Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T17:57:36.180Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

7 - Conclusion

Towards a New Imaginary of Prosperity in the EU

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 October 2024

Marija Bartl
Affiliation:
University of Amsterdam

Summary

Social integration in European countries seems increasingly dependent on the “we” that draws on tribal markers of identity. This type of belonging, in good times flatteringly called demos, tends to resurface in its far uglier exclusionary versions when times get more difficult and resources more scarce – and at the same time, the horrors of previous wars are either forgotten or strategically rehashed. The European Union (EU), however, still has a window to change these dynamics and reorient Europe towards prosperity. For Europe, this is both a task and a necessity: the EU cannot socially integrate but via the imaginaries of prosperity, all the while it emerged with a task to prevent the excesses of tribalism.

Type
Chapter
Information
Reimagining Prosperity
Toward a New Imaginary of Law and Political Economy in the EU
, pp. 204 - 214
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2024
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NC
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

Social integration in European countries seems increasingly dependent on the “we” that draws on tribal markers of identity. This type of belonging, in good times flatteringly called demos,Footnote 1 tends to resurface in its far uglier exclusionary versions when times get more difficult and resources more scarce – and at the same time, the horrors of previous wars are either forgotten or strategically rehashed. The European Union (EU),Footnote 2 however, still has a window to change these dynamics and reorient Europe towards prosperity. For Europe, this is both a task and a necessity: the EU cannot socially integrate but via the imaginaries of prosperity, all the while it emerged with a task to prevent the excesses of tribalism.

As I have tried to show above, the EU is not limited to privatised prosperity, with consumerism and neo/ordoliberal imaginaries as the only credible route to a better future. Rather it can, and has already started to, develop a thicker understanding of shared prosperity. Such a conception of prosperity will have to be built around the recognition of interdependence, collective institutions, public values centred on sharing and inclusion, and effective problem-solving. It is, however, not a conflict-free imaginary. Rather, political mobilisation and conflict will centre around questions of political economy and its constitutive outsides,Footnote 3 as well as questions of economic (including market) structures and their distributive outcomes. The collectives that engage in such political struggles are also constructed around shared interests and values (such as farmers, workers, practically educated, social movements, millennials, etc.), rather than tribal markers.

The possibility of developing a conception of shared prosperity in the EU, as a supranational entity, may go against some received wisdom on the capacity of “interstate federation” to generate solidarity. Writing in the 1930s, Hayek, later followed by a number of other brilliant political economists,Footnote 4 suspected that an “interstate federation” would be mostly incapable of redistribution or effective regulation – making thus sure that all individuals and groups living in such a federation would be permanently consigned to privatised prosperity. But the history of the EU to date, I would argue, proves them at least partially wrong.

First, from its inception, the EU has had a mixed set of “Ideological commitments”Footnote 5, with different values and normative concerns dominating EU's policy and action in each subsequent imaginary of prosperity. For instance, in the field of consumer law and policy, discussed in Chapter 3, this played out as a focus on protection, empowering weaker parties and restructuring market dynamics and distributive outcomes in the welfare state imaginary of prosperity.Footnote 6 At a later point, the has EU embraced a neoliberal imaginary of prosperity, with its focus on market liberalisation and optimisation, making consumers the main vehicles of internal market building. Finally, privatised prosperity came to seem increasingly untenable in the face of the current challenges, with the EU institutions hesitantly moving beyond privatised prosperity and its focus on overconsumption.Footnote 7

Second, after a prolonged period of privatisation, such as that which we have seen in recent decades (or in the pre-war period in Europe for that matter), discontent will mount. These pressures could either be channelled towards the transformation of political economy (as was the case in the US or Sweden in the 1930s), or they could be channelled to tribal collectivism (as was the case in Italy, Germany, and a significant part of Europe during the same period) and is threatening to be the case in Europe today.Footnote 8

Third, given that the EU cannot easily produce a thick tribal identity, it can only respond to these collectivising pressures by transforming its imaginary of prosperity, by rearticulating the relations between the state, capital, labour, society and so forth. At the same time, by remaining within the ambit of prosperity, the EU would be (as its founders envisaged) an important force in preserving democratic institutions, knowledge governance and ultimately peace on the continent.

