Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T06:45:52.046Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Are regime changes always bad economics? Evidence from daily financial data

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 March 2024

Devin Incerti
Affiliation:
Independent Researcher, USA
Trevor Incerti*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
*
Corresponding author: Trevor Incerti; Email: t.n.incerti@uva.nl
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Political instability is commonly thought to discourage investment and reduce economic growth. We challenge this consensus by showing that instability does not systematically depress investment. Using an event study approach, we examine daily returns of national financial indices in every country that experienced an irregular regime change subject to data availability. Returns following resignations are large and positive (+4 percent), while those following assassinations are negative and smaller in magnitude (−2 percent). The impact of coups tends to be negative (−2 percent), but we show that a pro-business coup results in large positive returns (+10 percent). We also find evidence that authoritarian or anti-business regime changes are more likely to lead to capital flight than democratic or pro-business changes. The immediate impact of political instability on investment is therefore dependent on the type of regime change and its expected impact on future growth.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Vinod K. Aggarwal

Economies are now global, financialized, and integrated, with domestic economies intrinsically linked to international investment. However, political instability such as coups and other regimes changes appear to jeopardize access to capital. Investors, multinational firms, development agencies, and aid organizations rank political risk as a top consideration when making investment decisions in emerging markets. Footnote 1 These considerations of political risk are reflected in research showing that political instability is negatively correlated with investment, financial development, and GDP growth, Footnote 2 as well as associated with increases in stock market variance. Footnote 3 Common rationales are that unstable governments act myopically and adopt inefficient policies. Unstable governments have, for example, been argued to be less likely to invest in the legal system and the protection of property rights, Footnote 4 and to be more likely to increases taxes. Footnote 5,Footnote 6

In this study, we examine the impact of “irregular” regime changes and public protests on investment in a country’s firms. However, unlike previous studies, we theorize that investors will not be uniformly discouraged by sudden regime change, but will instead recognize some sudden political shocks as “good” for future returns. We therefore (1) remain agnostic about the direction of the effect of political instability, and (2) separately examine the effect of different types of instability on domestic firms’ access to financial capital. Specifically, we examine whether changes in financial flows differ for coups, resignations, assassinations, and protests, as well as for authoritarian vs. democratic and pro-vs-anti-business shifts. Stock market returns are used as an indicator of whether investors view different types of sudden political shocks as “good” or “bad” for future profits. Importantly, expected future profits may differ from general economic performance, as stock prices only reflect the expected future profits of existing publicly-held firms.

We also provide methodological advancements when compared to the aforementioned cross-country studies. Specifically, we conduct event studies of daily financial data, which estimate a local average treatment effect of an unexpected event on stock prices at the exact time of the event. This interrupted time-series approach mitigates the endogeneity problems in previous cross-country regressions—confounding events would need to occur on the same day as instability, and do so for a large portion of all of our independently tested events in order to influence our estimates. Footnote 7 In addition, we integrate synthetic control and event study methods and demonstrate how “synthetic” control portfolios can be used to apply a method akin to market-model event studies even when a suitable control portfolio is absent.

We analyze the full sample of politically unstable events for which national-level daily financial data is available—13 successful coups, 8 assassinations, 15 forced resignations, and 11 public protests. Footnote 8 In addition, we examine 24 failed coups in order to compare the impact of successful coups that resulted in regime change to coups attempts that did not. We also engage in a closer examination of the failed 2002 Venezuelan coup, as it provides a special case that allows us to observe the effects of both a seemingly successful pro-business coup, and the immediate reinstatement of a left-wing populist. Our study therefore not only uses an event study approach to enhance the reliability of our estimates, but simultaneously examines a relatively large sample that enhances external validity and allows us to show that different types of political events have disparate effects.

We find that coups, assassinations, resignations, and public protests cause large increases in financial volatility. However, the magnitude and direction of the effects differ by type of regime change. On average, abnormal returns following resignations are large and positive (+4 percent) while abnormal returns following assassinations and coups tend to be negative and smaller in magnitude (−2 percent). We also find suggestive evidence that authoritarian regime changes are more likely to lead to negative returns than democratic regime changes. Finally, we examine the effect of pro-versus anti-business regime change via an in-depth examination of the seemingly successful but ultimately failed coup against Hugo Chavez in 2002. Stock prices increased dramatically (+10 percent) after the failed overthrow of Chavez’s socialist regime and decreased by approximately the same magnitude following his return to leadership.

Our primary contributions are empirical and methodological. We provide the first estimates of the effects of different types of political instability on domestic capital access. We show that instability does not systematically depress investment, and find evidence that authoritarian regime changes are more likely to lead to negative returns, but that leaders who are clearly pro-business can be rewarded by financial markets even if they use extra-judicial methods to take power. The capital flows we document are not insubstantial—they are in some cases larger shocks than the 2008 stock market crash on their respective domestic economies. Methodologically, we (1) employ a method less susceptible to endogeneity concerns than previous studies, and (2) integrate synthetic control and event study methods to allow for control portfolios when a control candidate is not present.

Reexamining how markets respond to irregular regime changes

Stable capital flows are important to financial stability in emerging markets, which are particularly exposed to shifts in the availability of foreign capital. Footnote 9 High country risk reduces capital flows, which in turn has been shown to reduce domestic output growth. Footnote 10 Conventional theory and cross-country empirical evidence suggests that political instability—as measured by events such as protests, strikes, assassinations, number of regime changes, and ongoing elections—depresses investment. Footnote 11 However, if market returns reflect investor expectations about future economic growth and expected returns, there are reasons to believe such hypotheses may be overly simplistic.

