Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T07:46:29.790Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Varieties of State-Building: Ecology, Clientelism, and Bureaucratic Rule in Chile

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 March 2024

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Current research suggests that all states share a perpetual appetite for extraction and standardization. However, this research overlooks the fact that subnational regions present different appeals and challenges to ruling coalitions. While states seek to extend bureaucratic rule over peripheries with valuable assets and favorable geography, they might instead seek to preserve local patrimonial bastions when those areas offer substantial electoral support. In turn, these strategies lead to broad subnational heterogeneity in the reach of the state. This paper focuses on regions’ ecological, military, and clientelistic features to explain local trajectories of bureaucratic rule and country-level state capacity. Empirically, I examine Chile, a successful case of capacity-building in Latin America. Prompted by a fiscal crisis in the mid-1850s, Chile’s central government launched state-building projects to offset its budgetary deficit. Using GIS and original data from censuses, budgets, and other primary sources, I show that Chile’s ruling coalition paradoxically modernized the country’s peripheries while deepening its own traditionalism. These results challenge prevailing narratives about the projection of political authority and Chile’s territorial uniformity.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of American Political Science Association

Introduction

State-building—the extension of a ruler’s authority over distance—is essential for political development. The effort to project authority enhances the government’s presence across the territory, compels the formation of professional bureaucracies, and promotes an efficient and equitable production of public goods. Successful state-building also helps to prevent the emergence of stateless spaces, which can become the foundation for nonstate actors (e.g., rebel groups, criminal organizations) to challenge the state’s monopoly of violence and thereby threaten its existence.

Contrary to the dominant approach, which focuses on the strength of a state-building core, this paper focuses on subnational regions’ socioeconomic and physical features.Footnote 1 Three types of factors, ecological, military, and clientelistic, strongly shape state-building projects, strategies, and outcomes. Regions with favorable ecologies—valuable commodities and advantageous geography—are targeted for state-building. However, the outcome—cooperative or imposed bureaucratization—depends on local elites’ ability to extract concessions through a military threat. When regions present unfavorable ecological conditions, leaders are unlikely to pursue state-building, settling instead for indirect rule. Paradoxically, ruling coalitions’ need to survive in office may compel them to form subnational enclaves to favor potential clientelistic allies, helping them to secure de facto autonomy and preferential access to public goods. In turn, the effort to disrupt ecologies and rule distant regions necessitates investments in administrative and technocratic reforms, contributing to national-level state capacity.

Empirically, this paper focuses on the dual effects of the global trade expansion of the mid-nineteenth century. As prices for raw materials increased rapidly, subnational regions previously considered insignificant gained newfound value. Advancements in transportation altered the perception of such peripheries, rendering them accessible and exploitable. However, the overall impact of expanded trade was a weakening of state authority, as ruling coalitions engaged in compromises with local elites, leading to revenue-sharing arrangements under the banner of indirect rule (Mazzuca Reference Mazzuca2021). Nonetheless, this period also witnessed a potent force driving state-building: fiscal shocks driven by commodity busts. Given a country’s typical reliance on a single commodity, sudden drops in international prices often triggered acute financial crises. In response, ruling coalitions strategically turned either to international credit or to state-building to produce or tax commodities they believed would gain value in the near future.

I assess this theory by studying nineteenth-century Chile. In a region known for endemic state weakness, Chile is a successful case of capacity-building in the absence of strong geopolitical pressures. Prompted by a fiscal crisis in the mid-1850s, Chile’s ruling coalition led several state-building efforts to offset fiscal vulnerability. The state negotiated a transition to bureaucratic rule in Atacama to the north and Concepción to the south, both peripheral areas with favorable ecological conditions that coalesced to make a military threat. Then, the state imposed bureaucratization in Araucanía, an area of dense forests and scattered geography in the far south dominated by the native Mapuche. Finally, to shore up political support, the government allied with landed elites in the capital’s hinterland, the Central Valley. Although Chile is often considered the poster child of evenly projected state power, this paper suggests that state-building was instead highly selective and uneven, with the very center being the most important deviation to uniform, bureaucratic rule.

The empirical section measures the state’s territorial reach using a geographic information system (GIS) with a combination of census and budget data. Censuses show individuals who identify as bureaucrats or members of the military and police, while budgets reflect the central government’s spending on wages and various public goods, including public works, the judiciary, and the police. The data is provided at the department level—the smallest administrative unit at the time. Unlike infrastructure-based indicators, this approach enables state-building and public goods to be analyzed separately.

My findings contribute to the study of state-building, democratization, and public goods distribution. First, the role of regional ecology can be employed to think about how states negotiate and regulate the contemporary expansion of illicit economies, including drug production, deforestation, and mining in hard-to-reach areas. Against conventional wisdom in democratization theory, this paper suggests that landowners can promote enfranchisement if they can secure a base of clientelistic support among peasants. Finally, my analysis suggests that there is a conceptual and empirical difference between public goods distribution and state capacity, as an increased flow of public goods to a region—commonly confounded with state capacity in the literature—can coexist and even thrive under patrimonialism.

In what follows, I discuss major works on state-building and Latin American politics, and chart a theory-building exercise that suggests how fiscal and coalitional needs combine with regions’ ecologies to shape subnational outcomes. Then, I provide a sketch of center–periphery relations in Chile and the events that led to state-building projects. Finally, I test the theory by showing the cross-sectional and temporal variation in the reach of Chile’s state and country-level state capacity, and by conducting case studies for each subnational outcome.

Theories of State-Building

Studies on the emergence of modern states have emphasized the role of warfare. In this approach, geopolitical pressures between rival feudal lords after the end of the Carolingian era in the ninth century eventually led to the concentration of coercive and extractive resources in the hands of the state. This “bellicist” hypothesis was first proposed by Hintze (Reference Hintze and Gilbert1975), who suggested that geopolitical pressures began in the early sixteenth century once France interpreted the Habsburgs’ territories in Spain and the southern Netherlands as a security threat. The French crown responded by “eliminating provincial particularism, centralizing administration, and creating a standing army to boost French military effectiveness” (Ertman Reference Ertman, Kaspersen and Strandsbjerg2017, 54). These events created escalatory pressures that led Spain and Austria to react similarly. From then on, the creation of standing armies and tax collection became the exclusive authority of the king (Hintze Reference Hintze and Gilbert1975, 194–95).

Several works have expanded the bellicist thesis by adding new dimensions, mainly the availability of taxable resources. Wherever rulers had to tax individuals instead of imposing trade duties—a far more significant effort—the state became sturdier (Tilly Reference Tilly, Skocpol, Evans and Rueschemeyer1985; Reference Tilly1992). The timing and scope of the military revolution have also been associated with variations in state capacity (Ertman Reference Ertman1997). Where state-building took place before the military revolution (ca. 1450), technologies of state expansion were obsolete and became hard to replace (Ertman Reference Ertman1997, 27).Footnote 2

A second school emphasizes states’ enduring interest in making nature and populations legible in order to extract revenue (Scott Reference Scott1998; Reference Scott2009). To achieve such legibility, states develop official measurements, censuses, statistical yearbooks, scientific forestry, and cartography to make their surroundings easier to read and tax. Recent empirical works have suggested that legibility is associated with centralized governance (Lee and Zhang Reference Lee and Zhang2017), suffrage expansion (Brambor et al. Reference Brambor, Goenaga, Lindvall and Teorell2020), and fiscal capacity (Vom Hau, Peres-Cajías, and Soifer Reference Vom Hau, Peres-Cajías and Soifer2023).

A third group of works counter the idea of states as control- and revenue-maximizers by instead emphasizing instances of subnational heterogeneity within states’ reach. Some of these works focus on the projection of authority as a cost-benefit trade-off that includes a region’s distance to the center, population density, and geographic ruggedness (Alesina and Spolaore Reference Alesina and Spolaore2003; Herbst Reference Herbst2014). Related works that focus on postcolonial states suggest that ruling coalitions tend to allow for decentralized governance with regional elites or even leave areas wholly ungoverned in an effort to minimize political conflict (e.g., Boone Reference Boone2003; Giraudy and Luna Reference Giraudy, Luna, Centeno, Kohli, Yashar and Mistree2017; O’Donnell Reference O’Donnell1993; Sánchez Talanquer Reference Sánchez Talanquer2017; Slater and Kim Reference Slater and Kim2015).

State-Building in Latin America

A growing consensus in the study of Latin American politics suggests that the aftermath of the independence wars of the early nineteenth century had long-term repercussions on state development. Those who share this view agree on two conclusions: (1) state weakness is common in the region, and (2) cross-national differences are consistent. The first wave of scholars to arrive at these conclusions evaluated the bellicist hypothesis. Centeno (Reference Centeno2002) claimed that although Latin American countries did experience wars in this period, these conflicts did not increase states’ capacity since they were financed with foreign loans instead of direct taxation. Unlike the effort to tax individuals directly, loans do not encourage bureaucratic development. Centeno’s hypothesis was revisited by Thies (Reference Thies2005), Schenoni (Reference Schenoni2021), and Queralt (Reference Queralt2022). Discussing Chile, they suggest that its divergence lies in its disputes with Peru and Bolivia throughout the nineteenth century, especially during the War of the Pacific (1879–84). For Schenoni, the results of wars—rather than preparations for them—put countries on different trajectories of state development. Queralt (Reference Queralt2022, 273–89) argues that since Chile could not access credit during the War of the Pacific, ruling elites had to impose taxation on elites, enhancing institution-building in the long run.

