Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T08:32:18.343Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Group-Based Approach to Measuring Polarization

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 October 2023

ISAAC D. MEHLHAFF*
Affiliation:
The University of Chicago, United States
*
Corresponding author: Isaac D. Mehlhaff, Postdoctoral Scholar, Data Science Institute, The University of Chicago, United States, imehlhaff@uchicago.edu.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Despite polarization’s growing importance in social science, its quantitative measurement has lagged behind its conceptual development. Political and social polarization are group-based phenomena characterized by intergroup heterogeneity and intragroup homogeneity, but existing measures capture only one of these features or make it difficult to compare across cases or over time. To bring the concept and measurement of polarization into closer alignment, I introduce the cluster-polarization coefficient (CPC), a measure of multimodality that allows scholars to incorporate multiple variables and compare across contexts with varying numbers of parties or social groups. Three applications to elite and mass polarization demonstrate that the CPC returns substantively sensible results, and an open-source software package implements the measure.

Type
Letter
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of American Political Science Association

INTRODUCTION

Polarization is a key concept in the social sciences, playing a role in important political outcomes ranging from representation (Ahler and Broockman Reference Ahler and Broockman2018) and party-building (Aldrich Reference Aldrich2011) to policymaking (Binder Reference Binder1999) and democracy (Mason Reference Mason2018). Conceptually, polarization has two important features: intergroup heterogeneity and intragroup homogeneity. Yet the most common measures of polarization—difference-in-means and variance—are ill-suited to capture both features.

I offer an alternative. The cluster-polarization coefficient (CPC) explicitly models intergroup heterogeneity and intragroup homogeneity, placing polarization’s conceptual foundation front and center. I evaluate the CPC’s ability to discern polarization relative to difference-in-means and variance by applying them to three datasets of elite ideal points and mass party affect. One theoretical and two empirical advantages of the CPC emerge: it better captures the theoretical concept, displays greater flexibility when considering multiple variables, and facilitates measurement of and comparison across cases with more than two groups. Since most party systems have more than two parties and most political conflict occurs along more than one dimension, the CPC provides a very useful tool.

To make the measurement procedure widely accessible, I provide an open-source software package—CPC: Implementation of Cluster-Polarization Coefficient—which is freely available on the Comprehensive R Archive Network (https://cran.r-project.org/package=CPC). In addition to calculating the CPC with researcher-specified group memberships, this package contains support for a variety of clustering methods to assign observations to groups, making the measure applicable to a variety of data structures.

FEATURES OF POLARIZATION

Polarization tends to manifest both between and within groups, emerging when group members disagree with members of other groups, agree with members of their own, or both. That understanding implies two conceptual features: distance from opponents (intergroup heterogeneity) and concentration within groups (intragroup homogeneity). When scholars conceptualize polarization, they often reference both features (Aldrich Reference Aldrich2011; DiMaggio, Evans, and Bryson Reference DiMaggio, Evans and Bryson1996; Maoz and Somer-Topcu Reference Maoz and Somer-Topcu2010; Rehm and Reilly Reference Rehm and Reilly2010).

Yet when operationalizing polarization, the distance between groups tends to be the sole focus (Ahler and Broockman Reference Ahler and Broockman2018; Layman and Carsey Reference Layman and Carsey2002). The emphasis on intergroup heterogeneity is not misplaced; polarization certainly increases as groups grow farther apart. However, the debate about whether polarization exists in the American mass public illustrates why one-feature measurement strategies may miss critical underlying forces. The early twenty-first century witnessed increases in both intergroup heterogeneity and intragroup homogeneity. Indeed, Fiorina, Abrams, and Pope (Reference Fiorina, Samuel and Jeremy2005) conceded the parties had become farther apart, but dismissed this change as unimportant for polarization because the increase in distance between party means mostly resulted from partisans matching their issue preferences to their party, not necessarily becoming more extreme in their preferences. “Party sorting” as the primary contributor to diverging party ideal points in the American electorate suggests that whatever increase in intergroup heterogeneity that occurred in this case was mostly a function of increasing intragroup homogeneity.