First, a change in regime may be seen as a positive event for future economic performance if the current regime is regarded as anti-business or anti-global. Regime changes that attempt to overthrow anti-business autocrats may be expected to result in positive abnormal returns as investors see little risk of a replacement government “worse” than the status quo. For example, there is an active debate on whether “good coups” that lead to democratization or economic liberalization can be good for economic growth. Alesina et al. (Reference Alesina, Özler, Roubini and Swagel1996) argue that the negative effects of uncertainty dominate the positive effects of coups staged by pro growth factions, while Alesina and Perotti (Reference Alesina and Perotti1996) submit that “unconstitutional” regime changes such as coups are worse for economic growth than other types of political instability. Londregan and Poole (Reference Londregan and Poole1990) find that coups have no impact on economic growth and hypothesize that this may be because there is a bimodal distribution of coups, some of which enhance growth and others which restrict it.

Most research suggests that “good coups” are not the norm, Footnote 12 but some evidence suggests that they have become more frequent Footnote 13 and could have positive economic effects. Meyersson (Reference Meyersson2016) finds that coup attempts that occur in democratic regimes are associated with negative GDP growth, while those that occur in autocratic regimes are associated with positive GDP growth. In another study examining the same outcome variable as our own—financial returns—Girardi and Bowles (Reference Girardi and Bowles2018) show that Salvador Allende’s socialist government was associated with declines in stock prices while the coup that replaced him boosted them.

Previous research therefore suggests that on average coups should not be expected to lead to increased economic development or positive market returns, but that positive returns associated with “good coups” could occasionally be present. We shed light on this theory as our event study approach also allows us to examine “good coups”—coups that lead to democratization or economic liberalization—separately from others. As we are not limited to a single case study, we can provide both a cross-country and within-case analysis.

Second, it is not necessarily the case that even a sudden, extra-legal, or unexpected regime change will result in higher levels of instability. Not all regime changes are equivalent—resignations, assassinations, and coups are all examples of sudden regime changes and have been used as proxies for instability in previous research. However, resignations often occur when an ineffective leader steps down. By contrast, assassinations are not always related to the effectiveness of a leader, can occur seemingly at random, and the successor to the assassinated leader may be unclear. Coups can occur in the name of democracy or autocracy, and in general signal relative weakness in the current political system. These differences are often overlooked in past empirical strategies, which have proxied for instability in terms of the number of coups, Footnote 14 assassinations or revolutions, Footnote 15 or have combined various metrics into single indices. Footnote 16,Footnote 17 In another cross-country regression study, Jong-A-Pin (Reference Jong-A-Pin2009) disaggregates instability into four main metrics, one of which is regime changes, but does not subset below this metric. By contrast—recognizing the different degrees of instability that these events may reflect—we estimate effects separately for coups, assassinations, resignations, and protests. Our event study approach affords us this freedom without encountering the statistical power issues that would arise in a regression setting.

Third, the theoretical link through which political events are expected to have an impact on daily stock prices is changes in the broader macroeconomic environment that influence the expected stream of future profits of existing publicly-held firms. Examples of expected changes in the macroeconomic environment that can be influenced by sudden political events include: shifts in monetary policy, changes in trade or FDI openness, shifts in regulatory policy, changes in the share of output going to capital, transfer and convertibility restrictions, degree of resource nationalism, and heightened risk of capital expropriation or breach of contracts. Not all shocks to the political system will result in similar shifts in these macroeconomic variables depending on the actors involved, their ideological preferences, and their expected ability to enact policy changes.

Different types of regime changes may therefore have disparate effects on investment, just as they may differentially effect overall economic growth. Taken together, the theory and research above suggests that coups should on average lead to negative returns, but sometimes lead to positive returns when the coup’s instigators are clearly more pro market than the regime they replace. Assassinations should have a neutral or negative impact as they increase uncertainty, but institutional responses to assassinations vary by country. By contrast, resignations may be viewed positively on average, as they typically signal the departure of an ineffective leader and may in fact signal increased stability. Using immediate, day-of shocks to stock prices as our outcome variable, we investigate the hypothesis that investors will positively update their perceptions of future economic performance when a sudden political event clearly shifts a country in a pro-democratic or pro-business direction, and negatively update when an event merely exacerbates instability or uncertainty.

Our empirical findings validate these predictions. We find that the type of political event and its expected impact on economic policy determines the direction of investment. Events expected to lead to more stable governance, economic liberalization, or democratization (such as willful resignations and coups that overthrow protectionist or leftist autocrats) are associated with positive returns, while those that consolidate authoritarian rule (e.g., military coups), exacerbate poor economic policies, or merely increase policy uncertainty (such as assassinations) have the opposite effect. Of course, changes in stock prices reflect investor’s expected changes in the macroeconomic environment, and these expectations may differ from realized future economic performance. Nevertheless, it is clear from our results that even sudden and extra-legal regime changes can be viewed as a “positive” event by investors under the right circumstances.

Data

Financial data are from the Global Financial Data database, which includes the longest available daily time series of stock prices. We collect data on national equity indices and two global equity indices, the S&P/IFC Emerging Market Investable Composite and the Morgan Stanley Capital International (MSCI) World Index. The S&P/IFC index includes securities from emerging markets while the MSCI index includes securities from developed markets only. We collect national stock index data on every country in which there was a coup or coup attempt, an assassination or failed assassination, or a forced resignation and for which daily financial data is available. Footnote 18 The longest available daily time series for these stock indices are listed in Table 1.

Table 1. List of stock indices

Political data are primarily drawn from the Center for Systemic Peace’s (CSP) Polity IV Coup d’etat dataset and Coup d’etat Events handbook. The Coup d’etat dataset includes the date of (1) successful coups, (2) attempted coups, (3) plotted coups and (4) alleged coup plots. We focus on successful coups because it is difficult to classify failed coups, and the choice of dataset and classification methodology would directly alter our findings. Needler (Reference Needler1966, p. 617) has gone so far as to say that “the categories of coups that were aborted, suppressed, or abandoned melt into each other and into a host of other non-coup phenomena so as to defy accounting,” the Center for Systemic Peace states that it is “confident that [its] list of successful coups is comprehensive” but does not extend this confidence to attempted or failed coups, and Powell and Thyne (Reference Powell and Thyne2011) state that it is “difficult to identify more ambiguous forms of coup activity, such as coup failures, plots, and rumors.” With this caveat in mind, we nevertheless additionally construct a database of failed coups from the Colpus dataset Footnote 19 in order to test for robustness to inclusion of ambiguous coup cases, which can be found in Table A.6 in the appendix.