Four more scholars have evaluated sources of Chile’s state capacity. Saylor (Reference Saylor2014) argued that, in Chile, an export-oriented coalition demanded new public goods during the double boom of copper and wheat, which led to capacity-building. For Kurtz (Reference Kurtz2013), state-building was unlikely where rural elites depended on a labor-repressive agrarian economy. Echoing Moore’s (Reference Moore1966) thesis that landlords are the elite faction most hostile to democratization, Kurtz argued that landowners oppose state-building too, since a strong state is more likely to take away their control over coerced laborers. Soifer (Reference Soifer2015) identified ideational motivations behind state-building, as ruling elites opt for the expansion of the state when they see it as a means for development (2015, 4, 24). He suggested that the identities of administrators explain territorial unevenness, as state-building goals are more successful when the state deploys outsiders in communities than when they are appointed by local elites. Mazzuca (Reference Mazzuca2021) argued that trade expansion produces weak states, since ruling coalitions and peripheral elites share incentives for indirect rule. While he does not study Chile in depth, his argument suggests that the origins of Chile’s comparatively high-capacity state lie in the lack of patrimonial peripheries (28).

Varieties of State-Building

Despite the progress made by the theories outlined above, fundamental challenges remain. Geopolitical theories have limited application outside Western Europe and do not explain successful episodes of capacity-building in the absence of war. The fact that ruling elites are usually reluctant to commit to costly projects of simplification and standardization undermines the legibility school’s most relevant claim. While theories that focus on the uneven nature of states have modified their assumptions accordingly, they usually suggest that states reduce their scope and appetite for taxation only when local challengers push back. While scholars of Latin American politics have pushed the field’s theoretical and empirical boundaries forward, the uneven nature of Chile’s projection of authority remains unexplored. The following subsections explain how economic incentives brought by the trade expansion of the late nineteenth century combine with regions’ attributes to explain subnational trajectories of bureaucratic rule and country-level state capacity.

Trade Expansion and Fiscal Shocks

The literature broadly considers the global expansion of capitalism as inimical to state-building for two reasons. First, the wide availability of international credit limited the development of extractive institutions and, second, the possibility of sharing the benefits of trade incentivized decentralized governance.Footnote 3 On the contrary, this paper focuses on a less explored aspect of trade expansion: the fiscal crises prompted by commodity busts.Footnote 4 These episodes were among the first exogenous economic shocks experienced by the young republics of the Americas. Under such circumstances, fiscal needs offset the costs of disrupting friendly center–periphery relations and taking over newly valuable commodities becomes a plausible strategy to balance the deficit. Even though international finance became an important source of revenue for many governments under these circumstances, Chile could not balance its budget only with this mechanism, opting for state-building as a complementary strategy.

Regions’ Attributes

Ecological Suitability

State-building is more likely to succeed in ecologically suitable regions. Suitability varies according to two key factors: geographic accessibility and economic appeal. Scholars broadly agree that state development is probable in regions characterized by social and physical enclosure. Michael Mann (Reference Mann2012a, 42) explained the emergence of early states through the metaphor of a social cage, a “fixed settlement [that] traps people into living with each other, cooperating, and devising more complex forms of social organization.” These spaces limit the avenues of escape from the state’s ambitions. Olson (Reference Olson1993, 575) further argued that the advantages of being a “stationary bandit”—a ruler who establishes political order and facilitates economic development—are larger in contexts of geographic boundedness.

Political hierarchies first emerged in fertile agricultural regions with available connections (usually rivers) that were bounded by mountains, seas, or deserts. In such geography, individuals find it difficult to escape states’ attempts to tax them (Carneiro Reference Carneiro1970; Dal Bó, Hernández-Lagos, and Mazzuca Reference Dal Bó, Hernández-Lagos and Mazzuca2021; Fernández-Villaverde et al. Reference Fernández-Villaverde, Koyama, Lin and Sng2023). Hintze (Reference Hintze and Gilbert1975) linked geography and European state-building by suggesting that England escaped the escalatory pressures identified in the bellicist tradition due to its insular condition. But geographic features can also prevent state-building. In areas that Scott (Reference Scott2009) calls “zones of refuge,” rugged terrain hinders state control over local populations. Similarly, sparsely populated areas make it difficult for the state to access taxable populations, which limits its territorial scope (Herbst Reference Herbst2014).

A second feature of ecological suitability is a region’s economic endowments. The economic value of peripheries can increase when international markets drive up the price of commodities. Regions may contain newly valuable resources such as minerals, or have the appropriate climatic and geographic conditions for agricultural development. In contrast, regions without economic value are less likely to be targeted for state-building under these circumstances.

Figure 1 charts a theory-building exercise suggesting a relationship between geographic accessibility and economic appeal, leading to four ideal types: (1) cages, (2) marginal, (3) refuge, and (4) autonomous. Cages are ideal for state-building, as their geographic and economic features facilitate it; they are the only ecologically suitable region. Marginal regions have appropriate geographic conditions for state-building but lack economic appeal (i.e., before or after commodity booms). Refuge areas are inaccessible to the state, and, consequently, have no financial appeal. These are usually hills, tropical jungles, dense forests, and deserts. Finally, autonomous regions refer to hard-to-reach yet productive areas. These include, for instance, Colombia’s coffee-producing intermontane valleys, which stand in stark contrast to Chile’s Central Valley in terms of geographic accessibility (see empirical analysis below).

Figure 1 A Typology of Ecological Suitability for State-Building

Regional classifications are not fixed. Rather, fiscal shocks or commodity booms change regions’ economic outlook. Similarly, technological advancements in transportation, engineering, or cartography can change accessibility. The phrase “ecologically suitable” does not encompass every type of region. Rather, it describes regions whose ecological features most interact with state-building. Even though cages are the only regional type defined as ecologically suitable, ruling coalitions may still attempt to extend their rule into less suitable areas. As this paper focuses on state-building, the empirical section evaluates ecologically suitable regions only.

Ruling coalitions’ efforts to turn regions into cages can prompt tangible gains in state capacity. However, this too depends on regions’ features. Areas suitable for grazing, like the southwestern US and the central Atlantic coast of South America, may require little to no investment by the state yet still bring revenue to it. Conversely, if challenging “zones of refuge” hold highly valuable resources, states may, in the event of land shortages, spend significant energy and resources to make them legible, leading to investments in technology, infrastructure, and administrative reforms and enhancing capacity-building in the long run. As the empirical section below shows, the Chilean state invested many resources to turn Araucanía, an area of dense forests where native peoples escaped colonial ambitions for centuries, into a wheat-growing area. As a side effect, this project shaped the formation of technocratic cadres and prompted important bureaucratic reforms.

Credible Military Threats

A second attribute that impacts state-building outcomes is the ability of peripheral elites to threaten a ruling coalition. Regions that pool coercive resources and create a credible threat to the control of the ruling coalition are more likely to obtain concessions than those that do not. In particular, what matters is the perceived threat of ruling elites, not regions’ baseline defense capabilities. This difference is well illustrated by the threats created by colonial-era peripheral elites and first nations in the Americas during the nineteenth century. Empowered by the benefits of trade expansion, many peripheral elites were able to resist state-building efforts by raising armies. In Latin America, these were the well-known caudillos. On the other hand, indigenous peoples such as the Mapuche in present-day Chile (analyzed below) were able to secure fewer territorial concessions than wealthier, politically relevant colonial-era regional elites. The former often launched rebellions aimed at limiting state-building and upending the national ruling coalition, while the latter’s uprising attempted to stop internal colonization projects within their own regions.

Clientelistic Reserves

Successful state-building can paradoxically reinforce local patrimonial strongholds. As ruling coalitions disrupt friendly center–periphery relations to seek more revenue, they must forge new alliances to stay in power. Landed elites, for instance, employed patron–client relationships with the state to resist democratization pressures in the late nineteenth century. In agriculture-based regions reliant on labor, landowners could secure votes through clientelistic ties with a large pool of peasants. In contrast, rural political machines did not become prevalent in pastoralist economies due to low labor requirements, which prevent landlords from creating such clientelistic networks. This center–periphery dynamic—where local lords traded autonomy for political backing—became known as caciquismo in Spain, coronelismo in Brazil, and gamonalismo in the Andes.Footnote 5

Outcomes: Subnational Bureaucratic and Patrimonial Rule

The outcomes serve as answers to the following question: “Who rules a periphery?” A central authority enforces regulations under bureaucratic rule. This category is also characterized by division of labor, defined hierarchies, regular salaries, and free contracts (Mann Reference Mann2012b, 444; Weber [Reference Weber, Roth and Wittich1921] 1978, 1:220–21, 2:952). While common definitions include a meritocratic dimension,Footnote 6 my definition aims only at identifying who holds political and administrative authority within a region. Bureaucratic rule can be classified into two subtypes: imposed and cooperative. Imposition refers to replacing a regional patrimonial administration through force without granting concessions to local notables. It usually takes the form of internal colonization and involves a large deployment of coercive forces and technocrats—engineers and surveyors—to make new areas legible to the state. Cooperative bureaucratization, on the other hand, involves the extension of state authority into a region while also granting rights to local elites, typically through political incorporation and public goods.Footnote 7

Patrimonial rule is defined by the discretionary power wielded by local private actors, such as landowners, warlords, local parties and politicians, or the clergy. In place of state institutions, they rely on private patronage networks to enforce regulations. Under cooperative patrimonialism, allies secure high degrees of de facto autonomy—the right to use coercion, settle conflicts, and collect taxes—and preferential access to public goods.Footnote 8 Under patrimonial reinforcement, the national ruling coalition also bolsters legal and political boundaries to safeguard a subnational enclave where patrimonialism can endure and thrive.Footnote 9

Figure 2 illustrates the theory, including independent variables and outcomes. During fiscal crises, some regional attributes become valuable to the center. Ruling coalitions attempt state-building in ecologically suitable regions while targeting regions with clientelistic advantages for patrimonial reinforcement. Regions that lack both attributes are ignored for state-building by ruling coalitions, who settle instead for patrimonial cooperation. If a periphery is economically valuable but ecologically unsuitable—autonomous regions as defined in figure 1—ruling elites opt for patrimonial cooperation too. These areas can be made productive by the private sector, without the state’s intervention. Finally, in regions where ruling coalitions do attempt state-building, the type of bureaucratization depends on the extent to which local notables pose a credible threat to the incumbent’s role in the ruling coalition.

Figure 2 Regions’ Attributes and State-Building Outcomes

Note: Figure assumes that money borrowing is no longer an option and assumes the presence of regions that can be made productive.

