Even from my sickbed, even if you are going to lower me into the grave and I feel that something is going wrong, I will get up. Those who believe that after I have left the government as prime minister, I will go into a permanent retirement really should have their heads examined.
— Lee Kuan Yew, on the National Day Rally of 1988, two years before he stepped down as the Prime Minister of Singapore.
Contrary to the popular perception that they are all almighty despots with unrivaled authority, political leaders in authoritarian regimes exhibit wide variations in their personal power (Baturo Reference Baturo2014; Geddes Reference Geddes2003; Svolik Reference Svolik2012). While some leaders manage to concentrate a formidable amount of power in their own hands and achieve a dominant position within a ruling coalition, others have to follow the norm of collective rule and regularly share power with their elite colleagues. The varying configurations of the balance of power within authoritarian regimes can have profound consequences for domestic governance (Bueno de Mesquita et al. Reference Bueno de Mesquita2003; Djuve, Knutsen, and Wig Reference Djuve, Knutsen and Wig2019; Frantz et al. Reference Frantz2020; Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2019; Meng Reference Meng2020; Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Wright and Escribà-Folch Reference Wright and Escribà-Folch2012), as well as for international relations (Colgan and Weeks Reference Colgan and Weeks2014; Weeks Reference Weeks2012).
A rapidly expanding body of scholarship has ventured to explain what gives rise to the different levels of power concentration among autocratic leaders (Boix and Svolik Reference Boix and Svolik2013; Brownlee Reference Brownlee2007a; Frantz and Stein Reference Frantz and Stein2017; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Geddes Reference Geddes2003; Gehlbach and Keefer Reference Gehlbach and Keefer2011; Gehlbach and Keefer Reference Gehlbach and Keefer2012; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008; Meng Reference Meng2020; Reuter Reference Reuter2017). The prevailing view in the literature is that authoritarian regimes with strong organizations and institutional procedures tend to be more successful at curbing incumbent leaders' despotic tendencies and sustaining power-sharing arrangements among ruling elites. However, to the extent that institutions are ultimately human creations, their emergence (or the lack thereof) may be endogenous to deeper, less observable political and coalitional dynamics (Pepinsky Reference Pepinsky2014), and their effectiveness as constraints cannot always be taken for granted (Levitsky and Murillo Reference Levitsky and Murillo2009; Meng Reference Meng2019). Empirically, we also observe considerable variation in personal power among leaders from the same regime or even over the tenure of the same leader. How do we make sense of these ebbs and flows of power when the broader institutional variables are largely held constant?
This article provides a new perspective on power dynamics in authoritarian regimes by focusing on the informal constraints in high-level elite politics. We conceptualize informal constraints as the deeper and sometimes covert configurations of actors, networks, and coalitions between the ruling elites. We argue that such constraints define important parameters of elite politics, such as the amount of discretion the incumbent enjoys in making key political decisions, the size and the kind of patronage resources s/he can control, and the potential consequences for breaking power-sharing pacts with other elites. Unlike institutions, which are relatively stable over time, informal constraints are often dynamic and constantly evolve in response to many internal and external factors. The nature and strength of incumbent autocrats’ constraints at a given moment sets the scope for feasible political strategies and can influence their ability to personalize power successfully.
To illustrate how this perspective can help us better understand intra-elite power dynamics, we study a particular set of informal constraints common in relatively institutionalized autocracies – the presence of retired political leaders. Leadership turnover is an important yet highly sensitive issue in authoritarian politics (Burling Reference Burling1974; Huntington and Moore Reference Huntington and Moore1970; Meng Reference Meng2021; Treisman Reference Treisman2015; Tullock Reference Tullock1987). In regimes that have undergone one or more rounds of pre-mortem successions, new top leaders often enter office when prominent individuals from the previous generations are still alive and active. Despite having relinquished much of their formal power, those retired leaders often retain considerable informal influence over politics and policies through the contacts and networks they cultivated during their time in office. We argue that they can impose an informal yet important check on the incumbent ruler by serving as the potential focal points for other elites to coordinate counterbalancing actions.
Our empirical analysis leverages a global sample of autocracies between 1950 and 2019 to examine whether and how the presence of influential retired leaders affects the personal power of the incumbent ruler vis-à-vis other elites. Empirically, studying intra-regime power dynamics faces two main challenges. The first one is measurement. It is usually difficult to measure a political leader's power precisely and objectively, let alone compare it across time and different country settings. To overcome this challenge, we develop a novel measure of personal power for top national leaders by using two massive online databases: Google Books Ngram (Google Ngram or Ngram hereafter) and Wikidata. Our approach builds on a burgeoning body of recent literature using printed publications to make inferences about the political actors’ power (Ban et al. Reference Ban2018; Jaros and Pan Reference Jaros and Pan2017). We first compile a comprehensive list of prominent living politicians for each country-year spell covered in our sample based on biographical information from Wikidata and then use Google Ngram to compute a power index based on the ratio between the number of publications that mention a top political leader's name and the number of publications that mention other influential (living) political figures from the same country and same year. Through several case-by-case comparisons and systematic validation tests, we show that our measure not only exhibits a strong consistency with the existing measures of regime types, institutional constraints, and personalism but also does a better job than the existing measures at capturing the subtle yet important variations in personal power over a leader's tenure. We also show that our measure correlates well with various other outcomes and metrics that are often used as proxies of power, such as tenure length, vote share in elections, and expert assessments of leaders' political influence.
In addition to measurement, the second empirical challenge is causal identification. The presence and relative significance of retired leaders may be correlated with various other regime characteristics that can influence an incumbent's personal power. To overcome this problem, our main empirical design exploits within-incumbent variations in retired leaders' strength that come exclusively from retired leaders’ deaths (mostly natural). This design essentially removes all the unobserved, time-invariant heterogeneity across incumbent leaders. It enables us to focus solely on the change in power within the same leader before and after the passing of his most influential predecessor.
Our empirical results provide strong evidence that retired leaders play a significant role in limiting the personal power of the incumbents. According to the within-person estimates, the presence of a former leader from the same political regime reduces, on average, the incumbent autocrat's power by about 17 per cent of a standard deviation in the short run and by about 24 per cent of a standard deviation in the long run. Through a series of additional tests, we show that our findings are robust to various modifications to the sample coverage, model specifications, and coding of the dependent and independent variables. We also demonstrate that the estimated effects are not driven by unobserved shocks common to all leadership turnovers, but are only present for within-regime transitions wherein predecessors exit power relatively consensually.
Finally, we provide some suggestive evidence on how predecessors retain and exercise their influence in retirement. Our analysis draws on the existing measures for regimes’ leadership and institutions and new measures of power distribution within regimes' ruling cabinets, built by applying our Ngram-based method to a newly available global dataset on cabinet members (Nyrup and Bramwell Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020). We find that instead of affecting the more formal and conspicuous aspects of political institutions, such as elections, legislatures, or parties, the constraining effect of former leaders is often exerted in a highly specific and informal way – by limiting the successor's personal discretion over the appointment and removal of key supporting elites that are essential to his exercise of power.