The Coup d’etat Events handbook also provides a list of (1) auto-coups Footnote 20 , (2) the ouster of leadership by foreign forces, (3) the ouster of leadership by rebel forces, (4) assassinations of the executive and (5) resignations of the executive due to poor performance and/or loss of authority. Daily financial data is available for countries in categories 4 and 5, so we supplement the coups with assassinations and resignations to form a list of “irregular” regime changes. The resignations are those in which the ruling executive was coerced to resign due to poor performance, public discontent and popular demonstrations. Note that the Polity IV definition of “poor performance” is not synonymous with poor economic performance, and in practice the reasons cited for resignation across events are: loss in conflict/war, anti-authoritarian protest, corruption scandals, Supreme Court ruling against unconstitutional actions, contested elections, and abuse of power.

We further supplement the CSP data with leadership data from Archigos Version 4.1, which allows us to identify additional cases in which a “leader lost power through irregular means.” Irregular transfers of power are those in which leaders do not leave office “in a manner prescribed by either explicit rules or established conventions.” Nearly all removals by irregular means result from the threat or use of force (e.g., coups, revolts and assassinations).

A list of the political events in our dataset is shown in Table 2. Coups tend to have the largest impact on the level of democratization as a number of countries have subsequently transitioned from democracies to anocracies or autocracies. On the other hand, neither assassinations or resignations have much of an impact on the level of democratization.

Table 2. Regime changes

Notes: The Polity score is used to classify political outcomes as follows: autocracy = $ - 10 \le score \le - 6$ , anocracy = $ - 5 \le score \le 5$ , and democracy = $6 \le score \le 10$ .

The discussion above shows that there is considerable debate about classification of regime changes. We recognize that some readers may feel that certain events are missing based on their own substantive knowledge. However, we choose to rely on commonly used third-party classifications in order to minimize the possibility that our results are driven by our own subjective classifications. The one exception is that we separately study the failed coup attempt in Venezuela in April 2002 in which the President of Venezuela, Hugo Chavez, was removed from office for two days because it provides a natural test of the impact of the seemingly successful removal of a left-wing populist with a pro-business regime, and the ensuing reinstatement of a left-wing populist.

To gain perspective on the relationship between irregular regime changes and the stock market, Figure 1 plots the absolute value of daily stock returns averaged across all events. Returns are for 200 trading days before and after regime changes. The absolute value of returns on the event day (trading day 0) are significantly larger than on any other day. In addition, the magnitude of returns begins increasing just before the event day and remains high for a short period after. This suggests that financial volatility increases during the days surrounding regime changes, although it does not provide any evidence on mean returns.

Figure 1. Absolute value of daily returns.

Impact of Political Instability on Stock Returns tests these results more formally. It will first formally estimate the amount of volatility surrounding all irregular regime changes, then analyze coups, assassinations and resignations separately and determine what impact they have on mean returns.

Estimation strategy

We estimate the effect of irregular regime changes on financial flows using an interrupted time series—also known as event study—approach, and examine the impact of political events on stock returns using daily financial data. Additional explanation of the theoretical logic of why mean daily stock market returns would be influenced by politically unstable events is warranted. Event studies rely on the theoretical assumption that investors anticipate the effect of sudden events (e.g., corporate announcements, regulatory policy changes, political events, etc.) on future profitability of a firm or firms in a market, and importantly, that these anticipated changes in profitability are immediately reflected in stock market prices. The approach therefore implicitly relies on the efficient market hypothesis, or the idea that in an efficient market, stocks instantly incorporate publicly available information into their prices. Footnote 21 The immediate nature of this effect allows us to use the magnitude and direction of sudden fluctuations in granular daily data as a proxy for investors’ expected valuation of the event in terms of future profits. This in turn allows us to examine how global financial actors value different kinds of politically unstable events—for example, pro-vs-anti-business coups.

The focus on immediate fluctuations in daily financial data implies that we are examining the effect of “one shot” regime changes akin to a sudden day-of shock. Our estimates therefore capture the effect of these sudden, unexpected shocks on stock prices on the same day of the shock. Importantly, this implies that we are not estimating the effect of any larger underlying political conditions surrounding the event, but rather only the immediate event itself independent of other surrounding conditions. Further, as this approach provides an estimate at the exact time of the event, confounding events would need to occur on the same day, and do so for a large portion of all of our independently tested events in order to influence our estimates. We recognize that broader definitions of political instability may encompass political volatility over a wider range of time. In an attempt to address this concern, we also examine the impact of periods of protest and failed coup attempts on financial returns in the appendix.

The key identifying assumption behind our interrupted time-series approach is that the events are unpredicted in an immediate temporal sense. In other words, for an event to be plausibly exogenous, the exact timing of the event must be unknown to investors. If information about the event has leaked prior to occurrence of the event, a portion of the change in investment will already be priced into the index during the estimation window.