Bureaucratic Rule and State Capacity

Geopolitical theories suggest that the effort to raise an army to wage war prompts state capacity. The greater the effort, the larger the “organizational residues” (Tilly Reference Tilly, Skocpol, Evans and Rueschemeyer1985, 181). I suggest a slightly different proposition. The effort to disrupt local ecologies, govern distant regions, and make them productive creates residues in the form of investments in technocratic cadres and infrastructure. Such efforts can lead to capacity-building at the central level, as the availability of such expertise and institutional templates enhances the state’s capacity to deploy public goods across the territory.

The Case: Chile

Chile is a positive divergent case of state development in Latin America. Figure 3 illustrates the distinctiveness of Chile’s evolution through the development of railroads and telegraph lines per square mile—a commonly used indicator of the state’s territorial reach. The Chilean state’s territorial control was higher than the regional mean as early as the mid-1860s, a pattern that continued over time.

Figure 3 States’ Territorial Reach in South America

Source: Banks and Wilson (Reference Banks and Wilson2021).

The Chilean central government’s budget expanded steadily from the late 1850s (Humud Tleel Reference Humud Tleel1969; López Taverne Reference López Taverne2014; Reference López Taverne, Jaksic and Rengifo2017, 66–69). According to figure 4, the Treasury and Interior budgets saw the most significant growth.Footnote 10 These ministries allocated resources for tax collection and bureaucrats’ wages, respectively. Customs witnessed a 111% increase in employees, rising from 276 people in 1845 to 581 in 1880, in stark contrast to the rest of the Treasury’s agencies.Footnote 11 This change suggests a deliberate effort to enhance the state’s ability to extract resources from Chilean society.

Figure 4 Chile’s Annual Budget, 1845–78

Source: Interior Ministry budgets.

The Chilean case is ideal for studying capacity-building in the absence of the strong geopolitical pressures identified in the bellicist tradition. Scholars have noted that the animosity between Chile, Peru, and Bolivia may have driven the Chilean divergence (Schenoni Reference Schenoni2021; Thies Reference Thies2005). However, Chile’s successful state-building can be traced back to the early 1860s, 20 years after the war against the Peru–Bolivian Confederation (1836–39), and 15 years before the War of the Pacific (1879–84). Moreover, the 1860s were a period of amity between Chile and Peru, as both countries allied against Spain in the Spanish–South American War (1865–79).Footnote 12 The state-building projects of the 1860s were not a legacy of the war against the Peru–Bolivian Confederation either. Chilean elites perceived the confederation as a threat since Peru’s main port could surpass Chile’s Valparaíso and control trade in the South Pacific. Chile allied with the Peruvian opposition in the Ejército Restaurador, a coalition aimed at breaking down the confederation and restoring the Peruvian state. As such, Chile’s role in the conflict was not characterized by territorial conflict and did not include the annexation of regions. Internal conflict is another plausible hypothesis. Indeed, Chile had two civil wars, in 1851 and 1859. In my interpretation, the first conflict was mainly over presidential succession, while the latter was a peripheral backlash to state-building.

Historical Background

Chile’s territory consisted of four regions at the time of independence (1810): Atacama, Santiago, Concepción, and Araucanía. Atacama was a mining enclave near the Atacama Desert. Santiago included the capital, Valparaíso (the main port), and the surrounding wheat-producing area in the Central Valley.Footnote 13 Concepción was originally a Spanish military outpost created to fight wars of expansion against indigenous people. Over time, it developed into a large city with a frontier economy and culture like neighboring Araucanía, home of the native Mapuche. Figure 5 shows these areas and the territories that were annexed later on.Footnote 14 Due to their geographic features—bounded by the Andes, the Chilean Coastal Range, the Atacama Desert, and the western region of Patagonia—Chilean regions were cages, except for Araucanía. Due to its dense forests and scattered geography, that region can be defined as a refuge.Footnote 15

Figure 5 Chile’s Regions

A conservative ruling coalition sanctioned a unitary constitution in 1833, bestowing preeminence on the capital Santiago. Each province would be governed by an intendente (intendant), and each department by a gobernador (governor). However, given that the central government did not have a real presence across regions and local notables retained significant agency, the centralist nature of the constitution was nominal rather than real.Footnote 16 The supposed ascendancy of the capital rested on brittle political alignments within the ruling coalition. While named by the president, intendants were usually chosen in agreement with local elites, and “official” electoral lists were drafted in close alignment with, and in recognition of, local elites’ sensibilities.Footnote 17

Each region hosted numerous nonstate actors. These local elites had different origins.Footnote 18 In Atacama, mining businessmen filled administrative posts and named the intendente (Fernández Abara and Jerez Leiva Reference Fernández Abara, Leiva and Montory2020; Godoy Orellana Reference Godoy Orellana2018). Private actors built and operated ports, which led to inefficiencies and smuggling (Godoy Orellana Reference Godoy Orellana2018). Since rapid urbanization followed wherever a new mineral deposit was discovered, mine owners soon had to finance essential public goods like infrastructure and policing. A mine-owners’ guild organized the police; appointed administrative, political, judicial, and religious authorities; collected taxes; and distributed public goods (Fernández Abara Reference Fernández Abara2016; Venegas Valdebenito Reference Venegas Valdebenito2008).

Concepción saw the development of a local export economy of wheat and wine exports to Lima and the emergence of trans-Andean commercial routes (Pinto Rodríguez Reference Pinto Rodríguez and Montory2020). Yet independence brought a period of decline, as banditry and civil conflict brought expropriation and forced conscription. A new foreign elite arrived in the 1830s, helping to redevelop the wheat and milling sectors (Campos Harriet Reference Campos Harriet1979; Mazzei de Grazia Reference Mazzei de Grazia2015). Mapuche elites participated actively in Concepción’s local economy by exchanging meat, salt, and textiles (Pinto Rodríguez Reference Pinto Rodríguez2003). Having also settled across the Central Valley, they stopped the advancement of the Spanish army at the Biobío River (Bengoa Reference Bengoa2015), and developed diplomatic relations with the Spanish Empire.

The origins of Central Valley’s haciendas lay in the need to provide food for the military garrison in Concepción in the early colonial period. After the Spanish crown gave land grants to a select number of people, and given the need for cheap labor, landlords created a service-tenancy system. They began incorporating a small number of inquilinos—permanent laborers—and their families into haciendas, where they were given a small plot of land to grow food. Inquilinos and their families were tied to the land by tradition rather than law (McBride Reference McBride1936). Beyond their work in the fields, inquilinos also provided domestic services (Carrière Reference Carrière1981, 20). The process of mestizaje—the racial mixing of Spanish and native Chileans—created a large mass of seminomadic people in the area. In such a context, being included in the hacienda structure could be seen as an important benefit by peasants. Central Valley elites enjoyed preferential access to public goods, as the ruling coalition directed state-owned railroads, roads, and irrigation canals to this area to the detriment of Concepción’s farmers.Footnote 19

Fiscal Shocks and State-Building

The fiscal crisis of the mid-1850s triggered economic uncertainty, leading actors to reassess the advantages of state-building compared to the prevalence of indirect rule. First, silver prices plummeted due to the Panic of 1857 (Encina Reference Encina1949, 589). Stagnating silver deposits limited the currency supply, since this metal was used to mint coins (Edwards Reference Edwards1932, 147; Humud Tleel Reference Humud Tleel1974, 78–79). Revenue from customs duties declined and the trade balance became negative for the first time ever (Edwards Reference Edwards1932, 146; Humud Tleel Reference Humud Tleel1974, 22, 74). Added to a few poor harvests in previous years, Manuel Montt’s government (1851–61) was now facing an existential economic downturn.

At the same time, the opening of international markets created new opportunities. First, a wheat boom began with the California gold rush (1848–55). Elites foresaw a promising future for grain given improvements in navigation through the Strait of Magellan that could open up the European, Argentine, Brazilian, and US East Coast markets.Footnote 20 A copper boom due to the spread of electricity in emerging industrial economies also provided relief. Unlike silver, copper production survived thanks to smelting technologies that reduced the need for labor (Fernández Abara and Jerez Leiva Reference Fernández Abara, Leiva and Montory2020, 95) and the discovery of coal near Concepción that lowered fuel costs (L. Valenzuela Reference Valenzuela1992, 507). Together, these changes catalyzed state-building as an attempt to halt the looming fiscal crisis.Footnote 21

Chile: The Argument

Figure 6 illustrates the main argument, combining the theory outlined above and the Chilean process. After the emergence of a ruling coalition (1830), center–periphery relations were patrimonial and cooperative. After the price shocks in the 1850s, the central government changed its approach to governance in the periphery, opting for state-building. In Concepción and Atacama, the outcome was bureaucratic cooperation. Because these regions had gone through steady economic growth since the 1830s, local elites were able to pose a credible threat in the civil wars of 1851 and 1859. The central government defeated the rebels in a pyrrhic victory, as peripheral elites were able to extract concessions in the form of political incorporation and public goods.

Figure 6 Chile: Outline of the Argument

The ruling coalition opted for patrimonial reinforcement in the Central Valley by creating legal and political boundaries around the traditional hacienda-based social order to offer a base of clientelistic support to the conservative side. Finally, the state chose bureaucratic imposition in Araucanía through a military campaign to make the area arable for wheat and silviculture. Patagonia’s ecological conditions did not present any advantages for state-building. Its arid, cold climate and scattered geography thwarted any productive activities during the colonial period and shortly thereafter.Footnote 22

Empirical Analysis

Cross-Sectional and Temporal Variation

This section draws on original data from censuses and budgets to show the cross-sectional and temporal variation in the reach of the state (Véjares Reference Véjares2024). I use a population-adjusted measure of the presence of bureaucrats and members of the military and police, and of resources spent on bureaucrats’ wages, the judiciary, and public works.Footnote 23 Recent works measure states’ projection of authority through the distribution of infrastructure—mainly railroads (e.g., Bignon, Esteves, and Herranz-Loncán Reference Bignon, Esteves and Herranz-Loncán2015; Cermeño, Enflo, and Lindvall Reference Cermeño, Enflo and Lindvall2022). I choose an alternative approach that distinguishes between bureaucratic rule and public goods distribution. The analysis below suggests that an increased flow of public goods combines very well with the protection of local patrimonial bastions. As local elites enjoy preferential access to the state, they are more likely to receive resources for infrastructure projects while keeping the central bureaucracy at bay.