This study advances our understanding of power dynamics in authoritarian regimes in two ways. First, we offer a new perspective for thinking about how power is shared in authoritarian regimes. Existing literature often conceptualizes authoritarian power-sharing in a context-free way as the interaction between a dictator and a group of lesser elites who want to protect their power from the encroachment of the dictator (Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008; Meng Reference Meng2020; Myerson Reference Myerson2008; Svolik Reference Svolik2009). Our analysis highlights a different power-sharing mode wherein the central cleavage is organized between current and former autocrats. We provide evidence that the inter-generational model is effective in constraining the behaviours of incumbents because of the involvement of senior political actors. However, these constraints are inherently uncertain and impermanent because they depend heavily on the personal influence of former leaders.
Second, our analysis provides a new explanation for why significant power personalization happens under some leaders but not others, even when those leaders face the same kinds of institutional constraints. While the conventional narratives typically attribute successful power grabs to relatively idiosyncratic factors, such as a leader's luck (Svolik Reference Svolik2012, 62) or the use of certain political tactics (Slater Reference Slater2003), our findings suggest that structural factors in the political environment also play a role. Incumbent leaders are more likely to secure and expand their dominance when there is no influential retired leader in the elite circle to act as a counterweight against their strategic maneuvers.
Moreover, by constructing a new Ngram-based measure of leadership power, our paper makes a methodological contribution to the comparative study of political leaders and elites. Power is a key concept in the study of elite politics, and numerous formal models of conflict and political regimes have made theoretical predictions about the distribution and dynamics of power within the ruling elites (Acemoglu, Egorov, and Sonin Reference Acemoglu, Egorov and Sonin2008; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008; Meng Reference Meng2020; Svolik Reference Svolik2009). However, systematic empirical testing of those models has so far been hampered by our ability to accurately and objectively measure the power of individual political actors. Our measure offers a new way to capture the ebbs and flows of political leaders and elites' power that provides rich within-person variations and depends less on the subjective judgement of coders. By incorporating extensive biographical records from Wikidata, an important feature of our measure is that it enables researchers to examine, on a common scale, the relative influence of a large group of individuals that include not only national leaders but also cabinet members, sub-national leaders, leaders of key industries, and ethnic/religious groups. These unique features can support the development of more sophisticated measures of intra-elite power balance and help answer important questions about the distribution of influence both within a state and between the state and society.
Informal Constraints in Authoritarian Power Politics
Autocracies are highly heterogeneous in terms of their internal distribution of power.Footnote 1 The literature often explains the variation in power concentration across autocratic leaders through the lens of regimes' institutional features. A large body of research argues that regimes with a strong ruling party tend to do a better job at curbing the personalistic tendencies of top leaders (Boix and Svolik Reference Boix and Svolik2013; Geddes Reference Geddes2003; Kroeger Reference Kroeger2018; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008). Other works have examined the constraining role of semi-competitive elections, legislatures, and constitutions, showing that these institutions can make it costly for rulers to expropriate property from the elites and limit rulers' discretion over policies and the allocation of patronage goods (Albertus and Menaldo Reference Albertus and Menaldo2012; Blaydes Reference Blaydes2010; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Gandhi and Lust-Okar Reference Gandhi and Lust-Okar2009; Gehlbach and Keefer Reference Gehlbach and Keefer2011; Gehlbach and Keefer Reference Gehlbach and Keefer2012; Miller Reference Miller2015; Wright Reference Wright2008). More recently, some studies have suggested that concrete organizational rules, such as those that govern leadership successions and elite appointments, can also constrain the ruler by shaping the underlying power distribution among the elites (Frantz and Stein Reference Frantz and Stein2017; Meng Reference Meng2020).
This institution-centered perspective offers valuable insights into what affects the power balance between rulers and elites, but it also raises a number of questions. First of all, what enables institutions, which are ultimately man-made artifacts, to emerge and function properly in the first place? This question is especially relevant for autocracies, as rulers in those regimes typically enjoy much greater leeway in altering, modifying, and manipulating existing institutions than their democratic counterparts (Pepinsky Reference Pepinsky2014). Some theoretical works suggest that authoritarian institutions can only work under certain conditions, such as when there is a balance of coercive power within the ruling coalition (Boix and Svolik Reference Boix and Svolik2013; Meng Reference Meng2020; Przeworski, Rivero, and Xi Reference Przeworski, Rivero and Xi2015), yet it still begs the question of what factors contribute to or undermines this balance of power among the elites. Second, and more importantly, this perspective cannot explain why some dictators are able to accumulate more power than others, even though the formal institutions under which they take office are more or less the same. For example, in Malaysia, Romania, and more recently, China, there have been episodes of significant expansion of personal power by ambitious leaders under highly institutionalized regime parties (Fischer Reference Fischer1989; Li Reference Li2016; Slater Reference Slater2003). In other cases, top leaders came to office with a low-profile, collegial persona but went on to achieve a significant degree of dominance over their colleagues. How do we make sense of these within-regime (and even within-leader) variations in top leaders' personal power?
We argue that to better understand these variations, researchers need to look beyond the characteristics of formal institutions and pay greater attention to a broader set of informal constraints that operate within or alongside the formal apparatus of the regime. These constraints, which are usually less visible to outsiders than overt institutions, are based on deeper configurations of networks, coalitions, and resource distribution among elite actors. They may come from ‘the political dynamics of rivalries, factions, and power plays within a regime; the need to hold together a diverse coalition of supporters; or the need to gain the cooperation of key economic actors’ (Barros Reference Barros2002). Unlike written rules and procedures, which specify the formal boundaries of an incumbent's authority, informal constraints mainly impose de facto limits on what a top leader can and cannot do in intra-elite interactions. For example, these constraints can determine who the autocrat can seek as an ally, the amount of resources s/he can marshal, and the payoffs associated with various strategic choices. A leader with strong pre-existing ties to elites controlling key military and civilian offices may be more effective at solidifying his/her position in the ruling coalition than someone not yet deeply embedded in the elite network.Footnote 2 Likewise, an autocrat's strategy to divide and conquer the elites may work less well when other influential figures coordinate elites in different parts of the network and act as a focal point for their collective resistance (Luo and Rozenas Reference Luo and Rozenas2023).
Our conception of informal constraints differs from the concept of informal institutions, which often refer to the unwritten but largely stable norms and expectations governing actors' behaviours (Grzymala-Busse Reference Grzymala-Busse2010; Helmke and Levitsky Reference Helmke and Levitsky2004). Although informal institutions can sometimes be a crucial constitutive part of informal constraints, not all constraints are necessarily stable – many can change dynamically over time. In some cases, the change may be a result of intended actions taken by powerful and strategically minded actors to alter the composition and internal alignments of the elite corps. In other cases, significant changes can also occur in a relatively exogenous way. For example, an unanticipated death or incapacitation of a key political figure can sometimes induce sweeping shifts in the patterns of coalitions among the remaining elites (Acemoglu, Egorov, and Sonin Reference Acemoglu, Egorov and Sonin2008), while external economic or political shocks may increase the bargaining power of certain groups or factions while decreasing the leverage of others (Pepinsky Reference Pepinsky2015). These various contingencies are often not directly controlled or willed by the ruler (or any member of the ruling elite), but can have important bearings on how the power game plays out among the elites.