Volatility

Before examining the magnitude and direction of returns, we first confirm that our sample of events exhibits the increases in volatility suggested by previous literature. Since stock volatility is not directly observable, one must decide how to best estimate volatility. Our estimates are obtained from a generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (GARCH) model estimated using 1000 pre-event days, the event day and 1000 post-event days. As in Jensen and Schmith (Reference Jensen and Schmith2005) and Leblang and Mukherjee (Reference Leblang and Mukherjee2005), we use the GARCH (1,1) specification. In particular, for national stock index $i$ ,

$${R_{it}} = {\mu _i} + {\epsilon _{it}},{\rm{\;\;\;\;}}{\epsilon _{it}}\sim{\cal N}\left( {0,\sigma _{it}^2} \right),$$

where ${\mu _i}$ is a constant and,

$$\sigma _{it}^2 = {\gamma _i} + {\alpha _i}\epsilon _{i,t - 1}^2 + {\beta _i}\sigma _{i,t - 1}^2.$$

The key parameter of interest is the conditional variance, $\sigma _{it}^2$ . The one-period-ahead volatility forecasts, ${\sigma _{it}}$ , are larger when $\epsilon _{i,t - 1}^2$ and $\sigma _{i,t - 1}^2$ are larger. In other words, the model predicts that large shocks will be followed by other large shocks. As robustness checks, we also estimate volatility using exponential GARCH, threshold GARCH, fractionally integrated GARCH, and GARCH(1,1) accounting for structural breaks in the time-series data in the appendix.

Abnormal returns

We now turn to the magnitude and direction of the effect of irregular regime changes on stock returns. We follow the standard event study methodology as presented by, among others, MacKinlay (Reference MacKinlay1997) and Campbell, Lo and MacKinlay (Reference Campbell, Lo and MacKinlay1997). Normal performance is measured with a constant mean return model,

(1) $${R_{it}} = {\mu _i} + {\epsilon _{it}},$$

where ${R_{it}}$ is the logged return of national stock index $i$ on trading day $t$ and ${\epsilon _{it}}$ is the error term. We calculate abnormal returns (ARs), in an “event window” surrounding the date of each coup, ${R_{i\tau }} = {R_{i\tau }} - {\hat \mu _i}$ , where $\tau $ is a date in the event window, and ${\hat \mu _i}$ is estimated in an “estimation window” preceding the event window with Equation 1. We use a 41 day event window (i.e., 20 pre-event trading days, the event day, and 20 post-event trading days). The estimation window is the 250 trading days prior to the start of the event window. The abnormal returns are then used to generate cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) between event day ${\tau _1}$ and event day ${\tau _2}$ : $CAR\left( {{\tau _1},{\tau _2}} \right) = \mathop \sum \nolimits_{\tau = {\tau _1}}^{{\tau _2}} A{R_{i\tau }}$ .

A constant mean return model is used instead of a market model in order to maximize the number of observations and because our unit of analysis is country-wide market indices rather than firms. Footnote 22 To address concerns regarding use of a constant mean return model, we also create a synthetic control portfolio for each event and compare observed returns to the synthetic returns as a robustness check.

We define the event date as the first trading day in which the market could have reacted to news of the event. For example, during the October 12, 1999 coup d’etat in Pakistan led by General Pervez Musharraf, the army announced that Prime Minister Nawaz Sharif had been dismissed after market hours at 10:15 pm. We code October 14th, the day in which the market re-opened, as the event day. When events occurred on weekends, we change the event date to the following Monday.

$\left( {0,\tau - 1} \right)$ is used to denote the $\tau $ -day period beginning with the event day and $\left( { - 1,\tau } \right)$ to denote the negative $\tau $ -day period beginning with the day prior to the event day. In other words, for cumulative abnormal returns prior to the event date, we aggregate backwards starting at the day of the event. For example, $CAR( - 1, - 2$ ) is the sum of the abnormal returns on event date $ - 1$ and event day $ - 2$ . We present results for the sum of abnormal returns over the post-event windows of the event date only $(0,0$ ), the event date plus 6 days $(0,6$ ), and the event date plus 19 days $(0,19$ ). In addition, we present results for the pre-event windows $( - 1, - 7$ ) and $( - 1, - 20$ ).

As we hypothesize that different types of regime changes will have disparate effects on markets, we report abnormal returns separately for coups, assassinations and resignations. Standard errors and p-values are calculated using asymptotic t-statistics as in MacKinlay (Reference MacKinlay1997). Footnote 23

Impact of political instability on stock returns

Volatility

Figure 2 shows the mean volatility ( $\overline {{\sigma _t}} $ ) estimates from the GARCH (1,1) model across all irregular regime changes for 250 trading days prior to and 250 days after each event. Footnote 24 As expected, the volatility estimates stay between a narrow range at nearly all dates except those surrounding the regime change. Volatility appears to increase slowly just before the regime change, albeit not to a degree out of line with previous fluctuations in volatility. This may suggest that investors sometimes have information about the events before they occur. Nonetheless, there is still an enormous volatility jump on the day of the regime change. Volatility then decreases to normal levels within a month of the event.

Figure 2. Mean of volatility estimates from GARCH(1,1) models.

Abnormal returns

Coups

Table 3 shows abnormal returns for national stock indices both preceding and following coup d’etat. Table 3 contains all coups presented in Table 2 with the exception of the Argentinian coup of March 24, 1976. The March 24, 1976 Argentinian coup is excluded from our analysis because the stock market remained closed from March 24 to April 5, 1976, or a period of twelve days. Footnote 25

Table 3. Abnormal returns following coups

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. “Days to rebound” is the number of trading days following a negative stock return for the national stock index to return to pre-event level (it is calculated if the price decreases on the event day, not if the event day abnormal return is negative). Returns are inflation adjusted.

The average coup has a −2.1 percent event day AR. Event day ARs for the 1970 coup in Argentina, the 1991 coup in Thailand, the 1992 coup in Peru, and the 1999 coup in Pakistan are all negative and statistically different than zero. Moreover, all of these cases except Thailand have negative post-event CARs and pre-event CARs that are statistically indistinguishable from zero. In all of these cases, the coup either overthrew a democratically elected government or changed governance from one military ruler to another. The initial negative reaction followed by additional post-event negativity is consistent with the expected market reaction from a successful authoritarian coup followed by post-event consolidation of power.

The only events with positive ARs are the 1971 coup in Argentina and the 2002 coup in Nepal. These results provide evidence that coups do not necessarily lead to negative abnormal returns. While the 1971 Argentinian coup did result in another military leader, it did so while calling for free and democratic elections and replaced a government that had adopted extreme protectionist economic policies. In fact, by 1973 Argentina had transitioned to a democracy. Footnote 26 The 2002 coup in Nepal resulted in a monarchical restoration, but occurred after the country’s prime minister postponed general elections, itself a democratically subversive action.