In their critique of Fiorina, Abrams, and Pope (Reference Fiorina, Samuel and Jeremy2005), Abramowitz and Saunders (Reference Abramowitz and Saunders2008) theorized polarization in terms of distance between parties (intergroup heterogeneity). Yet their most compelling evidence of polarization actually revealed increasing intragroup homogeneity. Specifically, they found Republicans were increasingly likely to adopt conservative positions on a wide range of issues, whereas Democrats were increasingly likely to take liberal positions on those same issues. This increase in what Converse (Reference Converse and Apter1964) labeled “constraint” reflects changing opinion patterns within parties, not between them. With the United States becoming qualitatively more polarized over the past 25 years, it is noteworthy that the foundational evidence from this debate better reflects the importance of intragroup homogeneity, even as the dialogue focused on the distance between parties.

More important than the fact that greater intragroup homogeneity can mechanically produce more intergroup heterogeneity through a process like party sorting is the theoretical importance of intragroup homogeneity in understanding group identity and conflict. Group members tend to be able to perceive increases in the homogeneity of their ingroup (Park and Judd Reference Park and Judd1990), which leads group members to surmise they have more in common with each other. Such perceptions can strengthen ingroup identities and produce more intergroup conflict, including in networks of political partisans (Parsons Reference Parsons2015). Perceptions of homogeneity within opposing groups are also important. Because group members tend to exaggerate the homogeneity of outgroups, anti-outgroup bias often results (Wilder Reference Wilder1978). For example, when partisans misperceive other parties as being mostly comprised of negatively valanced constituent groups, they tend to see those out-partisans as more extreme, view them negatively, and express stronger allegiance to their own party (Ahler and Sood Reference Ahler and Sood2018). Taken together, measures of polarization would be well-served to account for both intergroup heterogeneity and intragroup homogeneity.

CLUSTER-POLARIZATION COEFFICIENT

Recognizing that a measure of polarization should account for both intergroup heterogeneity and intragroup homogeneity does not point to an obvious solution. A survey of eight political science journals reveals 322 articles published about polarization since 2000,Footnote 1 employing at least 20 distinct operationalizations. Two approaches account for most uses: measures of difference-in-means and variance are used in 57% and 14% of articles, respectively.Footnote 2 While both indicate movement toward the extremes, neither provides much information about the degree to which that movement is organized as group conflict.

I present a measure—the CPC—that accounts for both features, beginning from the premise that social scientific data are often comprised of distinct clusters of observations. In politics, clusters are typically represented by parties or social groups. To derive the CPC, I decompose the total variance of this clustered data ( $ TSS $ ) in Equation 1 into components corresponding to the two features of polarization: the variance accounted for between the clusters ( $ BSS $ ; intergroup heterogeneity) and the variance accounted for within all clusters ( $ WSS $ ; intragroup homogeneity). Dividing by $ TSS $ and solving for the $ BSS $ term in Equation 1 gives an expression for the proportion of the total variance accounted for by the between-cluster variance—what I call the CPC. As it is a proportion, the value produced by this expression varies on the domain $ [0,1] $ .

(1) $$ \begin{array}{rl}\begin{array}{rl}TSS& =BSS+WSS,\\ {}\to CPC& =1-\frac{WSS}{TSS}=\frac{BSS}{TSS}.\end{array}& \end{array} $$

More formally, the CPC takes the expression in Equation 2, where each individual i in cluster k holds a position on dimension j. Footnote 3 This construction in terms of k and j shows how the CPC facilitates the incorporation of multiple groups and variables, respectively. Expressed in this way, the CPC appears related to a one-way ANOVA F-statistic and the coefficient of determination ( $ {R}^2 $ ). These are useful similarities for deriving properties of the measure (Sections S2.2–S2.5 of the Supplementary Material).