The success of the EU in delivering shared prosperity will require political courage, however. To start, the EU institutions cannot replace their aspirations of “knowledge governance” with fear or prejudice. There is no such thing as losing (or gaining) legitimacy with those embracing tribal logics, as there is no place for European integration worth its name in a tribal Europe. Furthermore, the EU institutions will have to be able to stand up for those pulling the short straw in the integration process – something they failed to do in 2008. In order to help institutionalise a new imaginary of shared prosperity, they will have to stand up, on the one hand, to the (well-resourced) interests of the capital, driven more by the unhealthy pressures of the financial markets than societal and long-term interests. And, on the other hand, they will also have to stand up to influential EU member states (MSs), especially when they push for paths that are clearly damaging to peripheral EU MSs (today, for instance, the new push for austerity that would decimate welfare and infrastructural investment in these countries).Footnote 9 Finally, the EU institutions will have to take rule of law issues more seriously and intervene in a timely manner. If democracy-undermining conduct continues to spread, soon there may not be sufficiently large majorities to safeguard democracy and rule of law – and we may see, again, loud minorities destroy the institutions that have at least partially delivered equality, justice, and prosperity in Europe.

7.1 Changing Background Assumptions

As this book shows, the EU has already taken the first steps towards a new imaginary of shared prosperity in Europe. Apart from macro measures such as the European Green Deal and the Next Generation Europe, the EU has made significant strides in redesigning microeconomic institutions, including consumption, technology, industrial development, and the corporation. These various policy and legislative measures, put in place over the past couple of years, depart from a different background understanding of how central elements of its political economy – law, politics, government, economy, nature and society – fit together, setting thus grounds to shift to an imaginary of political economy that would be better able to include various contemporary constitutive outsides (such as nature, care, inequality, or prosperity abroad).

In Table 7.1, I try to capture what these background shifts are. They concern the assumptions as to (a) ontology, that is, how the political economy (economy, law, politics, government, society and nature) fit together, (b) epistemology, that is what frameworks one should use in order to know and act on the political economy, and finally (c) different values, both public and intersubjective ones, that ought to ground our moral, cultural, and political intuitions. Importantly, this table captures background assumptions rather than any specific ‘policy solutions’ that aim to address the problems the EU faces. These assumptions set ground for a different way of thinking about problems and possible solutions. The actual transition to a new imaginary, however, requires more: implementing laws and policies that can deliver on material, social, and institutional fronts, while grounding a real hope in a prosperous future. On that front, the new imaginary of prosperity is only in its infancy.

Table 7.1 Modern Social Imaginaries: Background Assumptions

‘HOW DOES THE WORLD FIT TOGETHER?’‘HOW SHOULD WE KNOW AND ACT ON THE WORLD’?‘WHAT VALUES GROUND THE FUTURE’?
Privatised ProsperityShared ProsperityTribal ImaginariesPrivatised ProsperityShared ProsperityTribal ImaginariesPrivatised ProsperityShared ProsperityTribal imaginaries
ECONSelf-regulating ‘Human-nature given’‘Human-made’ institution‘Ours’PositivistConstructivistMade by native peopleSelf-interest, growthCollective action, sharingTribal interest
POLCentrality of private/corporate actorsCentrality of collective & public institutions‘Deep state’, /elitesTechnocraticPolitical + technocraticIdentity focused; we/theyTrust in private/corporate actorsTrust in democracy collective actionProtect identity, nativism
GOVSmallerBiggerServing own tribeOutsourcing, neutral arbiterCapable, deciding, redistributingDistinguishing/discriminatingService providerResponsibleChoosing sides
LAWPrivate Autonomy, Self-regulationHard law, LiabilityDisregard for the Rule of LawExogenous, ‘add on’ to social processesEndogenous Constitutive TransformativeElitist judges, the enemy of peopleFacilitative rather than interven-tionistIntervenes, shapes, transformsKeeping out
NATUREResourcesEcosystem, complexTraditional landsTechnological fixesUncertainty and risksAdaptationEfficient useCareAnti-environmentalism
SOCIETYOnly individuals, no societyPluralist and inclusive societyTraditiona-lism, nativismAggregation of preferencesSocial norms, values, trust, justiceCommunity needs, hierarchiesWe don’t owe to others, inclusiveWe owe to others, inclusiveWe owe only to the ingroup, exclusive
SELF/ SUBJECTThin subjectsThick subjects, complexReduced to a particular identity markerNarrowing of “Self” and self-interestExpanding of “Self” InterestGroup interest, the ‘real’ peopleCompeti-tive, responsibleCoopera-tiveSoldier, tribal identification

The caveat is that the table itself presents ‘ideal’ types of social imaginaries, with respect to which the shift in the EU at present may still be incomplete. As it concerns the imaginaries of prosperity, the ideal types are distilled from the empirical work behind this book, including the previous transformation of the welfare state imaginary of prosperity to the neoliberal one, as well as the slow change of the neoliberal imaginary to the present more amorphous imaginary, as read in the light of the longer history of modernity. I articulate the tribal imaginaries, in contrast, on the basis of the secondary literature (dealing with contemporary and historical matters) only, without studying them empirically. The reason is that in the context of the fields I study, I have not (and likely could not have) found them expressed in any discernible form.