Assassinations

The results in Table 4 are produced from analyses identical to those in Table 3 but for assassinations rather than coups. Like the majority of coups, there is evidence that assassinations decrease stock prices. The mean event day abnormal return is negative and statistically different than zero. However, the result is driven by five events: the shooting of US President William McKinley on September 6, 1901; the assassination of US President John F. Kennedy on November 22, 1963; the assassination of Indian Prime Minister Indira Gandhi on October 31, 1984; the suicide bombing that killed Sri Lankan president Ranasinghe Premadasa on May 1, 1993; and the assassination of Israeli Prime Minister Yitzhak Rabin on the evening of November 4, 1995.

Table 4. Abnormal returns following assassinations

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. “Days to rebound” is the number of trading days following a negative stock return for the national stock index to return to pre-event level (it is calculated if the price decreases on the event day, not if the event day abnormal return is negative). Returns are inflation adjusted.

These results are consistent with our hypothesis that the nature of the political event and its expected impact on policy matters, and that assassinations should have a negative effect as they occur seemingly at random and increase uncertainty. While the mean effect of assassinations is negative, it is smaller in magnitude than for coups. Unlike a coup, an assassination may not necessarily be expected to cause immediate change in economic policy, particularly in the presence of an institutionalized line of succession. As such, we would expect CARs to be negative due to increased instability and uncertainty, but smaller in magnitude to a coup or resignation due to greater expectations of policy inertia.

There is no evidence of post- or pre-event CARs in almost any of the assassinations. This is consistent with expectations as assassinations are typically not predictable. As with coups, the number of days that it took the stock market to rebound to pre-event levels is fairly low. Footnote 27

Resignations

In contrast to coups and assassinations, abnormal returns following resignations are large and positive (see Table 5). The mean event day abnormal return is over 4 percent and the positive returns are persistent and grow larger over time (mean 20-day CAR $ \approx $ 12 percent). Furthermore, event day ARs are only negative and statistically significant at even the 10 percent level in two out of the fifteen resignations (Pakistan on April 19, 1993 and Tunisia on June 31, 2011).

Table 5. Abnormal returns following resignations

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. “Days to rebound” is the number of trading days following a negative stock return for the national stock index to return to pre-event level (it is calculated if the price decreases on the event day, not if the event day abnormal return is negative). Returns are inflation adjusted.

These results are again consistent with our hypothesis that different events will have disparate effects, and that resignations may lead to positive returns. The positive event day abnormal return following resignations is not surprising as resignations typically occur because of poor performance and/or loss of authority. Among our sample of events, leaders were ousted following loss in conflict/war, anti-authoritarian protest, corruption scandals, Supreme Court ruling against unconstitutional actions, contested elections, and abuse of power.

For example, consider Ferdinand Marcos’ resignation from office as President of the Philippines in February 1986. Prior to his resignation, the Philippine regime was known for rampant corruption, crony capitalism, extreme inequality, high unemployment, failed import substitution industrialization policy, and oligarchic control of the economy. Footnote 28 In fact, the Philippines was the least preferred site for foreign investment amongst East Asian capitalist economies and possessed one of the worst capital investment to economic output ratios in Asia. Footnote 29 Marcos held a snap presidential election on February 7, 1986, in which he declared victory despite overwhelming evidence of electoral fraud. Public protests ensued, and two weeks later the military withdrew its support of the Marcos regime. Footnote 30 Marcos was replaced by his electoral opponent, Corazon Aquino, who had run on a platform of economic liberalization and elimination of crony capitalism. Footnote 31 This event was associated with an approximately 13 percent positive event day AR.

By contrast, the largest negative event in our sample (−3 percent) is the 1993 resignation of President Ghulam Ishaq Khan and Prime Minister Nawaz Sharif in Pakistan. The resignations occurred after months of political infighting when the army demanded the President and Prime Minister resign and call for new elections. An interim prime minister was installed, but uncertainty about Pakistan’s political and economic future remained high prior to the next round of elections.

The resignations studied in this paper are those in which leaders left office because of poor performance, public discontent and popular protests. It is therefore not unreasonable to expect the political actions preceding the resignations to have similarly large effects on financial markets. Footnote 32 To examine this, we explore all resignations that were driven by significant popular demonstrations, riots, non-violent civil resistance and other forms of public discontent in Public Protests in the appendix. Footnote 33 When taking directionality into account, it appears that public protests have no effect on stock returns. However, this occurs because some political movements increase stock prices while others decrease them, and the absolute value of stock returns are approximately 1.5 percent higher during public protests (see Table A.2). Footnote 34

Exploring possible mechanisms

While markets may generally dislike political instability, the immediate effect of regime changes on markets may not always be unpredictable. For example, investors may generally value democracy if it is perceived to provide stronger property rights and lower susceptibility to capital appropriation. Footnote 35 In addition, when the successor in an irregular regime change is clear, investors may have strong priors about the effect of the new leader on economic and/or market performance. Two possible mechanisms that could be driving the differences may therefore be: (1) whether the regime change is associated with an authoritarian or democratic shift in governance, and (2) whether a new leader is clearly more pro- or anti-business than their predecessor.

We first attempt to explore these mechanisms by aggregating all of the events in our sample by whether they resulted in a shift in an authoritarian or democratic direction. Footnote 36 We find suggestive evidence that regime changes associated with authoritarian shifts are on average perceived negatively by investors (see Table 6), while those that move governance in a democratic direction are on average perceived positively (see Table 7). We refer to this evidence as suggestive despite statistical significance due to the small sample of cases which fit these criteria, particularly with regard to democratic shifts. We observe ten cases associated with an authoritarian shift in governance. Only two of these events result in positive CARs, and neither are significantly different from zero. Five cases resulted in a democratic shift in governance. Three of these five cases result in positive CARs. Of the two negative CARs, one is not significantly different from zero, and the other is associated with a forced market closure that lasted 17 days. However, the majority of the positive returns from democratic regime changes come from the 13 percent positive CAR associated with the resignation of Ferdinand Marcos in the Philippines in 1986.