(2) $$ \begin{array}{r}CPC=1-\frac{\sum_{k=1}^{n_k}\sum_{i=1}^{n_i}\sum_{j=1}^{n_j}({x}_{ikj}-{\mu}_{kj}{)}^2}{\sum_{i=1}^{n_i}\sum_{j=1}^{n_j}({x}_{ij}-{\mu}_j{)}^2}=\frac{\sum_{k=1}^{n_k}\sum_{j=1}^{n_j}({\mu}_{kj}-{\mu}_j{)}^2}{\sum_{i=1}^{n_i}\sum_{j=1}^{n_j}({x}_{ij}-{\mu}_j{)}^2}.\end{array} $$

Because intra-state political dynamics, the number and nature of sociopolitical cleavages, and the size and number of political coalitions typically vary across countries or within countries over time, one additional modification is needed to make the CPC appropriate for comparison across contexts with varying numbers of observations, variables, and clusters. The expression in Equation 2 will be biased upward in small samples, so I incorporate corrections for lost degrees of freedom and express the adjusted CPC in Equation 3:Footnote 4

(3) $$ \begin{array}{r}CP{C}_{adj}=1-\frac{\frac{\sum_{k=1}^{n_k}\sum_{i=1}^{n_i}\sum_{j=1}^{n_j}({x}_{ikj}-{\mu}_{kj}{)}^2}{n_i-{n}_j{n}_k}}{\frac{\sum_{i=1}^{n_i}\sum_{j=1}^{n_j}({x}_{ij}-{\mu}_j{)}^2}{n_i-{n}_j}}=1-(1-CPC)\frac{n_i-{n}_j}{n_i-{n}_j{n}_k}.\end{array} $$

By explicitly modeling both $ BSS $ and $ WSS $ , the CPC accounts for both features of polarization. It increases when the distance between groups increases or when groups become more tightly concentrated around their collective ideal point, with the rate of those increases depending on the relative levels of $ BSS $ and $ WSS $ .

To illustrate the importance of both features and how the CPC produces more accurate estimates than existing measures, consider the stylized distributions in Figure 1. They imitate four possible combinations of intergroup heterogeneity and intragroup homogeneity. The distribution in plot a has neither feature—two clusters are faintly apparent, but they are close together and display little cohesion. Plot b has high intragroup homogeneity and low intergroup heterogeneity, and plot c has the reverse. The group means are the same in plot b as in plot a, but the groups are more concentrated. Intragroup homogeneity is the same in plot c as in plot a, but group means are further apart. Finally, plot d has high levels of both characteristics.

Figure 1. Stylized Distributions of Polarization Features

Note: Simulated bimodal Gaussian mixture distributions with $ {\mu}_{global}=0 $ . Labels show polarization levels according to each measure. Plots labeled a–d to correspond to explanations in text.

A measure accurately capturing polarization should indicate more polarization in plots b–d of Figure 1 relative to plot a and less polarization in plots a–c relative to plot d. Plot labels display the polarization estimate for each distribution based on difference-in-means, variance, and the CPC. In all cases, higher numbers indicate greater polarization.

Difference-in-means successfully distinguishes between plots a and c and between plots b and d of Figure 1, assigning a higher polarization estimate to the latter plot in each pairing, but it cannot distinguish plot a from b nor plot c from d. It assigns identical polarization estimates to each distribution even though plots b and d are qualitatively more polarized than plots a and c, respectively, reflecting why Levendusky and Pope (Reference Levendusky and Pope2011) urge scholars to “go beyond the mean” when measuring polarization. Variance is frequently offered as one way of doing that, but it performs even worse here. It, too, distinguishes between plots a and c and between plots b and d, but it assigns lower polarization estimates to plots b and d relative to plots a and c, opposite the conceptual understanding of polarization. This simple exercise suggests that the most common measures may allow polarization to go undetected in some cases and, in others, identify it where it does not exist. The CPC is the only measure of the three that accurately captures the qualitative differences between all four distributions.