Figure 7 displays the presence of bureaucrats in each department’s capital between 1865 and 1920.Footnote 24 The central bureaucracy expanded widely through Chilean territory in this period, with a distinctive increase in the northern and southern peripheries. The ruling coalition already had an important presence in Atacama by 1865. While we lack census data for the pre-1859 rebellion period, historiographic accounts agree that mining businessmen ruled the area through their private clientele and networks.Footnote 25 Budget data in figure 9 corroborates this conclusion. Together with a large expansion in the number of bureaucrats, the central government increased the number of departments in Araucanía the most. The figure also shows the underdevelopment of the bureaucracy in the Central Valley, which is the only region that did not undergo bureaucratization.Footnote 26 By 1920, the presence of the central government became even greater than in previous decades. While such a pattern denotes a special effort by the ruling coalition to govern specific regions in earlier years, it is also worth noting that the central bureaucracy was still weak in the Central Valley 60 years after state-building projects took place.

Figure 7 Territorial Reach of the State, 1865–1920

Notes: White and black dots represent one standard deviation—positive and negative, respectively—from the mean. Given that departments’ limits were often drawn decades after census data were taken, the figure shows each department’s capitals instead of administrative boundaries. See González, Compán, and Sagredo Baeza (Reference González, Compán and Baeza2016, 311).

Figure 8 uses budget data to show the ruling coalition’s priorities over public goods in 1899. The pattern is similar to figure 7 with one relevant exception: the Central Valley received much more resources for productivity-enhancing public goods than for bureaucracy. Panels 2 and 3 show that the state prioritized funding for the judiciary and public works where landed elites were the strongest (particularly in provincial capitals like Talca and Curicó). Unlike high regulatory capacity, landed elites welcomed these public goods: the judiciary enforced property rights, while public works to improve irrigation and transportation were essential to increase production and exports. This pattern reflects a compliant relationship between the state and local notables, as state weakness was combined with infrastructural development and expanding state authority in other regions.

Figure 8 Spatial Distribution of Public Goods, 1899

Source: Dirección General de Contabilidad (1901).

Political elites saw state-building as a plausible strategy to increase revenue as early as 1865. Treasury ministers suggested that improving tax collection methods and creating unified administrative procedures could increase fiscal income without affecting trade. Until then, customs offices operated independently from one another.Footnote 27 By the mid-1870s, the Treasury Ministry was able to create a unified accounting system.Footnote 28 The plan included hiring guards and bureaucrats directly, whose wages would now be included in the central government’s budget.Footnote 29 Intendants and governors also began writing formal reports in the annual Interior memorias (reports) by 1863, denoting higher vertical accountability.

Subnational Outcomes

Bureaucratic Cooperation

What began as a strong alliance between local conservative factions in Atacama, Concepción, and the ruling coalition in the early 1830s became fragile 20 years later. The rebellious regions shared similar grievances. The first move of Manuel Montt’s government to offset the deficit was to raise taxes in regions already affected by the Panic of 1857 and in a context of a highly uneven tax rate. The agricultural tax—paid mainly by Central Valley landowners—accounted for only 3% of fiscal income (Zeitlin Reference Zeitlin1984, 38). Most of the revenue came from exports from the peripheries.

In Concepción, liberalism gained traction in the late 1840s due in part to the rise of its new business-oriented elite. Local actors condemned the 1851 elections over fraud and, angered by the economic downturn, followed a local warlord. José María de la Cruz and his followers rebelled against Montt’s newly elected government. In Atacama, middle-class sectors allied with elite families after the government’s refusal to change the tax rate once the crisis hit. Amid a predatory lending system (habilitación) that had fueled a contentious relationship between both parties, the crisis instigated shifts in loyalties. As a result, the province united to oppose the ruling coalition, initially in elections and later on the battlefield. From the ruling coalition’s perspective, the frontier economy and Concepción’s hopes for autonomy were a threat to its overall control.

Both regions shared favorable geographic conditions for state-building. Bounded by the Atacama Desert, the Andes, and the Pacific Ocean, these areas were protected from foreign interference and could not ally with trans-Andean provinces and become part of Argentina’s complex territorial political game.Footnote 30 These areas also had important economic resources the state could use. In Atacama, the ruling coalition needed to increase its presence to end tax evasion and take greater advantage of the copper boom. Concepción offered areas suitable for wheat growth, coal mining, and access to Araucanía.

Both civil wars followed similar trajectories, with local elites mobilizing armies through their local clientele and funding them with resources acquired during the bonanza period. They presented significant threats to the survival of the ruling coalition. Even though the central government emerged victorious both times, conservatives lost control of the ruling coalition and were forced to include liberals.Footnote 31

After the wars, both regions transitioned to bureaucratic rule. In Atacama, the government expanded the judiciary and coercive forces (Godoy Orellana Reference Godoy Orellana2018). Policing became part of the intendancy’s tasks, signaling greater control by the state (Fernandez Abara Reference Fernández Abara2016, 25). Concepción’s elites lost their discretionary power to name public officials. Figure 9 illustrates these regions’ transition to bureaucratic rule, as increased expenses for bureaucrats suggest an effort to enforce regulations directly.Footnote 32 This change was disproportionately large compared to that in other regions, which signals a special priority to increase the state’s presence in these locations.

Figure 9 Bureaucrats’ Wages, 1845–78

Source: Interior Ministry budgets.

Notes: Budget data were produced at the province level. The average includes every province except for Atacama and Concepción. The number of observations varies as new departments were created over time.

The newly created fusionista coalition threatened the executive, first politically, by joining forces to develop alternative electoral lists, and then militarily. While fusionistas lost the 1859 civil war, the ruling coalition was weakened and President Montt did not have political support to name his close ally Antonio Varas as his successor—a tradition upheld by every previous president. As the new Liberal-Conservative coalition came to power, the losing side obtained concessions, including public goods and the incorporation of previously unrepresented groups.Footnote 33

Peripheral elites also led the formation of new parties (Campos Harriet Reference Campos Harriet1979, 280). Radicalism in particular played a key role in pushing for democratization reforms. Their first manifesto promoted strengthening Congress and decreasing the executive’s power (Snow Reference Snow1972). Table 1 shows elections won by parties before and after 1861. This cutoff signifies the end of the conservative tenure.Footnote 34 Radicals dominated elections in both peripheries compared to the rest of the country, indicating that these elites were indeed incorporated into the political system.

Table 1 Representatives by Party

Source: Valencia Avaria (Reference Valencia Avaria1951).

Notes: Electoral districts changed over time, and did not fully align with other administrative boundaries like provinces or departments. Cells show the total number of elections, meaning there are some elections won by the same candidate.

Bureaucratic Imposition

The fiscal crisis made Araucanía highly attractive to the state. The area between the Biobío River and Patagonia was the last region suitable for wheat growing. Haciendas in central Chile had reached maximum productivity given technological and labor constraints, and many locations suffered soil erosion from deforestation to meet California’s demand for wheat (Schneider Reference Schneider1904). The government saw in Araucanía an opportunity to shift the country’s economic profile toward agriculture as early as 1867.Footnote 35 Technological improvements in military equipment, transportation, and engineering allowed the state, in alliance with private companies, to log the area and make it productive. Unlike other regions, Araucanía could not be used as a potential clientelistic bastion because the Mapuche were not enfranchised.

The ruling coalition invaded once Arauco’s intendant and military leader, Cornelio Saavedra, attempted to regulate the de facto expansion of private colonizers in 1861. Mapuche elites’ support for the 1859 rebellion and Concepción’s defeat helped to legitimize the incursion. Although the original project aimed only at rebuilding towns destroyed in previous wars, the incursion slowly became more encompassing. The state perceived the forests in the area—an essential element of Mapuche cosmology, diet, and economy—to be unmanaged nature and displaced the native population to reservations, creating sedentary communities and dissolving indigenous networks of exchange, trade, and migration (Klubock Reference Klubock2014, 31–32).

The state added one million hectares as early as 1871, yet a Mapuche uprising led to a stalemate.Footnote 36 Investments in railroads and telegraph lines allowed the central government to direct the war effort in real time. Together with improvements in weaponry, these advantages permitted the state to defeat outbreaks of Mapuche resistance. The effort to increase grain production drove the penetration of Araucanía. Figure 10 shows the expansion of the agricultural frontier. Provinces north of the Biobío River did not increase their production between 1875 and 1885.Footnote 37 On the other hand, the provinces south of the river experienced outstanding growth in these years.

Figure 10 Wheat Production in Selected Provinces

Source: Chilean national censuses.

The central government claimed ownership over occupied land, clearing large portions (Solberg Reference Solberg1969). From then on, state emissaries developed infrastructure and enforced property rights (Bengoa Reference Bengoa2002; Klubock Reference Klubock2014).Footnote 38 Figure 11 shows a population-adjusted measure of individuals who identified as bureaucrats, members of the police or the military, or engineers. The military intervention came first, followed by bureaucrats and engineers.Footnote 39 The military was in charge of defeating outbreaks of resistance and clearing land so engineers and surveyors could divide and measure plots (Bengoa Reference Bengoa2002, 46). While the number of engineers per capita was much lower than the other two categories, by 1895 there were three times as many engineers in Araucanía than the national average. The deployment of engineers is associated with state-building’s legibility dimension, as they are commonly hired to measure, assign value to, and divide land.

Figure 11 The Transition to Bureaucratic Rule in Araucanía

Source: Chilean national censuses.