Table 6. Abnormal returns following authoritarian regime changes

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. “Days to rebound” is the number of trading days following a negative stock return for the national stock index to return to pre-event level (it is calculated if the price decreases on the event day, not if the event day abnormal return is negative). Returns are inflation adjusted.

Table 7. Abnormal returns following democratic regime changes

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. “Days to rebound” is the number of trading days following a negative stock return for the national stock index to return to pre-event level (it is calculated if the price decreases on the event day, not if the event day abnormal return is negative). Returns are inflation adjusted.

A similar analysis is not possible for shifts from pro- or anti-business leaders, as examples of such clear and plausibly exogenous shifts in leader economic ideology do not exist in our sample. Footnote 37 We therefore look outside of the sample above and conduct an in-depth case study of a seemingly pro-business and anti-socialist coup followed by the reinstatement of a socialist government: the 2002 failed coup against Hugo Chavez in Venezuela.

The ultimately failed Venezuelan coup against Hugo Chavez replaced a left-wing populist government with a new pro-business president, and therefore provides a natural test of the effects of both pro-business and anti-business regime changes separately from simple uncertainty because investors reacted to an expected regime change twice: first, when Chavez was ousted, and second, when he was reinstated. On the evening of April 11, 2002, coup plotters removed Chavez from office and later detained him. Pedro Carmona, a Venezuelan economist and business leader, was named the transitional President of Venezuela. Two days later, on April 13, 2002, a popular uprising led to Chavez’s reinstatement as president. This provides an estimate of the market’s valuation of a transition from the Chavez regime to the Carmona regime and its valuation of a transition from the Carmona regime back to the Chavez regime. By extension, it provides an estimate of the impact of a shift from a left-wing populist government to a pro-business regime in an emerging market.

Figure 3 provides graphical evidence on the effect of the coup attempt. The top panel shows CARs for the 10 days prior to and following the event, along with 95% confidence intervals. The daily ARs and corresponding confidence intervals are displayed in the bottom panel. The abnormal return on April 12, the first trading day in which investors could react to the coup, was +10 percent. The market reacted in the opposite direction to Chavez’s reinstatement as president: the abnormal return on the next trading day, April 15, 2002, was −8 percent.

Figure 3. Abnormal returns surrounding the 2002 Venezuelan coup attempt.

The results in Figure 3 are particularly striking given the discrepancy between the ARs on event days 0 and 1 and all other days. Consistent with our earlier findings that coups tend to have pre- and post-event CARs that are statistically indistinguishable from zero, the only days on which the 2002 Venezuelan coup d’etat attempt ARs are statistically different from zero is on event days 0 and 1 after the coup attempt. The almost 0 percent 10-day CAR preceding the coup makes this an ideal case as it implies that investors were completely unaware of the coup plot, increasing our confidence that the abnormal returns capture the true effect of the Chavez to Carmona and Carmona to Chavez regime changes on stock returns. This failed coup therefore demonstrates a large positive market reaction to the attempted overthrow of a socialist leader, and an equally large negative reaction to his reinstatement. More generally, the large magnitudes and precision of these effects suggest that investors primarily value transition to a pro-business government regime, regardless of how the regime change is achieved.

Robustness

There are some potential concerns with the results in the Coups, Assassinations, and Resignations sections. First, the abnormal returns could have been driven by factors unrelated to the regime changes. Second, the true effects of regime changes on firm value may be underestimated if investors had a-priori information. Third, the reported means are based on small sample sizes so confidence intervals based on normally distributed abnormal returns may be inappropriate. Finally, for coups, it may also be useful to compare successful coups to unsuccessful events (rather than no coup), as the latter may adjust for selection into unstable events.

We explore these concerns in the following ways. First, we reestimate mean CARs on a set of time-shifted placebo dates, with means computed across all events for each type of regime change. We shift event dates surrounding the actual event date backwards and forwards in increments of five days (−20, 15, 10, 5, 0, 5, 10, 15, and 20 days). In addition, we extend the forward shifted event dates to one year (110, 195, 285, and 365 days) to capture dates that are likely to be completely unaffected by the regime change. The general intuition is that we should not observe significant abnormal returns when performing an identical test on dates where no intervention (i.e., a politically unstable event) occurred. Observing such effects would call the research design and modeling assumptions into question, and raise concerns that the abnormal returns were caused by factors other than the regime changes.

Figure 4 compares mean CARs estimated using the actual event date (Figure 4a) to CARs estimated with the event date shifted 1-year (365 days) into the future (Figure 4b). Figure 4a—which reproduces the tabular results presented in the Coups, Assassinations, and Resignations sections—shows that assassinations and coups are associated with negative event day ARs while resignations are associated with positive event day ARs. In contrast, there are no discernible abnormal returns in Figure 4b. The event day ARs are considerably smaller in magnitude and are not statistically different from zero for either coups or resignations. Moreover, while CARs estimated using the actual event date for resignations trend upwards following the event day, there is no consistent trend in the placebo analysis. Figure 4 therefore suggests that the main results are not merely an artifact of the data.

Figure 4. Mean cumulative abnormal returns by type of regime change.

To ensure that results of the placebo test based on 1-year did not occur by chance, Figure A.14 plots event-day abnormal against the number of days shifted. There are a few instances in which there are statistically significant (at the 5 percent level) ARs in the same direction as those on the actual event day, but they are always smaller in magnitude than the ARs estimated using the actual event date. Most of the statistically significant placebo estimates also occur when dates are shifted within the post-event window (days 0–20), a period during which stock returns remain volatile and, in the case of resignations, there is a consistent upward trend in the CARs. When dates are shifted forward further ( $ \ge $ 110 days), the event day AR is only statistically significant in one case (day 365 for assassinations). Overall, these results reinforce the main results: the ARs on the actual event date capture most of effect of the regime change, although effects can sometimes persist in the short event window following the event date.