The Supplementary Material includes several validation exercises (Mehlhaff Reference Mehlhaff2023). Sections S3.1 and S3.2 of the Supplementary Material show that, compared to difference-in-means and variance, the CPC more consistently captures both features of polarization in univariate and bivariate contexts and in distributions with two, three, and four groups. Sections S3.3 and S3.4 of the Supplementary Material show the CPC can be sensitive to outliers and large differences in group size, though it still outperforms existing measures and scaling the input data ameliorates outlier sensitivity. Section S4 of the Supplementary Material benchmarks each measure’s performance against “ground-truth” data gathered from human annotators.

POLARIZATION IN CONGRESS: A MULTIDIMENSIONAL TEST

I investigate the well-established rise in congressional polarization in the United States, showing that the CPC recovers this increase in multidimensional data. I calculate congressional polarization using DW-NOMINATE (Lewis et al. Reference Lewis, Poole, Rosenthal, Boche, Rudkin and Sonnet2021), which uses a scaling procedure to estimate the ideal points of legislators in a two-dimensional latent space. The first dimension is said to capture economic issues and the second racial and other social issues. Because the CPC is expressed in terms of j in Equation 2 and Equation 3, it can incorporate both variables without needing to average over them or create an index.

A steady increase in party polarization has been one of the defining features of congressional politics in the late twentieth and early twenty-first centuries, occurring in economic, racial, and cultural issue domains (Layman and Carsey Reference Layman and Carsey2002). Focusing on the period from 1975 to the present, each measure of polarization should therefore indicate increases whether they examine only the first NOMINATE dimension or incorporate both.

Polarization estimates for each Congress appear in Figure 2. All measures generally capture the expected trend in the first NOMINATE dimension. However, performance diverges with the addition of the second dimension.Footnote 5 Difference-in-means detects the increase in polarization that occurred in the House, but it implausibly suggests the Senate didn’t begin polarizing until the mid-2000s and, even in 2019, remained almost a full standard deviation less polarized than it was in the late 1970s. Variance does even worse with the addition of the second dimension, suggesting flat or declining polarization levels leading up to the present-day. The CPC consistently recovers trends that more closely reflect expectations in both one and two dimensions.

Figure 2. Congressional Polarization Estimates

Note: Calculated using NOMINATE ideal point estimates; each measure unit-normalized to enable comparison. All point estimates are available in the online replication materials.

Evaluating general trends is informative but, in some cases, it is difficult to tell how much estimates deviate from each other. To assess whether those deviations lead each measure to reflect polarization more or less closely, I evaluate how polarization estimates correlate with each chamber’s party unity score—the percentage of legislators voting with their party on votes in which a majority of Democrats oppose a majority of Republicans (Brookings Institution Reference Jardina and Ollerenshaw2022). Each measure should indicate a positive correlation between polarization and party unity.

Results are shown in Table 1. All three measures correlate highly with party unity when examining only the first dimension, though the CPC holds a narrow performance advantage in the House and a significant one in the Senate. When considering both dimensions, difference-in-means shows a strong correlation in the House, though it is again narrowly bested by the CPC. Variance struggles in both chambers, suggesting negative associations between polarization and party unity. Though correlations with all measures are lower in the Senate, the CPC is the only measure that still shows a positive association with party unity.

Table 1. Correlation Between Congressional Polarization Estimates and Party Unity Scores

Note: Bolded values denote measure with highest correlation.

This underscores an important benefit of the CPC. Aldrich, Montgomery, and Sparks (Reference Aldrich, Montgomery and Sparks2014) show that high-dimensional estimates are crucial for accurate ideal point estimation, especially in polarized contexts. Researchers using current measures may need to ignore higher-dimensional information as a pragmatic matter, but the CPC allows it to be preserved, resulting in more accurate polarization estimates.

COMPARATIVE ELITE POLARIZATION: A MULTI-GROUP TEST

Measuring polarization in multi-party systems is a persistent challenge (Gidron, Adams, and Horne Reference Gidron, Adams and Horne2020; Wagner Reference Wagner2021). To demonstrate that the CPC can capture polarization across contexts with different numbers of groups, I use a set of elite ideological ideal points from six Western countries (Barberá Reference Barberá2015). As depicted in Figure 3a, these countries differ in the extent to which their latent elite groups are internally homogeneous and externally heterogeneous, and even in how many groups exist within each country. The United Kingdom and Netherlands have high intergroup heterogeneity, the United States has high intragroup homogeneity, and Spain has a fair amount of both. Italy and Germany both have two identifiable modes, but their intragroup homogeneity is relatively low.