The incursion into Araucanía demanded substantial investments and technical knowledge. The government helped to develop the civil engineering field, and included these experts in policy-making communities later on. The state-owned railway company (Empresa de Ferrocarriles del Estado, EFE), for instance, became a hub for the advancement of engineers. Slowly, they took over important roles in that company, helping them to acquire a high reputation among politicians and the broader public (Crowther Reference Crowther1973, 303; Guajardo Reference Guajardo2007, 26). The deployment of infrastructure into Araucanía through EFE and a topographic commission in charge of measuring plots gave engineers the necessary legitimacy to take over more policy-making spaces (Ibáñez Santa María Reference Ibáñez Santa María2003, 118). Engineers developed an “antipolitics” policy-making style and obtained de jure bureaucratic insulation (Crowther Reference Crowther1973, 400), and subsequent reforms created a meritocratic mechanism for the incorporation of engineers into the public administration. Governments replicated the railway company’s organizational and technical structure in other areas. By the 1920s, the practice of engineers assuming roles as decision makers expanded into the private sector (Ibáñez Santa María Reference Ibáñez Santa María2003, 119).

Patrimonial Reinforcement

The state reinforced patrimonial rule in the Central Valley to benefit landowners, who secured political and economic survival by keeping a clientelistic base within haciendas. Landlords’ control over peasants worked as insurance against expropriation, decreasing the costs for the conservative side to survive in an increasingly competitive environment. Landed elites opted for this strategy after they lost their seniority within the ruling coalition. The plan created legal and political boundaries to keep the state’s potential regulatory capacity away from landlords’ traditional sources of power.Footnote 40

Haciendas were highly authoritarian, self-contained systems. Inquilinos “lived and worked on the estates and depended on the patron for housing, for medical attention, for food, and the small plot of ground necessary for subsistence” (Kaufman Reference Kaufman1972, 22). The patrón (owner) could arbitrarily change work requirements and land allotted to each family at any point (Petras and Zemelman Merino Reference Petras, Merino and Flory1972, 54). Land inequality in the Central Valley was among the highest in the world, as fewer than three hundred people owned half of the agricultural land as late as 1935 (Carrière Reference Carrière1981, 30). While cities had policing institutions, the countryside “depended on a handful of ill-equipped constables, [and] ad hoc vigilante units led by the hacendados” (Bauer Reference Bauer1975, 166). Landlords also had de facto territorial sovereignty by controlling entry and exit into their properties (Loveman Reference Loveman1976, 34). By the late nineteenth century, these estates were not particularly productive. Instead, they became a source of status and prestige for the elite (Carrière Reference Carrière1981, 20).

Maintaining this institution (inquilinaje) was crucial for the viability of the landlords’ political goals. If inquilinos migrated to cities and became part of the urban poor, they could have become part of the Left’s political base. A transition to wage labor would have ended the system’s intrinsically paternalistic nature, hurting landlords’ chances of keeping peasants as an electoral base (Bauer Reference Bauer, Huber and Safford1995, 26–28). Keeping the hacienda-based social order intact would preserve the system of domination necessary to control peasants’ votes (30).Footnote 41

Two strategies were especially salient. First, Congress passed a law in 1874 that enfranchised literate males. While seemingly progressive, the effort aimed to create an electoral base across estates (Bauer Reference Bauer, Huber and Safford1995, 30). The bill was approved in the same months the conservative faction left the executive (Encina Reference Encina1949). The number of peasants enfranchised increased disproportionally between 1872 and 1876 across the Central Valley (J. S. Valenzuela Reference Valenzuela1985, 119). The literacy requirement was only enforced in cities, which gave landowners an advantage vis-à-vis urban parties. At the same time, conservatives were able to reform electoral boards, taking them away from the executive’s control. Second, landowners lobbied the executive through the Sociedad Nacional de Agricultura (Agricultural National Society, SNA). The group was originally created to push for price regulations in the 1890s and soon became the most influential lobbying association. Between 1873 and 1928, 20% of congressional members were SNA affiliates (Carrière Reference Carrière1981, 36–37). Together, these strategies helped landowners to maintain the status quo in the long run.

Change started in the 1930s, when labor inspectors began visiting estates to fine landowners over labor and housing-code violations. At the same time, leftist parties began unionizing peasants (Loveman Reference Loveman1976, 31). Arguably, subnational enclaves ended after the introduction of the secret ballot in 1958 and land reforms in the 1960s, effectively ending landlords’ control over peasants. Table 2 shows the evolution of political representation in Central Valley districts. In stark contrast to Atacama and Concepción, the right wing (Conservatives, Liberals, and Nationals) dominated, and the Radicals did not make any gains. The Right kept a sizable majority in Congress well into the twentieth century, even after the election of the first Radical government in 1938 (Correa Sutil Reference Correa Sutil2005, 71).

Table 2 Central Valley Representatives by Party

Source: Valencia Avaria (Reference Valencia Avaria1951).

Conclusions

This article suggests that state-building prospects hinge on the socioeconomic and physical profiles of subnational peripheral regions. States attempt to extend bureaucratic rule onto regions that have valuable commodities and advantageous geography. At the same time, their desire to optimize political support compels rulers to ally with landed elites that offer a clientelistic bastion. I build this theory by studying Chile, a case that stands out as a successful instance of capacity-building in Latin America. The Chilean state negotiated a transition to bureaucratic rule in Atacama to the north and Concepción to the south. Then, the state imposed bureaucratization in Araucanía, the home of the Mapuche in the far south. Finally, the government solidified its alliance with agrarian elites in the capital’s hinterland to secure electoral support.

Although Chile is often considered the poster child of the even projection of state power in Latin America, my argument shows that state-building was instead highly selective and uneven, with the very center being the most important deviation to uniform, bureaucratic rule. These projects created durable legacies. First, the effort to rule peripheries produced long-term gains in state capacity. Second, the enduring alliance between landed elites and the state helped the hacienda-based social order to survive mostly intact for a hundred years. This strategy allowed the Conservative party to gain a sizable portion of Congress and maintain the status quo well into the twentieth century, shaping Chile’s competitive yet highly restrictive regime. These results challenge the dominant geopolitical and legibility traditions by emphasizing how the need of elites to ensure their political and economic survival interacts with regional characteristics to create broad variation in the extent of rulers’ territorial reach and state capacity.

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Sebastian Mazzuca, Adam Sheingate, Adria Lawrence, Darcie Draudt-Véjares, Hillel Soifer, Consuelo Amat Matus, and four anonymous reviewers for their engaging and constructive feedback on previous drafts. The Johns Hopkins University’s SNF Agora Institute and the Program in Latin American, Caribbean, and Latinx Studies provided generous financial support.

Footnotes

*

Data replication sets are available in Harvard Dataverse at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/PKWB1F

1 Subnational regions are local socioeconomic orders that feature a set of elites, political traditions, trade networks, labor relations, and geographic features. Regions are “nonjurisdictional” (Soifer Reference Soifer, Giraudy, Moncada and Snyder2019) units, meaning that they do not necessarily align with administrative boundaries.

2 Even though the bellicist thesis has found less support outside Europe (e.g., Centeno Reference Centeno2002; Goenaga, Sabaté, and Teorell Reference Goenaga, Sabaté and Teorell2023; Queralt Reference Queralt2022), the evidence is mixed, as warfare did incentivize state-building in some circumstances (Feinstein and Wimmer Reference Feinstein and Wimmer2023; Saylor and Wheeler Reference Saylor and Wheeler2017; Schenoni Reference Schenoni2021). Several authors have disputed the role of warfare in Western Europe, emphasizing the role of religion instead (Fabbe Reference Fabbe2019; Gorski Reference Gorski2003; Grzymała-Busse Reference Grzymała-Busse2023) and the transition from early to mature feudalism (Anderson Reference Anderson2013).

3 Saylor (Reference Saylor2014) is the most remarkable exception.

4 Garfias (Reference Garfias2018) develops a similar framework.

5 Landed elites have been important allies to the state in other periods. According to Tilly (Reference Tilly and Tilly1975, 28), the ability of landlords to suppress the mobilization of peasants in Western Europe explains the survival and strength of landlords following the state-building process.

6 For recent works that discuss patrimonialism and bureaucratization as civil service reform, see Mazzuca and Munck (Reference Mazzuca and Munck2020) and Vogler (Reference Vogler, Jenkins and Rubin2022).

7 The difference between cooperative and imposed bureaucratization differs from Soifer’s (Reference Soifer2015) deployed and delegated rule. Although they may overlap empirically, cooperative bureaucratization entails a commitment between local and country-level elites, and does not account for the identity of administrative appointees.

8 The literature usually refers to this outcome as “indirect rule.” My conclusions are in line with works that suggest that indirect rule can be a successful state project (e.g., Gerring et al. Reference Gerring, Ziblatt, Van Gorp and Arévalo2011; Mamdani Reference Mamdani1996; Naseemullah and Staniland Reference Naseemullah and Staniland2016; Tilly Reference Tilly1992). In my perspective, however, successful state-building always implies the extension of bureaucratic rule.

9 The category “patrimonial reinforcement” is analogous to the “subnational enclave” concept in the literature on democratization (Gibson Reference Gibson2013; Mickey Reference Mickey2015).

10 Data in figure 4 is adjusted for inflation. This data is available in Braun-Llona et al. (Reference Braun-Llona, Braun-Llona, Briones, Díaz, Lüders and Wagner2000).

11 See the Treasury Ministry’s budgets for the years 1845, 1850, 1860, and 1880.

12 Beyond conflicts with Peru and Bolivia, Chile and Argentina experienced diplomatic conflicts due to territorial disputes over Patagonia. These incidents, however, never reached the existential threat identified in the literature on Western Europe.

13 I take a loose approach to the geographic term “Central Valley,” a set of valleys located roughly between Rancagua and Talca amid the Andes and the Chilean Coastal Range. In some historiographic and official documents, the region is called the “central nucleus,” yet this denomination also includes urban areas.

14 These administrative boundaries are taken from González, Compán, and Sagredo Baeza (Reference González, Compán and Baeza2016, 44–45). I have added Araucanía, demarcating its border with Concepción at the Biobío River. Atacama’s northern limit is delineated according to the administrative boundaries drawn after the War of the Pacific (69–70).