These figures also provide evidence on the extent to which regime changes appear to be unexpected. For instance, the CARs prior to assassinations and coups presented in Figure 4a tend to be close to zero, suggesting that investors were unaware that a negative event was likely to occur in the coming days. For resignations, CARs trend downward in the 10 days prior to the event; however, if investors were aware that a resignation were about to occur one would expect the pre-event CARs to be positive given the positive CARs observed in the post-event window. By contrast, a clear break exists between the negative pre-event trend and positive event day jump and post-event trend. For coups, there is suggestive evidence of a negative pre-trend in the run up to the event. However, the overall 7-day and 20-day pre-trends are both insignificant at conventional levels. There is also a much larger jump in negative CARs on the day of the event. This therefore implies that even if investors had some expectation of a negative event occurring, they were unaware of its timing, and at worst a portion of the negative change in investment was already priced into the day-of shift. There is thus little evidence that the CARs in the post-event window are not capturing most of the effect caused by the regime changes.

Second, we create a synthetic control portfolio for each event based on the techniques introduced in Abadie and Gardeazabal (Reference Abadie and Gardeazabal2003) and Abadie, Diamond and Hainmueller (Reference Abadie, Diamond and Hainmueller2010). This approach creates a “synthetic” time series of daily financial returns based on the returns in a basket of countries which did not experience tumultuous political events on the day of the event. We are then able to compare the returns in the country which experienced the unexpected regime change with the actual returns of a reference market—in this case all countries that did not experience an unexpected regime change. Footnote 38 Each country is given a weight which represents its influence in the synthetic control portfolio. The weight is chosen so that the daily returns and the variance of the daily returns of the control portfolio and the event country are most similar in the estimation window. Footnote 39 The set of possible countries in the control portfolio consists of all countries listed in Table 1. In contrast with the large and significant abnormal returns in the actual countries of study, the returns in the synthetic control portfolio are never significantly different from zero for coups, assassinations, or resignations (or when aggregated together).

Non-parametric statistical techniques that are free from distributional assumptions are used to address concerns about inferences from small sample sizes. We employ the sign and the rank tests, which are based on the sign and the rank of the event day ARs respectively. Footnote 40 Both tests are less influenced by departures from normality than statistics based on traditional t-tests such as those reported earlier in this paper. Table 8 compares event day ARs as well as “abnormal absolute returns” between the event country and the synthetic control portfolio using the non-parametric methods discussed above. The “abnormal absolute returns” are abnormal returns for the absolute value of stock returns. This is done to combine events since resignations tend to increase returns while assassinations and coups tend to decrease them. The idea that the absolute value of returns might increase during irregular regime changes is similar to the finding that volatility increases and is consistent with Figure 1.

Table 8. Non-parametric tests of the impact of regime changes

Notes: Estimates for assassinations do not include the assassination of US president William McKinley in 1901 because no control portfolios are available.

As shown in Table 8, the mean event day abnormal returns for coups, assassinations and resignations are all statistically different from zero at the 1 percent level using the rank test statistic and the abnormal returns for coups and assassinations are significant at at least the 10 percent level using the sign test. In addition, abnormal absolute returns for all events are statistically significant at at least the 5 percent level using both the rank and sign tests. On the other hand, the event day abnormal returns for the control portfolio are never statistically different from zero at even the 10 percent level using the rank or sign tests. Finally, the difference in means between the regime change country and the control portfolio are statistically different from zero for coups (1 percent level), assassinations (10 percent level), resignations (5 percent level), and all events combined (1 percent level) when using two-sided p-values from the Wilcoxon rank test. Footnote 41 In sum, the synthetic control and small sample tests suggest that the main results are not a result of deviations from normality or confounding world events.

Finally, we supplement our list of successful coups with a list of failed coups from the Colpus data set Footnote 42 and show robustness to including and excluding ambiguous cases by reestimating our models while also including failed coups. This analysis demonstrates that including failed coups reduces the magnitude of the negative effect of coups overall, but that the estimates remain negative and statistically significant (see Table A.7). This result is clarified by analyzing failed coups independently of successful coups, which reveals a slightly negative but insignificant effect of failed coups on returns, suggesting that ambiguous cases and plots tend not to have the same level of directed impact on average as successful regime changes (see Table A.6).

Discussion and conclusion

While conventional wisdom suggests investors dislike unexpected regime changes, we show that this is not necessarily always the case. Unexpected changes in ruler virtually always increase market volatility, but the directionality is not always negative as markets can be given a boost when a new regime is expected to offer a more stable, democratic, or pro-business environment than the previous one.

Coups and other types of regime changes remain common, highlighting their relevance for economic and political development. Our sample consists of 5 coups, 1 assassination, 7 resignations, and 7 instances of public protect since 2000. The Arab spring is perhaps the most notable, with protests spreading throughout the Middle East in late 2010. There have also been a number of failed coups such as the 2002 coup attempt against Hugo Chavez and the 2016 failed coup in Turkey. Footnote 43 Yet despite their frequency there is little evidence on their economic consequences.

This paper helps fill the evidence gap by using an event study approach that exploits daily returns of national stock market indices. This approach provides well-identified estimates of the effect of regime changes on investment that is less susceptible to endogeneity bias than prior cross-country studies. Furthermore, the large sample of political events in our study increases the generalizability of our findings.