Leadership Retirement and Inter-Generational Power Constraints
Informal constraints can take a variety of forms depending on the political context. To provide a more focused illustration of how these constraints matter for intra-elite power dynamics, we examine a specific set of constraints associated with leadership retirement in this article. This focus is motivated by two reasons. First, succession is a fundamental challenge faced by all regimes that do not select leaders via competitive elections (Herz Reference Herz1952; Huntington and Moore Reference Huntington and Moore1970; Meng Reference Meng2021; Spearman Reference Spearman1939). Within the set of relatively institutionalized autocracies where there is often a norm against life-long tenure, the retirement of top leadership is a sufficiently common phenomenon that can be analyzed systematically.Footnote 3 Second, and more importantly, studying retired leaders can provide useful analytical leverage because of their unique political status: they are formally out of office but may still possess considerable informal influence among the elites. This helps us effectively distinguish between the formal and informal sources of power constraints in autocracies.
Autocratic successions are inherently difficult to manage because they must address two simultaneous challenges: peaceful entry by the successor and peaceful exit by the predecessor (Meng Reference Meng2021). These two challenges require potentially conflicting solutions. To ensure peaceful entry, a successor usually needs to be designated in advance and be given sufficient authority to rule so that heFootnote 4 will be able to withstand potential challenges from elites upon the predecessor's eventual departure (Kokkonen and Sundell Reference Kokkonen and Sundell2014; Kurrild-Klitgaard Reference Kurrild-Klitgaard2000; Meng Reference Meng2021). However, if a successor becomes too powerful too quickly, he may turn into a threat to the old leader (Burling Reference Burling1974; Herz Reference Herz1952). In a classic formulation of the problem known as the crown-prince dilemma, a capable but impatient heir may try to stage a coup against the dictator and take over early (Tullock Reference Tullock1987; Zhou Reference Zhou2021). Even when the exit per se is relatively peaceful, once the predecessor is out of office, the successor will have many opportunities to take actions that can hurt the predecessor's political or personal interests (Acemoglu, Egorov, and Sonin Reference Acemoglu, Egorov and Sonin2010). These actions may include changing the course of policy set by the predecessor (Bunce Reference Bunce2014) or replacing her appointees with the successor's own supporters. Sometimes, the need to establish his reputation and authority may motivate the successor to launch direct attacks on the predecessor's close associates, family members, and even herself. While the successor can make promises about respecting the predecessor's core interests before coming to office, once he takes power, he often cannot credibly commit to such promises without effective external enforcement.
The presence of this thorny succession dilemma is an important reason why many rulers choose to hold office until death and postpone the designation of a successor for as long as possible. However, it also means that when pre-mortem successions do happen, as they have done in many relatively institutionalized regimes, the departing leader will have an incentive to put in place arrangements that will tie the hands of her successor when he comes to office.Footnote 5 The incentive may come from the desire to protect one's policy legacies, the need to safeguard key political and economic interests for one's family members and close associates, or both.Footnote 6 In some cases, having such arrangements in place might be a critical precondition for an ageing leader to agree to a voluntary exit in the first place.Footnote 7
Outgoing leaders' management of pre-mortem successions often involves a variety of formal and informal maneuvers. In the formal realm, they may try to create additional institutional constraints (or strengthen the existing ones), such as high-level supervisory bodies, mandatory collective decision-making procedures, or explicit term limits on leaders' tenure (Ma Reference Ma2016; Meng Reference Meng2020). For example, Lee Kuan Yew, the former Prime Minister of Singapore, created a new advisory position for himself before stepping down in 1990 to make sure that he could continue to stay abreast of the next leadership's major decisions and intervene when necessary (Mauzy and Milne Reference Mauzy and Milne2002). More recently, Nursultan Nazarbayev, the long-serving autocrat in Kazakhstan, also began a managed succession process by initiating a series of reforms that would significantly strengthen the institutional oversight of the chief executive office that he intended to pass on to his successor.Footnote 8
Aside from altering the formal institutions, many other constraining measures that outgoing leaders take are informal in nature. Those measures are sometimes substitutes for, but at other times complementary to, institution-level changes (Helmke and Levitsky Reference Helmke and Levitsky2004). For example, appointing trusted allies to critical military and political positions is one of the most commonly used strategies that embed informal maneuvers within a formal institutional setting. The presence of a sizable number of the former leader's loyalists in the subsequent administration helps dilute the successor's power and prolongs the old leader's influence beyond her formal tenure. When Julius Nyerere, the founding leader of Tanzania, retired in 1985, he left behind an extensive network of loyal supporters in the military and security apparatus. This group of officers, drawn predominantly from the ethnic group of Kurya and owing their allegiance to Nyerere personally, acted as a significant counterweight to Nyerere's successor, Ali Hassan Mwinyi, in the subsequent administration. This enabled Nyerere to remain influential in Tanzanian politics long after he retired (Southall Reference Southall, Southall and Melber2006). Similarly, Deng Xiaoping and Jiang Zemin, the two leaders who oversaw the Chinese Communist Party's first two peaceful, pre-mortem successions, both planted trusted proxies in high-level political and military offices before they stepped down and used those appointees to monitor and counterbalance their successors' actions (Li Reference Li2016).
Of all senior civilian and military appointments, one specific area over which departing leaders will often try to limit their successors' discretion is the selection of the successors' own heirs. When powerful Chinese leaders like Mao Zedong and Deng Xiaoping planned their respective retirements, they not only designated an immediate successor but also made deliberate efforts to cultivate younger figures who were expected to eventually take over from that immediate successor (Vogel Reference Vogel2013; Zhang Reference Zhang2011). In Singapore and Malaysia, strong leaders like Lee Kuan Yew and Mahathir Mohamad similarly made plans for the next two generations of successors when they were going into retirement (Brownlee Reference Brownlee2007b; Chin Reference Chin, Chin and Dosch2015). For the successor, the prospect that he will eventually pass power to a younger leader closer to the retired predecessor limits the extent to which the successor can or is willing to deviate from the predecessor's legacy. The presence of alternative power centres within the reigning leadership gives the retired leader unique leverage to exploit intra-elite cleavages and act as the ultimate adjudicator/mediator between competing factions in the sitting leadership.
While the inter-generational constraints may involve a diverse range of formal and informal arrangements, their effectiveness in constraining the successor ultimately depends on the amount of political capital that the predecessor personally possesses. A healthy, active former leader with extensive networks throughout key state and military sectors can play a central role in organizing collective resistance against the successor's personalistic tendencies. When Miguel Alemán Valdés was mulling over a second presidential term, which would have broken Mexico's convention of a one-term presidency, Lázaro Cádenas, one of the regime's most eminent former presidents alive at that time, defended the institution of term limits by mobilizing a group of alienated elites within the Institutional Revolutionary Party (PRI) to support an alternative candidate for the presidency. This quasi-opposition movement eventually forced Alemán to backtrack and offer a compromise candidate instead (Smith Reference Smith and Bethell1991).Footnote 9
By contrast, these constraints have limited efficacy when the predecessor is politically weak or becomes physically incapacitated (or even dies). Being the leader of an elite coalition often requires specific human capital endowment (for example, seniority, charisma, personal networks, etc.), and this role cannot be easily taken up by another person when the current leader is gone. Without a commonly recognized figure to resolve disputes and coordinate actions, it can become much more difficult to hold together a cohesive elite coalition against the incumbent. In some cases, the former leader might even deliberately keep her associates at a distance from one another in order to secure an exclusively central position for herself in the coalition. This may further reduce the likelihood that those associates will continue to band together after the passing of the former leader.Footnote 10 Internal rivalries and disagreements may be exploited by a tactically savvy successor to his own advantage. For example, Xi Jinping's quick consolidation of power within the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) after 2012 was primarily aided by the political weakness of his predecessor. Several other notable episodes of power consolidation in party-based regimes, such as those by Nicolae Ceausescu, Mahathir Mohamad, and Daniel arap Moi, also took place in an environment where the most dominant figure from the early generation had either died or was seriously ill.Footnote 11 Although nothing can guarantee the success of an attempted power grab, an environment in which the old guard is weak or absent is likely to give the incumbent more room for strategic maneuvering than one in which it remains healthy and active.Footnote 12
Taken together, the preceding discussion suggests that the presence or absence of retired leaders (and their political strength) is one of the key constraints that can influence the power of the incumbent leader. This leads to the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1. All else equal, incumbent leaders face greater constraints over their power when operating in an environment in which their predecessors are alive and active. Moreover, a predecessor with greater political clout should be more effective at tying the hands of her successors.