15 For a comprehensive illustration of each region’s ecological features, see Pissis (Reference Pissis1875).

16 Some traditional historiography traces the development of Chile’s centralized state to the early 1830s (e.g., Bravo Lira Reference Bravo Lira1985; Edwards [Reference Edwards1928] 2012; Góngora Reference Góngora1986). My interpretation is closer to recent works that focus on the importance of peripheries (e.g., Fernández Abara Reference Fernández Abara2016; Illanes Reference Illanes2003; Montory Reference Montory and Montory2020). This interpretation is supported by the original data presented in the empirical section.

17 According to Conservative lawmaker Abdón Cifuentes (Reference Cifuentes1936, 149), landed elites drafted “official” electoral lists that were later approved by the government. Originally cited in J. S. Valenzuela (Reference Valenzuela1985, 69).

18 Important works suggest that a distinctive feature of Chilean elites is their shared sociological and familial origins (e.g., Chambers Reference Chambers2015; Marcella Reference Marcella2000). I do not disagree with these accounts. Instead, my argument suggests that the peripheral coalitions that negotiated bureaucratization also included economic elites who were not originally part of those traditional oligarchies (see Fernández Abara Reference Fernández Abara2016; Mazzei de Grazia Reference Mazzei de Grazia2015). Recent works do suggest that the Chilean elite became increasingly diversified in the second half of the nineteenth century (e.g., Bro Reference Bro2023).

19 See the 1865 and 1875 censuses, and Sanhueza Benavente (Reference Sanhueza Benavente2018).

20 In his report to Congress in 1865, the Treasury minister wrote that “old worries are disappearing, and farmers—who used to be happy just to farm their land—are realizing that agriculture is set to become the country’s main source of wealth” (Chilean Treasury Ministry 1865, 98–99).

21 The government obtained loans in international markets in 1858 and 1865. However, Treasury ministers acknowledged that these were not enough to offset the deficit (Chilean Treasury Ministry 1865, 15, 28).

22 The western side of Patagonia was eventually incorporated through land grants to private actors to take advantage of the sheep farming boom of the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. I include the area in figure 5 to illustrate the ruling coalition’s lack of incentives to expand its rule into that area.

23 Estefane (Reference Estefane2016; Reference Estefane2019) shows that together with the introduction of censuses, the Chilean state undertook significant efforts to increase its legibility in the second half of the nineteenth century.

24 Censuses asked individuals to indicate their occupation. While questionnaires did not specify between levels of government, at the time the central government controlled local governments (municipalities) directly. For a historiographic account on the role of municipalities in the nineteenth century, see Salazar (Reference Salazar2019).

25 For recent accounts about the role of the state and local elites in Atacama’s nineteenth century, see Fernández Abara (Reference Fernández Abara2016), Fernández Abara and Jerez Leiva (Reference Fernández Abara, Leiva and Montory2020), Godoy Orellana (Reference Godoy Orellana2018), and Venegas Valdebenito (Reference Venegas Valdebenito2008).

26 The state did not increase its presence in a few departments north of Santiago either. Yet, this is due to the area’s desert climate, where no local economic order developed in the colonial period or afterward.

27 Chilean Treasury Ministry (1865, 66–68, 93).

28 Chilean Treasury Ministry (1870, 71–74; 1876, xxii).

29 Chilean Treasury Ministry (1865, 71–72).

30 Mazzuca (Reference Mazzuca2021) provides a comprehensive account of Argentina’s center–periphery conflict in this period.

31 My interpretation of the outcome of the 1859 civil war is close to Zeitlin’s (Reference Zeitlin1984). He suggests that the war allowed peripheral elites to become included in the political system (57), shaping a durable, albeit incomplete, competitive regime. Historiographic accounts by Collier (Reference Collier2003, 228–38) and Donoso (1946, 408–16) point in a similar direction.

32 The Treasury Ministry’s reports highlight the necessity to extend the state’s control over the provinces to offset the crisis (e.g., Chilean Treasury Ministry 1860, 10; 1865; 1870).

33 This interpretation differs from previous works that focus on the church–state conflict to explain the breakdown of the conservative coalition and the formation of the Liberal and Radical parties. (e.g., Collier Reference Collier2003, 93–94; Scully Reference Scully1992, 31–38; J. S. Valenzuela Reference Valenzuela1995, 7).

34 The liberal-led new ruling coalition was called the “Liberal-Conservative fusion” (1861–73). Conservatives remained in the coalition until 1873, but played a lesser role.

35 Chilean Ministry of the Interior (1867, 7).

36 Chilean Ministry of the Interior (1871, 9).

37 Aconcagua, Colchagua, and Ñuble were wheat-producing provinces.

38 Chilean Ministry of Foreign Affairs and Colonization (1879, xlvii).

39 Beginning in the 1875 census, engineers were classified as ingenieros o geomensores, “engineers or surveyors.” This distinction denotes an intended association between engineering and land measurement.

40 Similar to my findings, Suryanarayan and White (Reference Suryanarayan and White2021) show that local elites aim to weaken local bureaucratic capacity for long-term political goals.

41 Several works have evaluated inquilinaje as hacendados’ source of political power (e.g., Baland and Robinson Reference Baland and Robinson2008; Bauer Reference Bauer1975; Bengoa Reference Bengoa2015; Loveman Reference Loveman1976). My objective is to suggest that the reinforcement of patrimonialism in the region was a distinct state-building outcome.