Figure 3. Estimates of Elite Polarization

Note: Kernel density plots for each country (a) and polarization estimates with bootstrapped 95% confidence intervals (b). The online replication materials present point estimates and standard errors.

With all this variation, it is difficult to identify polarization levels simply by evaluating density plots. To generate expectations for how countries should compare in their levels of elite ideological polarization, I apply Dalton’s (Reference Dalton2008) measure of party system polarization to expert-coded data on left–right party positions (Düpont et al. Reference Düpont, Kavasoglu, Lührmann and Reuter2022). These benchmarks appear in the upper-left facet of Figure 3b and reveal three groupings. Italy and Germany have similar, low levels of polarization. The United States, United Kingdom, and Netherlands are similar to each other in their polarization levels, all higher than those in Italy and Germany. Finally, Spain has by far the highest level of polarization. A well-performing measure of polarization applied to the elite ideology data in Figure 3a should generally reflect these expert judgments.

The other three facets in Figure 3b display the degree to which difference-in-means, variance, and the CPC suggest the party systems are polarized. CPC estimates, shown in the upper-right facet, approximate the expert-coded data much better than difference-in-means or variance do.Footnote 6 The CPC indicates that Germany and Italy are the least polarized countries, with the United States, United Kingdom, and Netherlands significantly more so. Though the CPC does not capture the large difference between Spain and the Netherlands that appears in the expert-coded data, it does identify Spain as the most polarized country in the sample.

In contrast, difference-in-means and variance often produce polarization estimates at odds with the expert-coded benchmarks, not to mention the visual representation of the data. Both measures suggest the United States is the least polarized of the six countries, with Italy the second-most polarized despite a near-unimodal distribution of ideal points. Worse still, both difference-in-means and variance suggest polarization in Spain is relatively low, while the expert-coded data show it as by far the highest. In short, they fail to produce polarization estimates that resemble country-expert judgments when there are varying numbers of groups in the data, even in the simplest unidimensional space. The CPC much more closely reflects how experts view ideological polarization in party systems.

AFFECTIVE POLARIZATION: MULTIPLE DIMENSIONS AND GROUPS

In the United States, affective polarization appears to run deeper than ideological or issue polarization (Mason Reference Mason2018), and a robust research program examines this development in comparative perspective (Wagner Reference Wagner2021). In the previous two applications, I addressed problems associated with multidimensional and multi-group data separately. By employing party affect data, I can address them simultaneously. Party systems have different numbers of parties across cases, meaning the number of groups present in the data will vary. The number of parties also determines the number of dimensions; respondents’ assessments across multiple party feeling thermometers represents the several dimensions of their party affect. A measure of polarization should be able to accommodate both sources of variation. To estimate affective polarization, I apply each measure to party feeling thermometers (see also Gidron, Adams, and Horne Reference Gidron, Adams and Horne2020; Ward and Tavits Reference Ward and Tavits2019) from module four of the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems (CSES).

One way to assess validity is to calculate correlations between polarization estimates produced by each measure and indicators that tap attitudes theoretically related to party affect.Footnote 7 The CSES contains several good candidates. First, the proportion of respondents indicating “it makes a big difference who is in power.” Second, the proportion who believe “who people vote for can make a big difference.” These statements both capture the degree to which respondents believe their political system presents starkly differentiated options to voters, a belief that likely intensifies with stronger party affect (Ward and Tavits Reference Ward and Tavits2019). Third, the proportion of respondents expressing they “feel very close” to their political party. Respondents should hold their party identity more intensely when their party affect is strong (Mason Reference Mason2018). Finally, the proportion of respondents indicating they occupy extreme positions of a left–right self-placement scale. Citizens tend to distrust parties more when those parties are ideologically distant, so the degree of ideological extremity should also be related to affective polarization (Wagner Reference Wagner2021).Footnote 8