On the basis of the four case studies, I submit that the EU has made at least partial shifts in all aspects of political economy that I have examined. The EU has increasingly started to recognise that the (internal) market is a gullible institution, rather than a natural self-regulating system, which thus needs more than just facilitation (via information obligations, for instance) to operate in socially useful ways.Footnote 10 What is more, if the EU wants growth, it has to be green – and green growth is always steered growth: celebrating economic activity as such will not do.Footnote 11 The transition that the EU is contemplating requires restructuring the economy, away from the production of consumer goods towards the services to maintain goods,Footnote 12 while replacing throw-away consumer culture with a more caring – that is repairing, refurbishing, and reusing – consumption.Footnote 13

This transforming imaginary of the economy hinges on the EU’s changing conception of politics. We can see that the EU starts recognising distributive conflicts to a greater degree than was the case before, with different groups struggling over the shape of the economy and its distributive outcomes – rather than being staged in a common project of optimising markets.Footnote 14

The shift in the imaginary of prosperity in the EU has also implied a shift in the role of government – the EU institutions in our case – who must assume more political responsibility going forward. The government increasingly has to choose between different products,Footnote 15 between different sectors,Footnote 16 and even between different ways of producing,Footnote 17 in order to bring about a more sustainable and equitable economy. Hiding behind (often regressive) ‘horizontal measures’ of cutting labour rights or lowering taxes in order to create a “good investment climate” will not do any longer.Footnote 18 This embrace of political responsibility from the side of the EU institutions has, however, only been partial. For instance, in industrial policy, the EU still does not impose many conditionalities, remaining in the paradigm where benefits are privatised while costs are socialised.Footnote 19 Gabor has critically called this a ‘de-risking state’ – de-risking private capital investment, without corresponding benefit on the side of the public.Footnote 20 But the EU position goes even further, I would argue: the EU seems to suffer from a certain aversion to public voice or public ownership – even though the new imaginary of prosperity will likely have to ensure that many services are provided either publicly or via some other collective route.Footnote 21

There have been changes also in the EU’s legal imaginaries. The law is becoming more clearly ‘normative’ – relying on its own normativity rather than the one borrowed from “efficient markets”, while aiming to reshape the economy rather than just optimise it.Footnote 22 In most examined fields, law is moving away from self-regulationFootnote 23 and returning to the language of protectionFootnote 24 and institutional experimentation, designing at times even new institutional and legal forms.Footnote 25 However, the issues of distributive justice and the inequality of (bargaining) power remain in very early infancy.Footnote 26

In relation to nature, we see somewhat more humility, recognising the complexity of natural ecosystems and human (inter)dependence on them. Rather than only intervening on nature, it is recognised that we need to extract less (via consumption and production)Footnote 27 and return more (via care and nature laws).Footnote 28 This is, however, not an entirely consistent position.Footnote 29

Finally, we see also the transformation of the subject. The EU is moving beyond the thin subject interested only in price and profit.Footnote 30 The subject rather has more interests and more complex rationality, they are more interdependent with their social and natural environment, and finally they carry more responsibility for others and for nature.Footnote 31 This thicker subject is also what, going forward, may ground a different conception of society, which places interdependence and sharing more centrally.Footnote 32

7.2 The Road Ahead

The shift in the background assumption sets preconditions for instituting a new, post-neoliberal society. For that to happen, however, many new struggles, new movements, new programmes, measures, policies, and laws will have to be taken up and implemented. Some of these transformations are already incipient and thus imaginable going forward. In what follows, on the basis of previous chapters, I want to propose a couple of ‘compossible futures’ that would help usher in a new imaginary of prosperity and thus, to paraphrase Acemoglu and Robinson, help the EU and its MSs to “stay in the corridor”.Footnote 33

To start, the EU is working towards making consumption both slower and less wasteful. However, the paradigm is still that of individual consumption. Public infrastructures and services (e.g. ‘European public goods’)Footnote 34 as well as via public and collective ways of consumption (including enabling forms of co-housing, sharing of consumer goods, public transport, etc.) will be a must if we indeed intend to keep the quality of life while lowering material throughput. The EU already opens up towards restructuring consumption, away from mass consumption, towards reuse, services, and repair, but it still does not venture into encouraging more public or communal forms of consumption that would be beneficial both environmentally and socially.Footnote 35 This connects to a wider problem, namely that the emergent imaginary is still a “fair weather” imaginary, more easily embraced by those who are economically and socially secure. To be truly an imaginary of shared prosperity, the new imaginary of prosperity should be increasingly thought of from the perspectives of have not’s rather than have’s – that ought to convey, I would argue, the primary meaning of GED’s ‘just transition’.