References

Alesina, Alberto, and Spolaore, Enrico. 2003. The Size of Nations. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. DOI: 10.7551/mitpress/6261.001.0001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Perry. 2013. Lineages of the Absolutist State. New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Baland, Jean-Marie, and Robinson, James A.. 2008. “Land and Power: Theory and Evidence from Chile.” American Economic Review 98 (5): 1737–65. DOI: 10.1257/aer.98.5.1737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, Arthur S., and Wilson, Kenneth A.. 2021. Cross-National Time-Series Data [database]. Jerusalem: Databanks International. https://www.cntsdata.com.Google Scholar
Bauer, Arnold J. 1975. Chilean Rural Society: From the Spanish Conquest to 1930. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bauer, Arnold J. 1995. “Landlord and Campesino in the Chilean Road to Democracy.” In Agrarian Structure & Political Power: Landlord & Peasant in the Making of Latin America, eds. Huber, Evelyne and Safford, Frank, 2138. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. DOI: 10.2307/jj.5973238.5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bengoa, José. 2002. Historia de un Conflicto: El Estado y los Mapuches en el Siglo XX. Santiago: Planeta.Google Scholar
Bengoa, José. 2015. La Construcción del Valle Central de Chile, Vol. 1 of Historia Rural de Chile Central. Santiago: LOM Ediciones.Google Scholar
Bignon, Vincent, Esteves, Rui, and Herranz-Loncán, Alfonso. 2015. “Big Push or Big Grab? Railways, Government Activism and Export Growth in Latin America, 1865–1913.” The Economic History Review 68 (4): 12771305. DOI: 10.1111/ehr.12094.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boone, Catherine. 2003. Political Topographies of the African State: Territorial Authority and Institutional Choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511615597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brambor, Thomas, Goenaga, Agustín, Lindvall, Johannes, and Teorell, Jan. 2020. “The Lay of the Land: Information Capacity and the Modern State.” Comparative Political Studies 53 (2): 175213. DOI: 10.1177/0010414019843432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braun-Llona, Juan, Braun-Llona, Matías, Briones, Ignacio, Díaz, José, Lüders, Rolf, and Wagner, Gert. 2000. “Economía Chilena 1810–1995: Estadísticas Históricas.” Documento de Trabajo 187, January. Santiago: Instituto de Economia, Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile. https://www.economia.uc.cl/docs/doctra/dt-187.pdf.Google Scholar
Bravo Lira, Bernardino. 1985. De Portales a Pinochet: Gobierno y Régimen de Gobierno en Chile. Santiago: Editorial Jurídica de Chile.Google Scholar
Bro, Naím. 2023. “The Structure of Political Conflict. The Oligarchs and the Bourgeoisie in the Chilean Congress, 1834–1894.” Theory and Society 52 (3): 353–86. DOI: 10.1007/s11186-022-09491-3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campos Harriet, Fernando. 1979. Historia de Concepción 1550–1970. Santiago: Editorial Universitaria.Google Scholar
Carneiro, Robert L. 1970. “A Theory of the Origin of the State.” Science 169 (3947): 733–38. DOI: 10.1126/science.169.3947.733.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Carrière, Jean. 1981. Landowners and Politics in Chile: A Study of the Sociedad Nacional de Agricultura, 1932–1970. Amsterdam: Centrum voor Studie en Documentatie van Latijns-Amerika.Google Scholar
Centeno, Miguel Angel. 2002. Blood and Debt: War and the Nation-State in Latin America. University Park: Penn State University Press. DOI: 10.5325/j.ctv14gphb8.Google Scholar
Cermeño, Alexandra L, Enflo, Kerstin, and Lindvall, Johannes. 2022. “Railroads and Reform: How Trains Strengthened the Nation State.” British Journal of Political Science 52 (2): 715–35. DOI: 10.1017/S0007123420000654.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, Sarah C. 2015. Families in War and Peace: Chile from Colony to Nation. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. DOI: 10.1215/9780822375562.Google Scholar
Chilean Ministry of Foreign Affairs and Colonization. 1879. “Memoria del Ministro de Relaciones Exteriores y Colonización: Presenta al Congreso Nacional, Año de 1879.” Annual report to Congress. Santiago: Imprenta Nacional.Google Scholar
Chilean Ministry of the Interior. 1867. “Memoria que el Ministro de Estado en el Departamento de Interior: Presenta al Congreso Nacional, Año de 1867.” Annual report to Congress. Santiago: Imprenta Nacional.Google Scholar
Chilean Ministry of the Interior. 1871. “Memoria que el Ministro de Estado en el Departamento de Interior: Presenta al Congreso Nacional, Año de 1871.” Annual report to Congress. Santiago: Imprenta Nacional.Google Scholar
Chilean Treasury Ministry. 1860. “Memoria que el Ministro de Estado en el Departamento de Hacienda: Presenta al Congreso Nacional, Año de 1860.” Annual report to Congress. Santiago: Imprenta Nacional.Google Scholar
Chilean Treasury Ministry. 1865. “Memoria que el Ministro de Estado en el Departamento de Hacienda: Presenta al Congreso Nacional, Año de 1865.” Annual report to Congress. Santiago: Imprenta Nacional.Google Scholar
Chilean Treasury Ministry. 1870. “Memoria que el Ministro de Estado en el Departamento de Hacienda: Presenta al Congreso Nacional, Año de 1870.” Annual report to Congress. Santiago: Imprenta Nacional.Google Scholar
Chilean Treasury Ministry. 1876. “Memoria que el Ministro de Estado en el Departamento de Hacienda: Presenta al Congreso Nacional, Año de 1876.” Annual report to Congress. Santiago: Imprenta Nacional.Google Scholar
Cifuentes, Abdón. 1936. Memorias, Vol. 1. Santiago: Nascimento.Google Scholar
Collier, Simon. 2003. Chile: The Making of a Republic, 1830–1865: Politics and Ideas. New York: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511512070.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Correa Sutil, Sofía. 2005. Con las Riendas del Poder: La Derecha Chilena en el Siglo XX. Santiago: Editorial Sudamericana.Google Scholar
Crowther, Warren Winfield. 1973. “Technological Change as Political Choice: The Civil Engineers and the Modernization of the Chilean State Railways.” PhD diss. University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, Ernesto, Hernández-Lagos, Pablo, and Mazzuca, Sebastián. 2021. “The Paradox of Civilization: Preinstitutional Sources of Security and Prosperity.” American Political Science Review 116 (1): 213–30. DOI: 10.1017/s000305542100071x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Direcci ó n General de Contabilidad. 1901. Resúmen de la Hacienda Pública de Chile: Desde la Independencia Hasta 1900. Santiago: Imprenta Nacional.Google Scholar
Edwards, Agustín. 1932. Cuatro Presidentes de Chile, 1841–1876. Valparaíso: Sociedad Imprenta y Litografía Universo.Google Scholar
Edwards, Alberto. (1928) 2012. La Fronda Aristocrática en Chile. Santiago: Editorial Universitaria.Google Scholar
Encina, Francisco Antonio. 1949. Historia de Chile: Desde la Prehistoria Hasta 1891, Vol. 13. Santiago: Editorial Nascimento.Google Scholar
Ertman, Thomas. 1997. Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe. New York: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511529016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ertman, Thomas. 2017. “Otto Hintze, Stein Rokkan and Charles Tilly’s Theory of European State-Building.” In Does War Make States? Investigations of Charles Tilly’s Historical Sociology, eds. Kaspersen, Lars Bo and Strandsbjerg, Jeppe, 5270. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/9781316493694.003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Estefane, Andrés. 2016. “La Institucionalización del Sistema Estadístico Chileno: Debates y Problemas Prácticos (1843–1851).” Estudios Sociales del Estado 2 (4): 3573. DOI: 10.35305/ese.v2i4.90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Estefane, Andrés. 2019. “Bureaucracy and State Knowledge: On the Production of Statistics in Chile (1750s–1870s).” Nuevo Mundo, Mundos Nuevos 8. DOI: 10.4000/nuevomundo.76841.Google Scholar
Fabbe, Kristin. 2019. Disciples of the State? Religion and State-Building in the Former Ottoman World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/9781108296878.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feinstein, Yuval, and Wimmer, Andreas. 2023. “Consent and Legitimacy: A Revised Bellicose Theory of State-Building with Evidence from around the World, 1500–2000.” World Politics 75 (1): 188232. DOI: 10.1353/wp.2023.0003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández Abara, Joaquín. 2016. Regionalismo, Liberalismo y Rebelión: Copiapó en la Guerra Civil de 1859. Santiago: RIL Editores.Google Scholar
Fernández Abara, Joaquín, and Leiva, Dany Jerez. 2020. “Construyendo el Estado en la Frontera Minera. Atacama en el Siglo XIX.” In Región y Nación: La Construcción Provincial de Chile, Siglo XIX, ed. Montory, Armando Cartes, 91130. Santiago: Editorial Universitaria.Google Scholar
Fernández-Villaverde, Jesús, Koyama, Mark, Lin, Youhong, and Sng, Tuan-Hwee. 2023. “The Fractured-Land Hypothesis.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 138 (2): 11731231. DOI: 10.1093/qje/qjad003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfias, Francisco. 2018. “Elite Competition and State Capacity Development: Theory and Evidence from Post-Revolutionary Mexico.” American Political Science Review 112 (2): 339–57. DOI: 10.1017/S0003055417000715.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerring, John, Ziblatt, Daniel, Van Gorp, Johan, and Arévalo, Julián. 2011. “An Institutional Theory of Direct and Indirect Rule.” World Politics 63 (3): 377433. DOI: 10.1017/s0043887111000104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibson, Edward L. 2013. Boundary Control: Subnational Authoritarianism in Federal Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781139017992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giraudy, Agustina, and Luna, Juan Pablo. 2017. “Unpacking the State’s Uneven Territorial Reach: Evidence from Latin America.” In States in the Developing World, eds. Centeno, Miguel Angel, Kohli, Atul, and Yashar, Deborah J., with Mistree, Dinsha, 93120. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781316665657.005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Godoy Orellana, Milton. 2018. La Puerta del Desierto: Estado y Región en Atacama: Taltal, 1850–1900. Santiago: Mutante Editores.Google Scholar
Goenaga, Agustín, Sabaté, Oriol, and Teorell, Jan. 2023. “The State Does Not Live by Warfare Alone: War and Revenue in the Long Nineteenth Century.” The Review of International Organizations 18: 393418. DOI: 10.1007/s11558-022-09477-x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Góngora, Mario. 1986. Ensayo Histórico Sobre la Noción de Estado en Chile en los Siglos XIX y XX. Santiago de Chile: Editorial Universitaria.Google Scholar
González, José Ignacio, Compán, José, and Baeza, Rafael Sagredo. 2016. La Política en el Espacio: Atlas Histórico de las Divisiones Político-Administrativas de Chile, 1810–1940. Santiago: Centro de Investigaciones Diego Barros Arana. https://www.centrobarrosarana.gob.cl/622/articles-71237_archivo_01.pdf.Google Scholar
Gorski, Philip S. 2003. The Disciplinary Revolution: Calvinism and the Rise of the State in Early Modern Europe. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. DOI: 10.7208/chicago/9780226304861.001.0001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grzymała-Busse, Anna M. 2023. Sacred Foundations: The Religious and Medieval Roots of the European State. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. DOI: 10.1515/9780691245133.Google Scholar
Guajardo, Guillermo. 2007. Tecnología, Estado y Ferrocarriles En Chile, 1850–1950. Mexico: Fundación de los Ferrocarriles Españoles en coedición con el Centro de Investigaciones Interdisciplinarias en Ciencias y Humanidades de la Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México.Google Scholar
Herbst, Jeffrey. 2014. States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons in Authority and Control, 2nd edition. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. DOI: 10.1515/9781400852321.Google Scholar
Hintze, Otto. 1975. “Military Organization and the Organization of the State.” In The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze, ed. Gilbert, Felix, 178215. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Humud Tleel, Carlos. 1969. El Sector Público Chileno Entre 1830 y 1930. Santiago: Facultad de Ciencias Económicas, Universidad de Chile.Google Scholar
Humud Tleel, Carlos. 1974. “Política Económica Chilena Desde 1830 a 1930.” Estudios de Economía 1 (1): 1122.Google Scholar
Ibáñez Santa María, Adolfo. 2003. Herido en el Ala: Estado, Oligarquías y Subdesarrollo, Chile 1924–1960. Santiago: Editorial Biblioteca Americana.Google Scholar
Illanes, María Angélica. 2003. Chile Des-Centrado: Formación Socio-Cultural Republicana y Transición Capitalista 1810–1910. Santiago: LOM Ediciones.Google Scholar
Kaufman, Robert R. 1972. The Politics of Land Reform in Chile, 1950–1970: Public Policy, Political Institutions, and Social Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. DOI: 10.4159/harvard.9780674497085.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klubock, Thomas Miller. 2014. La Frontera: Forests and Ecological Conflict in Chile’s Frontier Territory. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. DOI: 10.1215/9780822376569.Google Scholar
Kurtz, Marcus J. 2013. Latin American State Building in Comparative Perspective: Social Foundations of Institutional Order. New York: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781139019668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Melissa M., and Zhang, Nan. 2017. “Legibility and the Informational Foundations of State Capacity.” The Journal of Politics 79 (1): 118–32. DOI: 10.1086/688053.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López Taverne, Elvira. 2014.El Proceso de Construcción Estatal en Chile: Hacienda Pública y Burocracia (1817–1860). Santiago: DIBAM.Google Scholar
López Taverne, Elvira. 2017. “El Proceso de Formación de la Burocracia Estatal Chilena, 1810–1930.” In Estado y Sociedad, eds. Jaksic, Iván and Rengifo, Francisca, 5586, Vol. 2 of Historia Política de Chile, 1810–2010, ed. Iván Jaksic. Santiago: Fondo de Cultura Económica.Google Scholar
Loveman, Brian. 1976. Struggle in the Countryside: Politics and Rural Labor in Chile, 1919–1973. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
Mamdani, Mahmood. 1996. Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy of Late Colonialism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. DOI: 10.2307/j.ctvc77c7w.Google Scholar
Mann, Michael. 2012a. A History of Power from the Beginning to AD 1760, Vol. 1 of The Sources of Social Power, 2nd edition. New York: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781139381307.Google Scholar
Mann, Michael. 2012b. The Rise of Classes and Nation-States, 1760–1914, Vol. 2 of The Sources of Social Power, 2nd edition. New York: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781139381314.Google Scholar
Marcella, Gabriel. 2000. The Structure of Politics in Nineteenth-Century Spanish America: The Chilean Oligarchy, 1833–1891. Notre Dame, IN: Notre Dame University Press.Google Scholar
Mazzei de Grazia, Leonardo. 2015. Historia Económica Regional de Concepción, 1800–1920. Concepción: Ediciones del Archivo Histórico de Concepción.Google Scholar
Mazzuca, Sebastián L. 2021. Latecomer State Formation: Political Geography and Capacity Failure in Latin America. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. DOI: 10.12987/yale/9780300248951.001.0001.Google Scholar
Mazzuca, L. Sebastián, and Munck, Gerardo L.. 2020. A Middle-Quality Institutional Trap: Democracy and State Capacity in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/9781108878449.Google Scholar
McBride, George McCutchen. 1936. Chile: Land and Society. Baltimore: The Lord Baltimore Press.Google Scholar
Montory, Armando Cartes. 2020. “Introducción: Hacia una Construcción Provincial de la Historia de Chile.” In Región y Nación: La Construcción Provincial de Chile, Siglo XIX, ed. Montory, Armando Cartes, 1954. Santiago: Editorial Universitaria.Google Scholar
Mickey, Robert. 2015. Paths out of Dixie: The Democratization of Authoritarian Enclaves in America’s Deep South. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. DOI: 10.23943/princeton/9780691133386.001.0001.Google Scholar
Moore, Barrington Jr. 1966. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Naseemullah, Adnan, and Staniland, Paul. 2016. “Indirect Rule and Varieties of Governance.” Governance 29 (1): 1330. DOI: 10.1111/gove.12129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Donnell, Guillermo. 1993. “On the State, Democratization and Some Conceptual Problems: A Latin American View with Glances at Some Postcommunist Countries.” World Development 21 (8): 1355–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American Political Science Review 87 (3): 567–76. DOI: 10.2307/2938736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petras, James, and Merino, Hugo Zemelman. 1972. Peasants in Revolt: A Chilean Case Study, 1965–1971, trans. Flory, T.. Austin: University of Texas Press. DOI: 10.7560/764040.Google Scholar
Pinto Rodríguez, Jorge. 2003. La Formación del Estado y la Nación, y el Pueblo Mapuche: De la Inclusión a la Exclusión. Santiago: DIBAM.Google Scholar
Pinto Rodríguez, Jorge. 2020. “Concepción y La Araucanía en el Siglo XIX: Un Proceso de Regionalización Frustrado.” In Región y Nación: La Construcción Provincial de Chile, Siglo XIX, ed. Montory, Armando Cartes, 321–57. Santiago: Editorial Universitaria.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pissis, Pedro José Amado. 1875. Atlas de la Geografía Física de la República de Chile. Paris: Instituto Geográfico de París.Google Scholar
Queralt, Didac. 2022. Pawned States: State Building in the Era of International Finance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. DOI: 10.23943/princeton/9780691231426.001.0001.Google Scholar
Salazar, Gabriel. 2019. Historia del Municipio y la Soberanía Comunal en Chile, 1820–2016. Santiago: Editorial Universitaria.Google Scholar
Sánchez Talanquer, Mariano. 2017. States Divided: “History, Conflict, and State Formation in Mexico and Colombia.” PhD diss. Cornell University.Google Scholar
Sanhueza Benavente, María Carolina. 2018. Por los Caminos del Valle Central de Chile: El Sistema Vial entre los Ríos Maipo y Mataquito (1790–1860). Santiago: DIBAM.Google Scholar
Saylor, Ryan. 2014. State Building in Boom Times: Commodities and Coalitions in Latin America and Africa. New York: Oxford University Press. DOI: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199364954.001.0001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saylor, Ryan, and Wheeler, Nicholas C.. 2017. “Paying for War and Building States: The Coalitional Politics of Debt Servicing and Tax Institutions.” World Politics 69 (2): 366408. DOI: 10.1017/s0043887116000319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schenoni, Luis L. 2021. “Bringing War Back In: Victory and State Formation in Latin America.” American Journal of Political Science 65 (2): 405–21. DOI: 10.1111/ajps.12552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, Teodoro. 1904. La Agricultura en Chile en los Últimos Cincuenta Años. Santiago: Imprenta, Litografía i Encuadernación Barcelona.Google Scholar
Scott, James C. 1998. Seeing like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. DOI: 10.12987/9780300128789.Google Scholar
Scott, James C. 2009. The Art of Not Being Governed: An Anarchist History of Upland Southeast Asia. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. DOI: 10.12987/9780300156522.Google Scholar
Scully, Timothy R. 1992. Rethinking the Center: Party Politics in Nineteenth and Twentieth Century Chile. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Slater, Dan, and Kim, Diana. 2015. “Standoffish States: Nonliterate Leviathans in Southeast Asia.” TRaNS: Trans-Regional and National Studies of Southeast Asia 3 (1): 2544. DOI: 10.1017/trn.2014.14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snow, Peter G. 1972. Radicalismo Chileno: Historia y Doctrina del Partido Radical. Santiago: Editorial Francisco De Aguirre.Google Scholar
Soifer, Hillel David. 2015. State Building in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781316257289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soifer, Hillel David. 2019. “Units of Analysis in Subnational Research.” In Inside Countries: Subnational Research in Comparative Politics, eds. Giraudy, Agustina, Moncada, Eduardo, and Snyder, Richard, 92112. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/9781108678384.003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solberg, Carl E. 1969. “A Discriminatory Frontier Land Policy: Chile, 1870–1914.” The Americas 26 (2): 115–33. DOI: 10.2307/980294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suryanarayan, Pavithra, and White, Steven. 2021. “Slavery, Reconstruction, and Bureaucratic Capacity in the American South.” American Political Science Review 115 (2): 568–84. DOI: 10.1017/S0003055420000933.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thies, Cameron G. 2005. “War, Rivalry, and State Building in Latin America.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (3): 451–65. DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-5907.2005.00134.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1975. “Reflections on the History of European State-Making.” In The Formation of National States in Western Europe, ed. Tilly, Charles, 383. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1985. “War Making and State Making as Organized Crime.” In Bringing the State Back In, eds. Skocpol, Theda, Evans, Peter B., and Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, 169–91. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511628283.008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1992. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–1992, rev. edition. Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Valencia Avaria, Luis. 1951. Anales de La República: Textos Constitucionales de Chile y Registro de los Ciudadanos que han Integrado los Poderes Ejecutivo y Legislativo desde 1810. Santiago: Imprenta Universitaria.Google Scholar
Valenzuela, J. Samuel. 1985. Democratización Vía Reforma: La Expansión del Sufragio en Chile. Buenos Aires: Ediciones del IDES.Google Scholar
Valenzuela, J. Samuel. 1995. “Orígenes y Transformaciones Del Sistema de Partidos En Chile.” Estudios Públicos 58: 580.Google Scholar
Valenzuela, Luis. 1992. “The Chilean Copper Smelting Industry in the Mid-Nineteenth Century: Phases of Expansion and Stagnation, 1834–58.” Journal of Latin American Studies 24 (3): 507–50. DOI: 10.1017/S0022216X00024263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Véjares, Maximiliano. 2024. “Replication Data for: Varieties of State-Building: Ecology, Clientelism, and Bureaucratic Rule in Chile.” Harvard Dataverse. DOI: 10.7910/DVN/PKWB1F.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Venegas Valdebenito, Hernán. 2008. El Espejismo de la Plata: Trabajadores y Empresarios Mineros en una Economía en Transición: Atacama, 1830–1870. Santiago: Editorial USACH.Google Scholar
Vogler, Jan P. 2022. “Bureaucracies in Historical Political Economy.” In The Oxford Handbook of Historical Political Economy, eds. Jenkins, Jeffery A. and Rubin, Jared. Oxford: Oxford University Press. DOI: 10.1093/oxfordhb/9780197618608.013.19.Google Scholar
Vom Hau, Matthias, Peres-Cajías, José Alejandro, and Soifer, Hillel David. 2023. “No Taxation without Informational Foundation: On the Role of Legibility in Tax State Development.” Journal of Institutional Economics 19 (3): 426–43. DOI: 10.1017/S1744137422000534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Max. (1921) 1978. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, 2 vols, eds. and trans. Roth, Guenther and Wittich, Claus. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Zeitlin, Maurice. 1984. The Civil Wars in Chile: (Or the Bourgeois Revolutions that Never Were). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. DOI: 10.1515/9781400857562.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 A Typology of Ecological Suitability for State-Building