Figure 4 illustrates how affective polarization correlates with each of these items. Each variable should exhibit positive correlations with polarization estimates. That is true of CPC estimates in all four cases. Difference-in-means and variance also uncover a strong, positive relationship between affective polarization and ideological extremity, but their relationships with other variables are less consistent. Difference-in-means uncovers positive correlations between polarization and beliefs about whether it matters who is in power, but variance displays negative associations with that correlate as well as beliefs about whether one’s vote makes a difference. More concerning, difference-in-means and variance suggest that polarization is negatively related to respondents feeling “very close” to their party. This result would seem to be at odds with the very definition of affective polarization, part of which emphasizes in-group affection, a sentiment that should strengthen when group members are more similar to each other. This finding lends further credence to the notion that the measures most often used to measure polarization do not successfully capture intragroup homogeneity, rendering the accounts of polarization they provide incomplete.

Figure 4. Correlates of Affective Polarization

Note: Error bars give bootstrapped 95% confidence intervals. Full results reported in online replication materials.

CONCLUSION

Polarization is a critical concept that bears on a wide variety of social scientific phenomena, yet efforts to quantify it often fail to capture its two conceptual elements: intergroup heterogeneity and intragroup homogeneity. The CPC accounts for both features, aligning concept with measure and producing sensible estimates of polarization across contexts. The CPC’s greater accuracy is largely driven by its ability to capture intragroup homogeneity, but it should be noted that including this feature may not always be theoretically appropriate or empirically practical. For example, research on party system polarization primarily focuses on ideological distance between parties, party families, or coalitions at the aggregate level (e.g., Dalton Reference Dalton2008). As such, there are also fewer data points available in each case. In these situations, researchers may still prefer alternative operationalizations of polarization.

Though difference-in-means and variance are the most commonly used measures in political science, the measure perhaps most similar to the CPC is that of Esteban and Ray (Reference Esteban and Ray1994), which is used most frequently in economics and ethnic studies. However, Clark (Reference Institution2009) shows this measure is not much different from variance, with correlations as high as 0.933. Maoz and Somer-Topcu (Reference Maoz and Somer-Topcu2010) further argue it is based on arbitrary assumptions, such as a small number of groups, and is very highly correlated with the number and size of groups. The CPC is conceptually simpler than Esteban and Ray’s measure, and the adjusted CPC is explicitly developed to correct for the types of problems scholars have identified with it.

I focused here on party-based polarization, but similar dynamics arise across an array of contexts. Existing work that could benefit from employing the CPC includes studies of polarization in mass policy preferences (DiMaggio, Evans, and Bryson Reference DiMaggio, Evans and Bryson1996), racial polarization (Jardina and Ollerenshaw Reference Layman and Carsey2022), economic polarization (Dwyer Reference Dwyer2013), and religious polarization (Montalvo and Reynal-Querol Reference Montalvo and Reynal-Querol2003). By introducing the CPC and providing open-source software to simplify its implementation, I aim to advance the critical study of polarization’s causes and consequences.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055423001041.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Research documentation and data that support the findings of this study are openly available at the American Political Science Review Dataverse: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/ZTWRSQ.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

For valuable feedback at many different stages of the project, I thank Santiago Olivella, Ted Enamorado, Erin Hartman, Marc Hetherington, Cecilia Martinez-Gallardo, Matthew Singer, Leslie Schwindt-Bayer, Michael Greenberger, Liesbet Hooghe, Jonathan Hartlyn, Robert Luskin, Jason Roberts, the editors, and four anonymous reviewers; seminar participants at UNC-Chapel Hill, Duke University, Texas A&M University, the ECPR Summer School for Political Behavior in Latin America; and conference participants at the 2020 PolMeth Annual Conference and the 2021 SPSA Annual Meeting.