Empirical Design
Sample Construction
To test the above hypothesis, we constructed and analysed a panel dataset of authoritarian regimes in the post-Second World War era. Our dataset builds on an updated and expanded version of the authoritarian regime spell dataset by Svolik (Reference Svolik2012) and merges additional country-level institutional and socioeconomic information from several other existing datasets.Footnote 13 We follow convention to identify the de facto head of the executive branch as the leader of an authoritarian regime. Generally speaking, this means presidents in presidential or semi-presidential systems, prime ministers in parliamentary systems, and general secretaries in communist regimes. In some cases, we have to deviate from this rule either because these positions are not available/unoccupied or because leaders serving in these positions are considerably more junior than senior contemporaneous figures in other positions. We handled these special cases with extra caution, often consulting a number of biographical sources and existing datasets (Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland Reference Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland2009; Goemans, Gleditsch, and Chiozza Reference Goemans, Gleditsch and Chiozza2009; Przeworski Reference Przeworski2013; Svolik Reference Svolik2012) before making a decision. Typically, we require the person identified as the de facto leader to hold at least some kind of senior formal position (government, party, or military) to avoid relying purely on subjective judgement.Footnote 14
The full dataset includes 4,799 country-year observations from 265 regimes in 122 countries between 1950 and 2019. A total of 472 leadership transitions are recorded in the full dataset, of which 181 (38.5 per cent) took the form of a pre-mortem, consensual exit.Footnote 15 For our specific analysis of the inter-generational constraints, we use a trimmed sample that excludes observations where incumbent leaders are regime founders (that is, the first leader of a regime) who naturally do not have any predecessor. This effectively also excludes regimes that did not survive beyond the death of the founding leader. The trimmed sample is about half the size of the full dataset, covering 127 regimes from 101 countries. Obviously, regimes included in this sample are unlikely to be representative of the average autocracy. They tend to be larger, wealthier, and more durable and are the more significant players on the world stage. While it is instructive to focus on those regimes given their practical importance,Footnote 16 in later sections, we discuss how sample selection issues might affect our inference and whether insights gained from this sample can travel to other settings.
Measuring Political Leaders' Power
A key challenge to our empirical analysis is to measure political leaders’ power accurately. To the extent that power is not directly observable and can manifest itself in different ways in different settings, it is often difficult to devise a general measure applicable to a large set of countries. The two most notable recent contributions to the challenge of measurement are the personalism index developed by Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2019) (GWF) and the power consolidation index from Gandhi and Sumner (Reference Gandhi and Sumner2020) (GS). GWF's measure is generated by running an Item Response Theory (IRT) model on several sub-indicators for, among other things, whether a leader personally controls high-level appointments and key organizations such as the ruling party, the military, and the security apparatus.
While these two measures have made important advances in the empirical operationalization of a concept as elusive as power, there is still significant room for improvement. One limitation of the GWF's personalism index, for example, is that it relies on the subjective judgement of human coders. This problem is further complicated by the fact that most of the sub-indicators are evaluated on a yearly basis. Even for a country expert, it would be difficult to tell with great precision whether a leader is more or less powerful in a given year than in the previous year.Footnote 17 GS's measure addresses the problem of subjective coding by mainly relying on objective information as input. Their focus on power consolidation actions raises a different kind of concern. Such actions are highly strategic and sometimes occur along off-equilibrium paths. It is, therefore, unclear whether they necessarily have a monotonic relationship with the actual degree of power a leader enjoys. Weak leaders who feel insecure about their position may be more inclined to engage in power consolidation actions than those who are more powerful and secure.
In this paper, we seek to develop a new measure of autocratic leaders' power that builds on the strengths of both existing approaches. Conceptually, we conceive of our measure as something closer to GWF's idea of personalism (but potentially applicable to more than just the top leaders) in that it should vary monotonically with a leader's underlying power. Methodologically, however, we share with GS the preference for using relatively objective information that does not require too much personal judgement to process. Simply put, our approach is to track the number of times an autocrat's name is mentioned in printed publications relative to other senior political elites. This approach is motivated by a growing body of recent literature that uses media sources to infer political actors' power (Ban et al. Reference Ban2018; Jaros and Pan Reference Jaros and Pan2017). We believe that name appearances in publications reveal important information about political leaders' power for at least two reasons. First, national leaders' de facto power partially stems from their charismatic appeal, which is often correlated with their fame and publicity. Second, the frequency of media appearances can also reflect the number of executive activities that a leader engages in. A leader who is frequently involved in major domestic and international affairs is usually more powerful than one who is not.
We construct a power index by combining information from Google Ngram and Wikidata. Google Ngram is a massive linguistic database that provides yearly counts for billions of words and short phrases (up to five words in length) from 28 million publications in Google Books' digital catalogue. The publications are drawn from the collections of Google's partner libraries (that is, major university and public libraries in the United States); they are roughly evenly divided between (a) regular academic and popular books and (b) a diverse set of ‘non-book’ items such as policy memos and reports, pamphlets, manuals, government documents, yearbooks, magazines, journals, and newspapers.Footnote 18 The Ngram database was initially developed to study the evolution of language and culture over time (Michel et al. Reference Michel2010) but has turned out to be a valuable tool for exploring other important socioeconomic trends and assessing public reactions to major natural or social events.Footnote 19 Wikidata is a central storage of structured data from Wikipedia, containing extensive information on the identity and biographical information of prominent public figures in a wide range of countries (Vrandečić and Krötzsch Reference Vrandečić and Krötzsch2014).
