economics and Immigration Attitudes
We take three additional steps to ensure that our group-based economics results do not merely stand in for views toward immigrants. We first examine whether relative group-based economics effects differ according to immigration attitudes. We do this by re-estimating Table 2 Model 5, conditioning the influence of perceptions of in-group–out-group economics on views of immigrants using an interaction between in-out group economic comparisons and immigration attitudes.Footnote 13 Figure 3 shows that people with high levels of animosity towards immigrants (Anti-immig = 1) tend to be more likely to support Leave (in contrast to Anti-immig = 0). More importantly, the effect of relative group-based economic perceptions holds even for those with high levels of anti-immigration sentiment. This underlines the presence of relative group-based economic voting above and beyond existing immigration attitudes.
We next analyse, using multiple waves of the BES panel, the impacts of group-based economics on immigration attitudes nearly two years later. We regress immigration attitudes measured in April 2019 (BES panel Wave 15) on Wave 11 immigration attitudes and Wave 11 relative group-based economics variables. If evaluations of group-based economic gains were fully endogenous to general views of immigrants, the former should have no effect on the latter when we control for previous views of immigrants. This, however, is not the case: coefficients are precisely estimated for self vs. out-group and for in-group vs. out-group. Perceptions of group economic standing are conceptually separate from views of immigrants (see Table A5).
We also examine possible question-order effects by randomizing our survey instrument. The concept of ethnocentrism implies that people perceive themselves to be superior to out-groups (Kinder and Kam Reference Kinder and Kam2009). This may lead people to bias their in-group evaluations, or evaluations of ‘self’ if asked to first assess the economic conditions of ‘inferior’ out-groups, akin to positive distinctiveness strategies predicted by social identity theory (Tajfel and Turner Reference Tajfel, Turner, Austin and Worchel1979). This could bias the results if people maximized in- and out-group differences in response to survey order effects. We therefore compared responses of white British respondents to the three key economic evaluation questions (self, ethnic in-group and ethnic out-group) according to whether they received the question relating to (a) self before out-group and (b) in-group before out-group. There were no significant differences in evaluations of white Britons based on question ordering (see Figure A2a). However, those asked about white Britons first scored minorities as having performed better economically than those that were asked about ethnic minorities first (Figure A2b). The differences are small on a five-point scale but are reflected in a greater negative difference score among respondents who were asked the in-group question first (Pr(T < t) = 0.9996). When we split the sample by Leave and Remain voters, we see that the relationship is driven entirely by Leave voters (see Figure A3). This negative accentuation is opposite to what might be predicted by positive distinctiveness strategies of social identity theory. However, such downplaying of one's in-group is consistent with the interpretation that negative relative economic evaluations are an expression of resentment or perceived threat. To account for these modest effects, we included question order dummy variables in our models and found no change in the results reported above (Appendix Table A6 and Figure A4).
Extensions of the Results
We replicated our analyses with two alternative dependent variables: feelings toward Brexit (higher values for ‘happy’ the UK voted to leave EU; lower values for ‘disappointed’) and a factor score produced from five items tapping populist attitudes. Models estimated using ordinary least squares are reported in Appendix Tables A7 and A8 with predictions displayed in Figures A5 and A6. The results closely align with models in Table 2 and Figure 2, and reveal that out-group and in-group perceptions contribute to these political attitudes. These findings suggest that our argument is applicable to other cases in which populism sentiment is the outcome of interest and are not driven by the hypothetical nature of EU referendum vote intention after the Brexit referendum in 2016.
We also consider whether relative group-based economics is more important among low-income respondents. Status threat and economic grievance explanations are argued to be especially relevant to lower-income groups – such as the white working class – whose prior social status had been higher and more secure (Gest Reference Gest2016; Gest, Reny and Mayer Reference Gest, Reny and Mayer2018; Gidron and Hall Reference Gidron and Hall2017). We examine whether relative group-based economics are more important to Brexit support by variation in household income. Figure 4a reports the findings, which are based on further interactions re-estimating Table 2, Model 5.Footnote 14 Those with below-average incomes (defined as the sample mean minus one standard deviation) are more likely to vote Leave relative to high incomes (mean plus one standard deviation). However, overlapping confidence intervals show that this effect is very modest. As the steep slopes for both lines show, far more important are the perceived economic gains made by minority out-groups relative to the white British in-group.