FUNDING STATEMENT

This work was supported by the National Science Foundation (Grant No. 2040435) and the Department of Political Science at UNC-Chapel Hill.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

The author declares no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

ETHICAL STANDARDS

The author declares the human subjects research in this article was reviewed and approved by the Institutional Review Board at UNC-Chapel Hill and certificate numbers are provided in the appendix. The author affirms that this article adheres to the APSA’s Principles and Guidance on Human Subject Research.

Footnotes

1 See Section S1 of the Supplementary Material for details.

2 “Variance” refers to total variance, as opposed to within-group variance.

3 Section S2.1 of the Supplementary Material shows full derivations.

4 The expression in Equation 3 is unbiased and consistent (Sections S2.2–S2.5 of the Supplementary Material). All calculations in this paper use the adjusted CPC.

5 I calculate difference-in-means using the Euclidean distance between group means, and I calculate variance using the trace of the covariance matrix.

6 Difference-in-means and the CPC require knowledge of the cluster to which each observation belongs, so I use three clustering methods to assign observations to clusters. Estimates are consistent across methods (see online replication materials). The number of clusters in each country is implied by Figure 3a. For example, Germany has two clusters, Spain has three, and so on. Silhouette scores corroborate choices of cluster numbers (see online replication materials). Users should note, however, that different methods sometimes suggest different numbers of clusters—particularly in multidimensional data—and these differences will affect CPC estimates.

7 See online replication materials for country-level affective polarization estimates.

8 These expectations are derived in the context of democratic regimes, so I limit my analysis to countries with a Polity score above 8.