We first use Wikidata to compile a list of living politicians (including incumbent chief executives) for each country-year spell based on occupational labels. We then search each politician's name (official name and various aliases, also available from Wikidata) in the Ngram database and record the number of new publications produced each year that mention his/her most commonly used alias.Footnote 20 The Ngram-based power index is computed using the following formula:
where i, c, and t index the incumbent leader, country, and year, respectively, and L denotes the set of politicians who had served as the chief executive of country c for at least one year. Essentially, this index is the (logged) ratio between the Ngram publication counts for the incumbent leader in a given country-year spell and the publication counts for the highest living, non-chief-executive (non-CE) politician in the same spell.Footnote 21 We exclude all former chief executives from the calculation of the denominator so that the death or weakening of a predecessor will not lead to a mechanical increase in the index. Normalizing a leader's Ngram by that of his/her most influential non-CE colleague serves two purposes. First, it helps to address the potential bias due to differential coverage, as some countries and periods may have more publications stored by Google Books than others. Second, to the extent that power is a largely zero-sum quantity, using a relative count is conceptually attractive because it captures how much attention a top leader receives from publications relative to his/her colleagues. The identities of the non-CE politicians whose Ngrams are used as the denominator are quite diverse but typically belong to one of the following groups: (1) the president in a parliamentary system or the prime minister in a semi-presidential system, (2) vice presidents or prime ministers, (3) cabinet ministers, (4) members of the legislature, (5) governors of major states or provinces, or (6) other authoritative figures such as kings, sultans, or religious leaders (see Figures A.5 and A.6 for details). The median number of politicians included in the denominator is about 70 for country–year spells in our sample, and the inter-quartile range is between 26 and 154. The average ratio between the chief executive's Ngram and the highest non-CE figure's Ngram is 3.02 (logged ratio = 1.11), with a standard deviation of 5.4.Footnote 22
We conducted a number of validation tests to evaluate the quality of our measure against existing data and variables. In the interest of space, we provide most of the details in Appendix C but discuss several key tests here. First, we compare our measure with the two existing measures from GWF and GS. The upper part of Fig. 1 presents the respective distributions of the three measures. We can see that the GWF and GS measures tend to have a sizable number of observations clustered around a relatively small value (0 for GWF and −1 for GS). This is likely because there were not enough visible political events in those country-year spells for coders (or algorithms) to precisely determine the incumbent leaders’ power. By contrast, our Ngram-based measure follows a more natural, bell-shaped distribution and contains a good amount of variation, even for leaders located at the lower end of the distribution. The third row of Fig. 1 shows the correlation between our measure and the two others. We see that our measure is strongly and positively associated with the GWF personalism index. A one standard deviation increase in the power index is associated with about a 27 per cent of a standard deviation increase in GWF personalism (p < 0.001). By contrast, there appears to be a U-shaped relationship between our measure and the GS measure. These patterns are broadly consistent with our intuition. The Ngram-based measure is conceptually closer to GWF's idea of personalism, whereas power consolidation actions are more distinct and do not always have a monotonic relationship with leaders' underlying power.
Second, we examine how our Ngram measure varies across regime types. Generally speaking, we expect democracies to place stronger constraints on incumbent leaders rather than non-democracies. Within non-democracies, Geddes (Reference Geddes2003) suggests that military and party-based regimes may have a more collectivist style in exercising power than personalist regimes. In the bottom row of Fig. 1, we plot the average power index of national leaders by the Polity score (Marshall, Gurr, and Jaggers Reference Marshall, Gurr and Jaggers2018) and Geddes’ (Reference Geddes2003) autocratic regime classification. We see that, as countries become more democratic, the power index of their chief executives becomes smaller. On average, top leaders in military and party-based regimes have a lower power index than those in monarchies and personalist regimes. These patterns are consistent with the established view of how the level of power concentration varies across regime types.
In Appendix C, we use several qualitative examples to illustrate how our Ngram measure captures the over-time variations in leaders' power for selected countries and compare it with other existing measures (Section C.1). We also report additional validation tests using both cross-country and within-country data. We find strong relationships between our measure and a number of commonly used proxies for political power, including the seniority of formal positions (Section C.2), the length of political leaders' tenure (Section C.3), candidates' vote margins in competitive elections (Section C.4), and expert assessment of politicians' power (Section C.5). The fact that our measure tracks closely with power proxies from a variety of settings gives us confidence in its utility as a general indicator of leaders' power in cross-country analysis.
Identification Strategy and Model Specification
The key quantity of interest that we want to estimate is the effect of retired leaders on the power of the current chief executive.Footnote 23 A major challenge to identification here is that the presence or absence of influential retired leaders in a regime is likely to be correlated with many other (unobserved) country- or regime-level factors that can affect the incumbent's ability to consolidate power. For example, more institutionalized regimes may have stronger constraints on incumbents and a larger number of living predecessors due to established norms that require leaders to step down after a period of service. Sometimes, leaders who plan to initiate pre-mortem transitions may also deliberately select weaker successors who are less threatening and easier to control. Given that these factors are not all observable, a simple cross-regime or even cross-leader comparison may yield spurious correlations.
Our main strategy to address this endogeneity problem is to include several different types of fixed-effects in regression models. We can include fixed-effects for each unique political regime within a country, assuming that the leaders coming to power under the same regime face a more or less similar political and institutional environment. A more restrictive approach includes fixed-effects for every unique incumbent leader. The main advantage of the latter approach is that it eliminates the confounding influence of all unobserved factors that only vary across individual leaders but not within each leader. This enables us to make weaker identifying assumptions than a within-regime design (we discuss these assumptions below). However, a potential drawback of this approach is that it reduces the effective sample size to only those observations where such variations exist, and this may raise generalizability concerns. In the analysis presented below, we use the within-leader design as the preferred specification but also report results from other models to evaluate the robustness of our findings.
Our main specification is as follows:
where i, c, and t index individual leader, country, and year, respectively. η i is the leader fixed-effects that capture heterogeneity across incumbent leaders, and τ t is the year fixed-effects that capture common, worldwide shocks to the power index. The dependent variable, Incumbent power, is the Ngram-based power index. Since power is likely path-dependent, we also include lagged dependent variables in the model to capture its persistence over time. A common concern with including lagged dependent variables in a panel fixed-effects setting is the so-called Nickell bias (Nickell Reference Nickell1981), which is especially worrisome if the panel has a large number of units but a relatively short time period. However, this issue is mitigated considerably since our dataset spans several decades. We also run regressions as a robustness check using General Methods of Moments (GMM) estimators (Arellano and Bond Reference Arellano and Bond1991) and obtain similar results. In all models, we control for a country's Log GDP per capita and Log population, as both have been shown to be important predictors of leadership changes and regime breakdowns (for example, Djuve, Knutsen, and Wig Reference Djuve, Knutsen and Wig2019). The standard errors in all models are clustered at the country level to account for common unobserved factors that may affect the power of leaders from the same country.
The key explanatory variable, Predecessor power, is computed as follows:
For the ith (i ≥ 2) incumbent leader in regime r at year t, $\mathop {{\rm Power\;as\;CE}} _{j, r}$ is the average power index of his/her predecessor j during j‘s own tenure as the chief executive.Footnote 24 We choose to focus on the predecessor's past influence because of endogeneity concerns: Compared to a predecessor's contemporary influence (that is, at t), his/her past influence is less likely to be affected by the incumbent's current power. We also restrict the set of predecessors to those who belong to the same political regime r as the incumbent because incumbents are unlikely to be constrained by predecessors from a rival regime. ${\rm {\opf I}}$(death yearj > t) is an indicator function for whether j is still alive at t. Therefore, the variable Predecessor power is the logged average power of the most powerful predecessor if one or more retired leaders are aliveFootnote 25 and 0 if all within-regime predecessors are deceased by time t (that is, death yearj ≤ t for all j). In our sample, about 30 per cent of the observations have at least one living within-regime predecessor present, and the average value of a predecessor's power is about 0.91.Footnote 26
Since the average power index for each predecessor is computed based on the predecessor's time in the top executive office, its value does not change for the same predecessor throughout her successor's entire tenure.Footnote 27 Therefore, the only variation in predecessor power comes from the change in the identity of the most powerful predecessor, which happens when the predecessor who previously had the highest average power index passes away. As long as we are willing to assume that the deaths of retired leaders are largely exogenous events, this design allows us to identify the causal effect of losing a predecessor on the incumbent's power. A close look at the data suggests this assumption is reasonable. The vast majority of predecessors' deaths in our sample (~72 per cent) were due to natural illness, and less than 7 per cent were due to assassinations or other premeditated plots. As a robustness check, we later rerun our analysis in a sample in which all the variations in predecessors' power were caused by natural death only, and our results still hold (see Table A.22).