The imagination of the EU institutions also remains limited concerning the relationship between technology and labour – even if the EU sees itself as a regulatory champion.Footnote 36 Neither data legislation, industrial policy, nor ecodesign takes up the role of steering technological progress in a direction that would ensure safer labour futures. The EU remains reactive, making workers, consumers, and citizens fit for market-made technologies rather than the reverse. The EU will need to become more proactive in democratically shaping the technological futures that would actually live up to the needs of humans rather than capital.Footnote 37 The prosperous future requires a credible promise that it will not be a purposeless or dystopic future – a promise that has to be delivered via more democratic steering of technology and/or via modes of social provision (like universal basic income, citizen dividend, or work guarantee).Footnote 38

When it comes to relationships with the so-called third countries, we see two sets of developments, each pulling in a different direction. On the one hand, the EU is very carefully attempting to reign in its own multinationals from causing social and environmental harm abroad. The solidarity, however, does not go as far as to demand fairer pricing as a condition of non-extractive relations,Footnote 39 and at this point, it is also unclear whether even fair purchasing practices have made it through the last round of negotiations of the CSDDD between the EU parliament and the Council. On the other hand, within the framework of its industrial policy and the Critical Raw Materials Act, the EU remains in a competitive mode that we associate with privatised prosperity. If and when the EU actually takes the question of interdependence with “third countries” more seriously, it has to go further on many levels: the impact of multinationals, the sharing of benefits of cooperation, the questions of debt, climate adaptation funds, or sharing technologies in a way that tries to empower local populations rather than European capital.Footnote 40 It is crucial to see that with regard to these developing countries, it is perhaps the first time that the conflict between European capital and European society is there for everyone to see: the lack of even elementary prosperity abroad (due to the extraction of minerals, land, profits, tax, liveable climate, etc.) will increasingly contribute to migration pressures.

Currently, perhaps the lowest hanging fruit in EU policymaking, which could be a game changer in instituting a new imaginary of shared prosperity, is to strengthen the so-called ‘social economy’.Footnote 41 Social economy organisations engage in economic activity for the “right reasons”, creating on the way various kinds of “positive externalities”, such as providing a range of affordable services, ensuring resilience in the face of crises, increasing inclusion, and strengthening local communities.Footnote 42 While the EU has had social economy on the radar for a long time, due to all these positive externalities, it has not done much to actually create a level playing field for such organisations. If it does so, as I suggest in Chapter 6, social economy could be an instrument of economic development that would eventually limit anxiety with stagnating economic growth and at the same time support people, via individual and collective efforts, to make the economy that can be fun – and still work for people. Also in relation to the ‘third countries’, international trade via social economy or steward-owned enterprises would result in a fairer distribution of the surpluses of economic cooperation, increasing prosperity abroad in the interest of us all.

Together, these proposals may seem utopian, but I have tried to argue that they present a realistic utopia,Footnote 43 because they are both imaginable (within the framework instituted today) and necessary. They are imaginable inasmuch as the EU has already partially shifted its background understandings, having prepared grounds for a new understanding of prosperity. They are also necessary, since both peace and the relevance of the EU depend on ushering in a credible imaginary of prosperity. Such imaginary, which would be both more shared and sustainable, can address the problems societies face, while offering a credible prospect of a prosperous future.

Footnotes

1 For a famous debate on the need for demos in Europe, see Dieter Grimm, ‘Does Europe Need a Constitution?’, European Law Journal 1, no. 3 (1995): 282302; J. Habermas, ‘Remarks on Dieter Grimm’s “Does Europe Need a Constitution?”’, European Law Journal 1, no. 3 (1995): 303–7.

2 Who is the EU I discuss in this book? I focus on the European institutions: the European Commission, the European Parliament, the Councils of the EU, and occasionally the European Courts, the ECB, as well as more opaque institutions such as the ‘Regulatory Scrutiny Board’ or various standardisation bodies. Importantly, after more recent attempts of the EU institutions to move beyond privatised prosperity, I am somewhat more confident than before (Marija Bartl, ‘Internal Market Rationality, Private Law and the Direction of the Union: Resuscitating the Market as the Object of the Political’, European Law Journal, 21, no. 5 (15 January 2015), 572–98) in the responsiveness and democratic potential of these (surely imperfect) European institutions. At the same time, this is not to deny the contribution of the EU institutions to the very same problems that now threaten democratic institutions in Europe and beyond. Foremost, the incapacity of EU institutions to move beyond privatising prosperity post-2008, and instead doubling down on it, shows the EU’s limits – its deficient institutional framework, the misalignment between the economic interests of its MSs or the strong influence of industry and capital on its policymaking. But especially in the face of irrelevance or dissolution, the EU is more likely to develop an imaginary of shared prosperity, showing us hereby also – as Habermas once hoped – what the post-national democracy and solidarity could look like.