Figure 1

Figure 2 Regions’ Attributes and State-Building OutcomesNote: Figure assumes that money borrowing is no longer an option and assumes the presence of regions that can be made productive.

Figure 2

Figure 3 States’ Territorial Reach in South AmericaSource: Banks and Wilson (2021).

Figure 3

Figure 4 Chile’s Annual Budget, 1845–78Source: Interior Ministry budgets.

Figure 4

Figure 5 Chile’s Regions

Figure 5

Figure 6 Chile: Outline of the Argument

Figure 6

Figure 7 Territorial Reach of the State, 1865–1920Notes: White and black dots represent one standard deviation—positive and negative, respectively—from the mean. Given that departments’ limits were often drawn decades after census data were taken, the figure shows each department’s capitals instead of administrative boundaries. See González, Compán, and Sagredo Baeza (2016, 311).

Figure 7

Figure 8 Spatial Distribution of Public Goods, 1899Source: Dirección General de Contabilidad (1901).

Figure 8

Figure 9 Bureaucrats’ Wages, 1845–78Source: Interior Ministry budgets.Notes: Budget data were produced at the province level. The average includes every province except for Atacama and Concepción. The number of observations varies as new departments were created over time.

Figure 9

Table 1 Representatives by Party

Figure 10

Figure 10 Wheat Production in Selected ProvincesSource: Chilean national censuses.

Figure 11

Figure 11 The Transition to Bureaucratic Rule in AraucaníaSource: Chilean national censuses.

Figure 12

Table 2 Central Valley Representatives by Party

Supplementary material: Link

Véjares Dataset

Link