To provide an intuitive illustration of the variations we use for identification, Fig. 2 plots the co-variation between incumbents' power (solid red lines) and the power of the most influential predecessors (dashed black lines) for a select group of countries. Each shaded interval represents an uninterrupted period of reign by one incumbent leader. A cursory perusal of the trends suggests that, overall, incumbents' current power seems to be negatively correlated with their predecessors' past influence, both across and within administrations. When an influential predecessor is present (that is, when the dashed black line shows a positive value), the power index of the incumbent tends to be relatively low. The passing of the influential predecessor in the middle of an incumbent's tenure is usually associated with a notable increase in the incumbent's power in subsequent years. These visual patterns are consistent with our hypothesis about the role of predecessors as informal constraints. In the next section, we provide a more systematic test of this relationship using regression analysis.
Results
Baseline Results
Table 1 presents the baseline results. We first begin with a parsimonious model that only controls for the lagged dependent variables; the second model adds year and regime-fixed-effects; the third model replaces the regime fixed-effects with the more restrictive leader fixed-effects; the fourth model further adds controls for incumbents' tenure length and countries' economic and population sizes; and the fifth model uses the GMM method to address the Nickell bias in dynamic panel estimation. Consistent with our hypothesis, we see that, throughout all models, the presence of an influential retired leader is strongly and negatively associated with the incumbent's power. The estimated coefficient is somewhat smaller in the more parsimonious model (Column 1) but becomes more pronounced when fixed-effects are included. We also note that the size of the estimate becomes larger when we shift from a model with regime fixed-effects (Column 2) to one with leader fixed-effects (Column 3), suggesting that some confounding influence from unobserved regime-specific factors may exist. However, the difference between the leader fixed-effects model and the GMM estimate is relatively small, which is consistent with our conjecture that the scale of the Nickell bias is not too large, given our data's relatively long temporal coverage.
Note: This table presents the baseline regression results using incumbent leaders' Ngram-based power index as the dependent variable. The independent variable is the power of the living predecessor measured by the average power index during his/her tenure as the chief executive. When multiple living predecessors are present, the maximum value is used. Control variables include the incumbent's tenure length, log real GDP (in US dollars), and log population. Standard errors are clustered at the country level. *p < 0.1, **p< 0.05, ***p < 0.01, (two-tailed test).
Using estimated coefficients, we can compute the short-term and long-term effects of changes in the predecessor's influence on the incumbent's power.Footnote 28 Table 2 displays these effects in standard deviation terms. We see that the presence of an average former leader reduces the power of the incumbent by about 17 per cent of a standard deviation in that year and by about 24.7 per cent of a standard deviation in total in five years' time. The long-term effect is quite close to the five-year cumulative, suggesting that most of the predecessor's constraining effect materializes in the first five years after she leaves office.
Note: This table presents the cumulative effects of predecessors on incumbents' power based on Model 4 of Table 1. The results illustrate the difference in an incumbent's power between the scenario of no predecessor and the scenario of one predecessor with average strength (that is, the average power index as CE = 0.91). The coefficients are normalized by the standard deviation of the dependent variable to facilitate interpretation. *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, **, ***p < 0.01, (two-tailed test).
How large are these effects in substantive terms? To give a more concrete interpretation, we conduct some back-of-envelope calculations based on the estimated associations between incumbents' power and two more concrete political outcomes: overall tenure length and the likelihood of coups.Footnote 29 Among autocratic regimes, the incumbents' power index is positively associated with their tenure length (β tenure = 2.1, p < 0.001) and negatively associated with coup incidence (β coup = −0.024, p < 0.001).Footnote 30 Compared to a scenario where no predecessor exists, the cumulative constraining effect of an average predecessor (0.87) – someone whose power level is between China's Hu Jintao (0.825) and Tanzania's Ali Hassan Mwinyi (0.925) – translates into about a 0.72 year reduction in tenure length and 0.8 percentage point increase in year-on-year coup risk (~+15.8% from the baseline risk of 5.2 percentage points).Footnote 31 Further increasing the predecessor's power index from the average to the level of Julius Nyerere (2.0822) leads to another 0.92 year reduction in the incumbent's tenure length and a 1 percentage point increase in coup risk (~+20% from the baseline). Although the exact numerical quantities need to be treated with caution, the general magnitude of the results suggests that the presence of retired former leaders does have meaningful and measurable political consequences.
Event-Based Estimation
A central assumption of our empirical strategy is that, conditional on the within-leader design, the death of a predecessor is orthogonal to other leader- or regime-level confounders. This assumption might be violated if incumbent leaders who experience the deaths of predecessors during their tenures differ systematically from those who do not – if the predecessors' deaths are correlated with certain secular trends in the incumbents' power or if such deaths are fully anticipated in advance.Footnote 32 To verify this assumption, we adopt an event-study approach to examine the change in incumbent leaders' power in the few years before and after the death of their most influential predecessor. Specifically, we estimate the following regression equation:
where D ic denotes the year in which the event (death of the most influential predecessor) happened under a given leader i from the country c. 1{t − D ic = τ} is an indicator function that assigns 1 to the observation from country c that is the τth year relative to the event and 0 otherwise.
The results from the event-study regression are visualized in Fig. 3. We can see that incumbent leaders who experience the death of their most influential living predecessor do not exhibit significantly different trajectories of power compared to other incumbents (either they have no predecessor at all or do not face the imminent death of one) prior to the event. However, after the predecessor's passing, there is a notable surge in the former group's power in the following years. This suggests that the constraining effect we observe is highly specific to the presence or absence of influential predecessors – a finding that attests to the credibility of our identification strategy.
Results by Regime Type
We also take a closer look at how our results vary with a regime's institutional characteristics. As discussed, managed pre-mortem successions that produce living predecessors are typically more common in more institutionalized polities. Our argument also suggests that predecessors can sometimes constrain successors by creating new institutional arrangements or empowering existing ones. This implies that the presence and effectiveness of intergenerational constraints may be conditioned by a regime's level of institutional development. In Fig. 4, we report the subsample results using the three main authoritarian regime types from Geddes (Reference Geddes2003) as proxies for institutionalization. We find that the predecessors' effect is most pronounced in party-based regimes that tend to have relatively strong rules and institutions for regulating intra-elite interactions,Footnote 33 whereas the effect is smaller and less precisely estimated in military regimes and is virtually non-existent in personalist regimes. These findings suggest some complementarity between informal personal influence and formal institutional arrangements may exist. Predecessors can play a greater role in constraining their successors when the political system is at least moderately institutionalized.