3 I discuss those in Section 2.4.1.

4 Friedrich A. Hayek, ‘The Economic Conditions of Interstate Federalism’. New Commonwealth Quarterly  5 (1939): 131–49. For important revisions of this claim, for the context of the EU and global context, see Wolfgang Streeck, ‘The Crises of Democratic Capitalism’, New Left Review 71, no. 5 (2011): 529; Dani Rodrik, The Globalization Paradox: Democracy and the Future of the World Economy (W. W. Norton & Company, 2011).

5 Clemens Kaupa, The Pluralist Character of the European Economic Constitution (Bloomsbury Publishing, 2016).

8 Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (Broadway Business, 2013), chapter 13.

9 Wester Van Gaal, ‘“A Prosperous New Year”? EU Heads for Austerity in 2024’, EU Observer (2024), https://euobserver.com/green-economy/157852, last accessed 16 January 2024.

10 More institutionalist approach to the economy can be seen in Chapters 36.

11 A shift from taking to steering economy and markets can be seen in Chapters 36.

12 See Chapters 3 and 4.

13 Mostly Chapters 3 and 4

14 Foremost Chapter 4, but also Chapter 6.

15 Foremost Chapter 4.

16 Foremost Chapter 5.

17 Foremost Chapter 6.

18 Foremost Chapter 5.

19 See Chapter 5.

20 Daniela Gabor, ‘The (European) Derisking State’, Stato e mercato 1 (2023): 5384.

21 Foremost Chapters 3 and 5.

22 See Chapters 36.

23 See Chapters 36.

24 Foremost Chapter 3.

25 Foremost Chapter 5, partially also Chapter 6.

26 Some references in Chapters 36.

27 See Chapters 36.

28 Foremost Chapters 35.

29 In Chapter 5, for instance, “competitiveness” and “extractiveness” sometimes have an upper hand.

30 Foremost Chapters 3 (consumer), 4 (product), and 6 (corporation).

31 Foremost Chapters 3 and 6.

32 See Chapters 5 and 6.

33 Acemoglu and Robinson, Why Nations Fail.

34 Marco Buti and Marcello Messori, ‘European Public Goods Are Key to Tackle the Economic Challenges of 2023’, EUIdeas (2023), https://euideas.eui.eu/2023/02/01/european-public-goods-are-key-to-tackle-the-economic-challenges-of-2023/, last accessed 16 January 2024.

35 Jefim Vogel et al., ‘Safeguarding Livelihoods against Reductions in Economic Output’, Ecological Economics 215 (1 January 2024): 107977.

36 Anu Bradford, The Brussels Effect: How the European Union Rules the World (Oxford University Press, USA, 2020).

37 Simon Johnson and Daron Acemoglu, Power and Progress: Our Thousand-Year Struggle Over Technology and Prosperity (Hachette UK, 2023).

38 Vogel et al., ‘Safeguarding Livelihoods against Reductions in Economic Output’.

39 See Chapter 6.

40 Isabel Feichtner, Markus Krajewski, and Ricarda Roesch, eds., Human Rights in the Extractive Industries: Transparency, Participation, Resistance, vol. 3, Interdisciplinary Studies in Human Rights (Springer International Publishing, 2019).

42 European Commission, Building an economy that works for people: an action plan for the social economy, COM(2021) 778 final, pp. 4–6.

43 Rutger Bregman, Utopia for Realists (Bloomsbury Publishing, 2018).

Figure 0

Table 7.1 Modern Social Imaginaries: Background Assumptions

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Conclusion
  • Marija Bartl, University of Amsterdam
  • Book: Reimagining Prosperity
  • Online publication: 18 October 2024
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009236195.008
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Conclusion
  • Marija Bartl, University of Amsterdam
  • Book: Reimagining Prosperity
  • Online publication: 18 October 2024
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009236195.008
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Conclusion
  • Marija Bartl, University of Amsterdam
  • Book: Reimagining Prosperity
  • Online publication: 18 October 2024
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009236195.008
Available formats
×