Furthermore, we re-ran our models including British identity strength to assess whether relative group-based assessments have greater weight for people with a stronger sense of Britishness. If strength of attachment to the in-group accounts for the strength of group-based voting, then the impact of relative group perceptions might be stronger as a product of the strength of in-group identity. Figure 4b shows that the effects were marginally (but not significantly) stronger for people without a strong British identity (see also Table A4). This is likely to be a compression effect (Berry, DeMeritt and Esarey Reference Berry, DeMeritt and Esarey2010) since those with a strong British identity are already highly likely to support Brexit.Footnote 15
Group-based economics: geography
If our theory is persuasive, it should extend beyond racial groups, including to groups for which evaluations do not just relate to socially dominant groups that are performing less well (that is, white British). As discussed, social dominance theory predicts that certain people have preferences for inequalities between groups, as long as dominant groups are more successful.
Geography plays a prominent role in current debates about the winners and losers in advanced capitalist societies, with urban centres gaining at the expense of rural communities. Accordingly, we replicate the analysis by comparing one's own position and the economic gains/losses of respondents' local communities (the in-group) with the economic gains and losses of those living in London (the out-group), Britain's political and financial capitol, modelling the sample excluding people living in London.
Table 3 reports the distribution of responses. Cells on the left-hand side compare personal financial perceptions with those of the Londoner out-group, and those on the right-hand side draw the in-group–out-group comparison. The majority of respondents think Londoners have fared better relative to both themselves and to people in their own communities. These differences correlate with support for Brexit. Among those perceiving their local community's economy to have improved but the London economy to have declined, 44 per cent supported Leave. By contrast, six in ten of those who viewed London's economy as faring better while their local community's had declined supported Brexit.
Note: cells report the percent who evaluate the groups according to the combinations of worse, same and better. Shaded cells highlight the on-diagonal values which together sum to lower than 100. London residents excluded. N for comparison to self = 20,782; N for comparison to people in local community = 19,035.
Table 4, Models 1–5 displays logistic regression model estimates. To better isolate the geographic differences from what may be construed as ethnic differences between London and elsewhere, we include the white British economy vs. ethnic minority difference measure from the last model in Table 2. At first blush, the results diverge from those for group effects in terms of ethnicity. The coefficient on the geographic in-group, Local Economy, is positively signed, indicating more positive in-group economic assessments among Leave supporters, rather than negative assessments, as Hypothesis 1 predicts. Model 5 shows that this persists for the local economy relative to the London economy, albeit weaker in magnitude.
Notes: cells report logit coefficients with standard errors in parentheses; 1 = Leave, 0 = Remain. White British respondents residing outside of London only. Weighted by weight_w10w11. **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05, two-tailed test.
Source: Fieldhouse et al. (Reference Fieldhouse2019b).
Table 3 may provide an explanation for these counterintuitive results. The last column in the table shows that only 7 per cent of respondents evaluated their local economy as having gotten better; of that group, fewer than 1 per cent offered ‘a lot better’. Our measures for Local Economy and its difference from London Economy are sharply skewed. We therefore re-estimate the model but create a series of dummy variables indicating whether the respondent viewed the performance of their local economy and the London economies as simply ‘better’ or ‘worse’ than 12 months previous (Table 4, Model 6). This creates four dummy variables with a reference category of ‘stay the same’ for at least one of the two groups. From these estimates, we calculate the probability of supporting Leave for each of the four combinations of perceptions. These predicted probabilities, displayed in Table 5, show that support for Leave is highest (probability 0.76) among those who view their own economy as worse but the economy of Londoners as having improved. Furthermore, views of the financial standing of the out-group – Londoners – matter more than those of the geographically proximal in-group. This finding is consistent with our relative perceptions hypothesis (Hypothesis 3).Footnote 16
Note: cells report expected probability of choosing Leave calculated from estimates in Table 4 Model 6. Expected probabilities produced by manipulating Local economy and London economy while setting all other variables in the model at mean or modal values. Brackets report 95 per cent confidence intervals.