Robustness Checks
We conducted a number of additional tests to ensure the robustness of our results. In the interest of space, we leave the details of the tests to Appendix F and briefly summarize the key findings here. First, we check whether our results are sensitive to the way we construct the dependent and independent variables. For the dependent variable, we re-run the baseline analysis using several modified versions of the Ngram-based power index (Table A.15) and use a leader's overall tenure length as a proxy for their power (Table A.16). These alternative measures yield results very similar to the baseline finding.Footnote 34
For the independent variable, we experiment by using two alternative measures of the predecessors' influence: the predecessors' power index based on the median Ngram as chief executive (as opposed to the mean) and a binary indicator for whether there is any living predecessor from the same regime. The results obtained were all substantively similar to the baseline (Tables A.19). We also introduced two modifications to account for the possibility that predecessors' power may change over their successors' tenure. One modification is to allow predecessors' power to decline following some exponential decay functions after they leave office, and the other is to simply use the current Ngram index of the most influential living predecessor. Again, our main findings turn out to be highly robust to these modifications (Table A.20).
To ensure our results are not driven by the idiosyncratic features of the sample, we re-estimate our baseline regressions using several modified samples. Our results continue to hold when using (1) the alternative sample of authoritarian regimes defined by Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2019) (Table A.21), (2) a subsample where all changes in predecessors' power are caused by natural death (Table A.22), and (3) subsamples that exclude up to 25 per cent of the most influential observations (Table A.23).
Moreover, we conduct placebo tests using two predecessor power measures similar to our independent design variable but different in substantive meaning. The first placebo measure is based on deceased predecessors, and the second on those from the same country but a different regime. To the extent that the hypothesized informal constraints are most likely associated with living, within-regime predecessors, we should not expect to find the same effect with either of the placebo variables. The results from the placebo regressions confirm this expectation. The coefficients for the placebo variables are either much smaller or even of the opposite sign compared to the original estimate (Table A.24). These patterns suggest that our findings are not driven by the power of former leaders in general but are highly specific to within-regime predecessors who left office in a relatively consensual fashion.
Addressing the Issue of Sample Selection
Given that our empirical analysis utilizes only a subset of authoritarian regimes, an important issue to consider is how our results are affected by sample selection. A predecessor's decision to voluntarily retire will likely depend on leader- and regime-level factors. As a result, the set of observations where we can observe living predecessors may be systematically different from those where no living predecessors exist. Theoretically speaking, the bias induced by sample selection may go both ways. Suppose stronger leaders are more likely to step down than weaker ones because they are more confident in their ability to continue to exert influence after retirement. In that case, we may overestimate the effect of predecessors, as the observed living predecessors could be stronger than the average former leader. Alternatively, if weaker leaders are more likely to engage in voluntary exit because they are more bound by the norm of retirement, we may underestimate the effect of predecessors.
To address the issue of sample selection, we first look into how an incumbent's power affects his subsequent mode of exit. We find a negative association between voluntary retirement and a leader's Ngram (Table A.25), which is likely to be driven by the fact that the most personalistic leaders either died in office or lost power to coups or popular revolts. This implies that the effect of the predecessors' constraint may be underestimated. To confirm this, we estimate a two-stage Heckman selection model (Heckman Reference Heckman1979), which specifies a first-stage selection equation to account for whether the immediate predecessor exited office through voluntary retirement.Footnote 35 After correcting for selection, we find that the coefficient estimate in the main regression model increases in size, suggesting that we would have observed a larger effect of predecessors had more of the powerful leaders chosen to engage in pre-mortem successions (Table A.26).
Evidence on Mechanism
Evidence from Sub-Measures of Personalism and Institutions
The preceding analysis has shown that in autocracies where pre-mortem successions are practiced, retired leaders often function as a key informal constraint on the power of incumbents. Yet, it remains unclear how, exactly, this constraint works. We probe this question further in several ways. To begin, we examine how the presence of influential predecessors affects the institutional and non-institutional aspects of authoritarian politics using several existing cross-country indicators. For the institutional element, we use Svolik's (Reference Svolik2012) data on authoritarian institutions to measure the presence of key semi-democratic institutions (for example, executive elections, legislatures, and multiple political parties). For the non-institutional aspect, we use four sub-measures of the GWF personalism index, which capture, in a general sense, the extent to which autocratic incumbents personally control key sectors such as the military, the regime party, and the state bureaucracy.
The regression results are presented in Table 3. We see that, in general, the presence of an influential predecessor is negatively associated with the incumbent's personal discretion in many domains, but the magnitude of the association is larger (and more precisely estimated) for high-level appointments in the ruling party (Column 1) and the military (Column 2). These patterns are broadly consistent with arguments advanced in previous studies; the de-personalization of personnel matters is key to limiting the power of incumbent leaders in non-democracies (Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008; Slater Reference Slater2003). Yet, paradoxically, what drives the de-personalization here appears to be the personal power of the predecessors. Meanwhile, we do not find consistent evidence that the predecessors' presence helps to change the characteristics of a regime's formal institutions in terms of either the competitiveness of executive and legislative elections or the extent of multi-party competition (Columns 5 to 7). In other words, the predecessors' influence is more readily observed in the covert, rather than the overt, domain of politics.
Note: This table presents the standardized regression coefficients on the effect of the predecessors' strength on sub-measures of personalism (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2019) and the presence/competitiveness of semi-democratic institutions (Svolik Reference Svolik2012). Dependent variables are measured as incremental changes from last year. Standard errors are clustered at the country level. *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01, (two-tailed test).
Evidence from Cabinet Appointments
In addition to showing a general pattern with broad-stroke indicators, the highly granular nature of our Ngram-based measure enables us to go a step further in unpacking the internal power dynamics associated with inter-generational constraints. Specifically, since similar Ngram name counts can theoretically be obtained for every politician in a regime, we can go beyond current and former top leaders and examine how this constraint affects the power distribution among a broader set of political elites. The recently published WhoGov dataset (Nyrup and Bramwell Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020) provides a comprehensive collection of cabinet ministers for 177 countries between 1966 and 2016. Research on authoritarian cabinets suggests they are important venues for incumbent autocrats to form ruling coalitions and co-opt potential rivals (Arriola Reference Arriola2009). Cabinet seats provide elites with access to state resources and influence over government policies; in some cases, cabinet members also form the critical candidate pool from which a regime's future top leaders will be selected. Recent studies have proved that cabinet reshuffles in non-democratic countries exhibit distinct patterns during sensitive and uncertain political times, such as before elections (Kroeger Reference Kroeger2018) or after coups (Bokobza et al. Reference Bokobza2022). Regarding succession, one way for former leaders to retain power over key policies and personnel matters after retirement may be to maintain a critical mass of allies and followers in high-profile cabinet posts. A closer look at cabinet appointments will likely provide important insights into how inter-generational checks and balances work.
We match the WhoGov dataset with our autocratic regime sample and run the same algorithm to construct an Ngram-based power index for each cabinet minister based on the number of publications that mention their name in a given year. We then compute the average power index separately for two groups of cabinet members: (1) those who are first appointed to a cabinet position by the incumbent leader (Average Ngram of Incumbents' Appointees) and (2) those who have been previously appointed to the cabinet by the incumbent's within-regime predecessors (Average Ngram of Predecessors' Appointees).Footnote 36 We estimate fixed-effect models that correlate predecessors' power with these cabinet-level outcomes.