References

REFERENCES

Abramowitz, Alan I., and Saunders, Kyle L.. 2008. “Is Polarization a Myth?Journal of Politics 70 (2): 542–55.Google Scholar
Ahler, Douglas J., and Broockman, David E.. 2018. “The Delegate Paradox: Why Polarized Politicians can Represent Citizens Best.” Journal of Politics 80 (4): 1117–33.Google Scholar
Ahler, Douglas J., and Sood, Gaurav. 2018. “The Parties in Our Heads: Misperceptions about Party Composition and Their Consequences.” Journal of Politics 80 (3): 964–81.Google Scholar
Aldrich, John H. 2011. Why Parties? A Second Look. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Aldrich, John H., Montgomery, Jacob M., and Sparks, David B.. 2014. “Polarization and Ideology: Partisan Sources of Low Dimensionality in Scaled Roll Call Analyses.” Political Analysis 22 (4): 435–56.Google Scholar
Barberá, Pablo. 2015. “Birds of the Same Feather Tweet Together: Bayesian Ideal Point Estimation Using Twitter Data.” Political Analysis 23 (1): 7691.Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah A. 1999. “The Dynamics of Legislative Gridlock, 1947–96.” American Political Science Review 93 (3): 519–33.Google Scholar
Institution, Brookings. 2022. “Vital Statistics on Congress.” November 21. https://www.brookings.edu/multi-chapter-report/vital-statistics-on-congress/.Google Scholar
Clark, Tom S. 2009. “Measuring Ideological Polarization on the United States Supreme Court.” Political Research Quarterly 62 (1): 146–57.Google Scholar
Converse, Philip E. 1964. “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics.” In Ideology and Discontent, ed. Apter, David E., 206–61. New York: The Free Press of Glencoe.Google Scholar
Dalton, Russell J. 2008. “The Quantity and the Quality of Party Systems: Party System Polarization, Its Measurement, and Its Consequences.” Comparative Political Studies 41 (7): 899920.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul, Evans, John, and Bryson, Bethany. 1996. “Have American’s Social Attitudes Become More Polarized?American Journal of Sociology 102 (3): 690755.Google Scholar
Düpont, Nils, Kavasoglu, Yaman Berker, Lührmann, Anna, and Reuter, Ora John. 2022. “A Global Perspective on Party Organizations: Validating the Varieties of Party Identity and Organization Dataset (V-Party).” Electoral Studies 75: 102423.Google Scholar
Dwyer, Rachel E. 2013. “The Care Economy? Gender, Economic Restructuring, and Job Polarization in the U.S. Labor Market.” American Sociological Review 78 (3): 390416.Google Scholar
Esteban, Joan-María, and Ray, Debraj. 1994. “On the Measurement of Polarization.” Econometrica 62 (4): 819–51.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P., Samuel, J. Abrams, and Jeremy, C. Pope. 2005. Culture War? The Myth of a Polarized America. New York: Pearson Longman.Google Scholar
Gidron, Noam, Adams, James, and Horne, Will. 2020. American Affective Polarization in Comparative Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jardina, Ashley, and Ollerenshaw, Trent. 2022. “The Polarization of White Racial Attitudes and Support for Racial Equality in the US.” Public Opinion Quarterly 86 (1): 576–87.Google Scholar
Layman, Geoffrey C., and Carsey, Thomas M.. 2002. “Party Polarization and ‘Conflict Extension’ in the American Electorate.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (4): 786802.Google Scholar
Levendusky, Matthew S., and Pope, Jeremy C.. 2011. “Red States vs. Blue States: Going Beyond the Mean.” Public Opinion Quarterly 75 (2): 227–48.Google Scholar
Lewis, Jeffrey B., Poole, Keith, Rosenthal, Howard, Boche, Adam, Rudkin, Aaron, and Sonnet, Luke. 2021. “Voteview: Congressional Roll-Call Votes.” https://voteview.com/.Google Scholar
Maoz, Zeev, and Somer-Topcu, Zeynep. 2010. “Political Polarization and Cabinet Stability in Multiparty Systems: A Social Networks Analysis of European Parliaments, 1945–98.” British Journal of Political Science 40 (4): 805–33.Google Scholar
Mason, Lilliana. 2018. Uncivil Agreement: How Politics Became Our Identity. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Mehlhaff, Isaac D. 2023. “Replication Data for: A Group-Based Approach to Measuring Polarization.” Harvard Dataverse. Dataset. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/ZTWRSQ.Google Scholar
Montalvo, Jose G., and Reynal-Querol, Marta. 2003. “Religious Polarization and Economic Development.” Economics Letters 80 (2): 201–10.Google Scholar
Park, Bernadette, and Judd, Charles M.. 1990. “Measures and Models of Perceived Group Variability.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 59 (2): 173–91.Google Scholar
Parsons, Bryan M. 2015. “The Social Identity Politics of Peer Networks.” American Politics Research 43 (4): 680707.Google Scholar
Rehm, Philipp, and Reilly, Timothy. 2010. “United We Stand: Constituency Homogeneity and Comparative Party Polarization.” Electoral Studies 29 (1): 4053.Google Scholar
Wagner, Markus. 2021. “Affective Polarization in Multiparty Systems.” Electoral Studies 69: 102199.Google Scholar
Ward, Dalston G., and Tavits, Margit. 2019. “How Partisan Affect Shapes Citizens’ Perception of the Political World.” Electoral Studies 60: 102045.Google Scholar
Wilder, David A. 1978. “Reduction of Intergroup Discrimination through Individuation of the Out-Group.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 36 (12): 1361–74.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Stylized Distributions of Polarization FeaturesNote: Simulated bimodal Gaussian mixture distributions with $ {\mu}_{global}=0 $. Labels show polarization levels according to each measure. Plots labeled a–d to correspond to explanations in text.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Congressional Polarization EstimatesNote: Calculated using NOMINATE ideal point estimates; each measure unit-normalized to enable comparison. All point estimates are available in the online replication materials.

Figure 2

Table 1. Correlation Between Congressional Polarization Estimates and Party Unity Scores

Figure 3

Figure 3. Estimates of Elite PolarizationNote: Kernel density plots for each country (a) and polarization estimates with bootstrapped 95% confidence intervals (b). The online replication materials present point estimates and standard errors.

Figure 4

Figure 4. Correlates of Affective PolarizationNote: Error bars give bootstrapped 95% confidence intervals. Full results reported in online replication materials.

Supplementary material: Link

Mehlhaff Dataset

Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Mehlhaff supplementary material

Mehlhaff supplementary material

Download Mehlhaff supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 881 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.