Conclusion
The literature has been divided about the relative explanatory power of an economic vs. cultural basis for the widespread rise of populism. We demonstrate that these concepts are not entirely separable. Evaluations of economic conditions should take into account the group-based nature of economic improvements, relative assessments and resentments. If we do this, we find a combined role of economic evaluations for culturally and geographically defined groups that predicts support for populism and which also bridges a divide in the existing literature in empirically, conceptually, and theoretically useful and important ways.
We compared the importance of group-based economic assessments to the explanatory role of attitudes to immigration. We found that a group-based economic vote for Brexit plays a significant role in Brexit vote choices, and is a more useful measure of economics than ‘standard’ economic variables or a person's income, household-level economic evaluations or national-level economic evaluations. The evaluations of the out-group with respect to ethnic minorities are particularly important in driving these identified effects, but in-group assessments also play some part in this. If we are looking to identify an individual-level economic basis for support for populism, we need measures of group-based gains and losses, rather than using the standard economic voting variables. Furthermore, these effects are found net of immigration attitudes and a range of other possible confounding controls and remain statistically significant when we account for prior Brexit vote choice in a lagged panel design.
We conclude that a group-based economic vote has the potential to play an important role in explaining support for populist causes, and offers a more promising way to model the individual-level role of economics than has been used, to date, which helps to reconcile aggregate-level findings about economics with group-based measures of economics at the individual level.
Our findings prompt several new directions for consideration. The first is whether our findings are replicable in other country contexts. While we have no reason to think there is anything particular about the in-group and out-group comparisons and tendencies to form resentments based on relative economic assessments, the importance of various different group-based assessments might vary depending on other key factors in specific elections, and the political salience and public awareness and anxiety about different cultural and economic changes.
Substantively, our findings suggest new directions for conceptualizing the basis of economic voting. We have identified substantial effects of relative assessments, and the importance of group-based assessments. Researchers might also usefully consider a range of different ways and levels at which people assess the economic conditions of salient groups, especially given the group-based nature of political representation and policy making (see Thau Reference Thau2019). It is plausible that voters recognize policy appeals aimed at different groups of voters (groups they may or may not identify with) and reward or punish parties for a wider range of group-based economic outcomes than we assess here. Our focus has been on explaining resentment-based voting for populist causes, but a range of different political outcomes can be conceived on the basis of group-based economic voting.
In relation to our understanding of populism, this article offers a way to bridge and move on from the two ‘camps’ on display in prior studies – between those advocating cultural threat explanations for populism and support for populist leaders, and those highlighting the primary role of economics. We do not doubt that there are unique aspects to both, but recognizing the overlap between cultural threat and relative economic assessments offers a conceptual and theoretical advancement in understanding the focal political outcomes, and is one way to reconcile these debates.
The failure to draw more explicit links between economic experiences, immigration, race and support for populism is surprising to us in view of the extensive literature on the role of material resources in realistic-conflict theory (Sherif Reference Sherif1966), inter-group threat (Stephan and Stephan Reference Stephan and Stephan1985) and racial resentment (Kinder and Sanders Reference Kinder and Sanders1996), all of which place economic competition at the heart of intergroup conflict. In this article we found that the perception that other groups are gaining economically demonstrates a strong and substantial relationship with support for Brexit, alongside a scenario in which those groups are gaining and you (or your group) is not. Furthermore, this effect does not apply just to perceptions about ethnic-minority immigrants; it also applies to comparisons of the economic gains made in London with those of the respondent's local community.
Acknowledgements
We wish to thank to thank the editors and reviewers of the British Journal of Political Science and colleagues who gave helpful comments in seminar presentations at: Indiana University, the London School of Economics, the University of Manchester, Nuffield College – University of Oxford, the University of Montreal, the 2018 European Political Science Association annual conference and the 2018 Midwest Political Science Association annual conference.
Data availability statement
Replication data for this article can be found in Harvard Dataverse at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/WBLE7E. The British Election Study data can be downloaded via: www.britishelectionstudy.com/data.
Supplementary material
Online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123420000551.
Financial support
Data collection for this research was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council British Election Study grant, Award ES/K005294/1.