Table 4 presents the results of the cabinet-level analyses. Columns 1 and 2 use the percentage of first-time cabinet members (that is, those appointed exclusively by the current leader) as the dependent variable. We see that the predecessors' power is strongly and negatively associated with the incumbents' ability to make fresh appointments to the cabinet. A one standard deviation increase in the predecessors' power ( + 0.58) is associated with a 6.6 percentage point or 23.9 per cent of a standard deviation decrease in the share of the incumbents' first-time appointees. The second Column further adds the variable for incumbents' power. A more powerful incumbent tends to make more fresh appointments to the cabinet. Columns 3 to 6 further examine how the inter-generational power balance shapes the relative influence of the two different groups of cabinet members. We see that the presence of powerful predecessors weakens the influence of cabinet members who are exclusively appointed by the current leaders but increases the influence of those appointed by the predecessors themselves. Meanwhile, powerful incumbents appear to have the exact opposite effect, raising the profiles of the incumbents' own appointees while limiting those of their predecessors. Taken together, these patterns suggest that an important method by which predecessors constrain their successors is to limit the latter's ability to unilaterally change the lineup of supporting elites in organizations critical to top leaders' effective exercise of power.
Note: This table presents the regression results on the effects of the incumbents' and predecessors' power on the patterns of cabinet appointments. Data on the characteristics of cabinet members are drawn from Nyrup and Bramwell (Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020). Control variables include cabinet size, log GDP per capita, and log population. Standard errors are clustered at the country level. *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01, (two-tailed test).
Conclusion
The allocation and contestation of power lie at the heart of elite politics. While much of the existing literature on authoritarian power politics focuses on institutions, we study how informal, personalized constraints affect incumbent autocrats' ability to consolidate power. We demonstrate that the constraints imposed by retired leaders have a discernible constraining effect on incumbent leaders' power and that the relaxation of such constraints following a predecessor's death allows the incumbent to expand his personal influence. We also provide suggestive evidence on how this constraint works. It works less by altering the formal and conspicuous aspects of political institutions and more by limiting successors' discretion over the subtle yet crucial domain of personnel control.
Although the specific inter-generational arrangement we study here may not necessarily be present in all autocracies, the central insight that imposing effective constraints on power holders ultimately requires others to hold a commensurate level of power is relevant to a broad set of regimes. Without a powerful former chief executive, other influential members of the ruling circle, such as long-time cabinet members or senior military officers, can sometimes act as informal constraints on incumbents. In China during the 1980s, for example, the key constraint faced by the paramount leader Deng Xiaoping was from a coalition of veteran revolutionaries who possessed comparable or even greater seniority in the CCP than Deng himself (Shirk Reference Shirk1993). Moreover, according to the study by Barros (Reference Barros2002), even in a seemingly personalist regime like Chile under Augusto Pinochet, powerful generals from other branches of the military acted as key informal checks on Pinochet's power, and their influence helped to create an effective constitutional framework that paved the way for the subsequent democratic transition.
Our study serves as a cautionary note against the rapidly growing body of literature on authoritarian institutions (Boix and Svolik Reference Boix and Svolik2013; Brownlee Reference Brownlee2007a; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008). To the extent that formal institutions are often deeply intertwined with, and endogenous to, political maneuvering undertaken by powerful political actors, one needs to be extremely careful when making inferences about the independent effect of institutions. As our study suggests, institutions sometimes emerge in tandem with the need to cope with succession challenges, and the effectiveness of institutions as a form of executive constraint depends crucially on the informal political clout of retired leaders. Neglecting this hidden dimension can lead us to overstate the institutions' actual ability to constrain incumbents.
Findings from our study also suggest new ways to think about how personal power and institutionalization may interact. The prevailing view in the literature is that personalism is antithetical to building strong and robust political institutions (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2019; Levitsky and Ziblatt Reference Levitsky and Ziblatt2018). Recent studies have argued that weak leaders are more likely to pursue the strategy of institutionalization as a way of making credible commitments to other elites (Meng Reference Meng2020). Our findings provide a more nuanced and dynamic interpretation. In some cases, powerful leaders may be a blessing for building binding institutions if political exigencies provide them with the right incentives. As illustrated by the leadership succession case, departing leaders concerned with protecting their interests and legacies in retirement may want to put in place strong institutions to tie the hands of their successors (rather than themselves). Those with greater personal power are more likely to succeed because they have a greater capacity to defend and enforce nascent institutions and cultivate a norm of institutional compliance among the elites. Systematic explanations of how strong institutions take root in a regime need to take into account the role played by prominent political figures such as George Washington in the United States, Chiang Ching-Kuo in Taiwan, and Deng Xiaoping in China.
Recognizing the importance of personalistic input to executive constraint also suggests a different prediction of long-term institutional dynamics. Contrary to the commonly held view that institution building is a path-dependent process whereby institutions, once put in place, become incrementally stronger as time goes on (Pierson Reference Pierson2000), our finding that effective executive constraints also need support from relatively powerful predecessors suggests that strengthening institutional constraints in the short run may, paradoxically, sow the seeds for de-institutionalization in the long run. As the constraints over incumbent leaders become progressively stronger, it may reach a point where the incumbent leader is so constrained he cannot accumulate sufficient personal power to serve as an effective check on his successor after he retires. The presence of a relatively weak predecessor may become an opportunity for the successor to circumvent existing institutions and increase his personal power in the future. Therefore, instead of being a unidirectional path toward greater institutionalization, the rise and fall of institutions may be a cyclical phenomenon over the long historical durée.
Future research can extend this study in at least two ways. First, researchers can further explore how this specific informal constraint that we identify – the presence or absence of former leaders – affects incumbent leaders' behaviours in areas other than power consolidation, such as policy directions, economic performance, or interstate relations. Second, researchers can explore other sources of informal constraints in autocratic systems. While ex-leaders as a form of informal constraint may be most applicable to relatively institutionalized autocracies, other types of constraints, such as the breadth and depth of the ruler's personal networks, the configurations of the ethnic and regional interests within the ruling elites, and the relative influence of political leaders vis-à-vis prominent military, business, and religious figures, may play a greater role in less institutionalized settings. A better understanding of how those constraints work will shed important light on the nature of autocratic power and what limits it in the absence of binding institutions.
Supplementary material
The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123424000012.
Data availability statement
Replication data for this article can be found in Harvard Dataverse at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/FJIQQR.
Acknowledgements
We thank Alex Baturo, Kristin McKie, and Tod Van Gunten for generously sharing their data with us. Tak-Huen Chau, Weiye Deng, Xinting Du, Qianxun Feng, Zanhui Liu, Zhirui Luo, Yucheng Qiu, Junhan Tang, Meng Tang, Lixian Wang, Hanying Wei, and Sile Yan provided excellent research assistance.
Financial support
Jiang acknowledges financial support from the Research Grant Council of Hong Kong (ECS-24612618) and Columbia University's Institute for Social and Economic Research and Policy (ISERP). Tianyang Xi acknowledges research support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71874004) and the Ministry of Education of China (16JJD790003).
Competing interests
None.