The results are consistent with the idea that perceptions of government competence and changes in government have large impacts on investor confidence. But although the effect of regime changes and protests on stock volatility is substantial, the effect on the direction of stock returns is not uniformly negative. Abnormal returns following resignations are large and positive (+4 percent), abnormal returns following assassinations are negative and smaller in magnitude (−2 percent), and abnormal returns following coups also tend to be negative (−2 percent). Our examination of pre-event trends in abnormal returns suggests that the positive returns we observe following resignations are not driven by investors anticipating resignations, but not coups or assassinations. CARs trend downward in the days preceding resignations, but if investors anticipated a resignation that brought a more competent leader and increased stability, pre-event CARs should also trend positive.

A test of mechanisms suggests that democratic regime changes are typically preferable to authoritarian regime changes to investors. However, the returns surrounding the failed 2002 coup that temporarily ousted Hugo Chavez from power in Venezuela show that even democratically subversive coups can have positive effects if the instigators are clearly pro-business. These results are consistent with previous research showing that the coup replacing Allende in Chile increased stock market valuations. Footnote 44

Our findings have a number of potential policy implications. First, our finding that even democratically subversive irregular regime changes can have a positive impact on investment when the replacement government is clearly pro-business implies that investor goals and actions may be at odds with regime stability. Second, the immediate nature and large magnitude of the financial outflows we observe in the wake of the majority of coups and assassinations suggests that a weakened financial system and economy are likely to accompany these kinds of regime changes. More optimistically, however, we also find suggestive evidence that in the event of a democratic regime change or revolution, clearly signaling a commitment to democracy may result in increased investment in a country’s firms.

There are a number potential avenues for future research. First, more research is needed to identify the pro- and anti-market characteristics of regime changes. There may be pro- or anti-market features of regime changes that are more nuanced than those identified in this paper. Similarly, it would be useful to identify additional mechanisms through which regime changes effect investment. In the case of Chile, Girardi and Bowles (Reference Girardi and Bowles2018) show that increasing stock market valuations were caused by changes in private property rights rather than economic growth prospects or wage costs. Research focusing on mechanisms in other settings would help generalize these findings. Second, it would be helpful to determine the extent to which stock market returns translate to broader economic development outcomes. Meyersson (Reference Meyersson2016) has made progress on this front by examining the impact of coups on a number of outcomes in addition to economic growth including investment, debt, inflation, infant mortality, and years of schooling. It would be fruitful to examine whether the direction of the effects of different types of regime changes on these outcomes are consistent with their stock market effects, or if investor perceptions are at odds with certain development goals. Such research can help enlarge the body of evidence on the extent to which regime changes cause institutional and political change, and, in turn, have significant consequences for economic development.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to P.M. Aronow, Matthew Graham, Frances Rosenbluth, Hikaru Yamagishi, and four anonymous reviewers for helpful feedback and suggestions. Authors are listed in alphabetic order, implying equal authorship. Replication data and code can be found at https://github.com/dincerti/political-instability. Any and all errors are our own.

Footnotes

1 In the 2013 Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA) World Investment and Political Risk (2013) report (the last report published), executives of multinational enterprises (MNEs) ranked political risk as the second most important constraint for foreign direct investment (FDI) in developing countries over the next three years (after macroeconomic instability). In World Investment and Political Risk (2011) and World Investment and Political Risk (2012), political risk was ranked the most important constraint for FDI in developing countries—even greater than macroeconomic instability. The types of political risk of most concern to investors in developing countries (ranked in order of importance) were 1) adverse regulatory changes, 2) breaches of contract, 3) transfers and convertibility restrictions, 4) civil disturbances, 5) non-honoring of government guarantees, 6) expropriation nationalization, 7) terrorism and 8) war.

2 Aisen and Veiga (Reference Aisen and Veiga2013); Alesina and Perotti (Reference Alesina and Perotti1996); Alesina, Özler, Roubini and Swagel (Reference Alesina, Özler, Roubini and Swagel1996); Baker, Bloom and Davis (Reference Baker, Bloom and Davis2016); Fosu (Reference Fosu1992); Jong-A-Pin (Reference Jong-A-Pin2009); Roe and Siegel (Reference Roe and Siegel2011).

3 Jensen and Schmith (Reference Jensen and Schmith2005); Leblang and Mukherjee (Reference Leblang and Mukherjee2005); Liu and Zhang (Reference Liu and Zhang2015).

4 Svensson (Reference Svensson1998).

5 Devereux and Wen (Reference Devereux and Wen1998).

6 Devereux and Wen (Reference Devereux and Wen1998) propose a model in which political instability causes governments to leave fewer assets to their successors which forces them into increasing capital taxes. The knowledge of future taxation then causes the private sector to reduce current investment which reduces future output.

7 A growing body of work uses event studies to assess political phenomenon. For example, political events have been used to estimate the effect of political connections on firm value (Faccio Reference Faccio2006; Fisman Reference Fisman2001; Goldman, Rocholl and So Reference Goldman, Rocholl and So2009). Studies in “forensic economics” have used bnormal returns from political events to locate or examine transactions such as insider trading (Dube, Kaplan and Naidu Reference Dube, Kaplan and Naidu2011), illegal arms trading (DellaVigna and La Ferrara Reference DellaVigna and La Ferrara2010), and the impact of hostilities on the financial performance of diamond mining firms in Angola (Guidolin and La Ferrara Reference Guidolin and La Ferrara2007).

8 We recognize that this does not represent a full list of historical coups, assassinations, resignations, and public protests, but are restricted to the sample of events for which national-level daily financial data is available.

9 Cohen, Domanski, Fender and Shin (Reference Cohen, Domanski, Fender and Shin2017); Koepke (Reference Koepke2019); Obstfeld (Reference Obstfeld2012).

10 Koepke (Reference Koepke2019).

11 Boutchkova, Doshi, Durnev and Molchanov (Reference Boutchkova, Doshi, Durnev and Molchanov2012); Irshad (Reference Irshad2017); Le and Zak (Reference Le and Zak2006); Lehkonen and Heimonen (Reference Lehkonen and Heimonen2015); Lensink, Hermes and Murinde (Reference Lensink, Hermes and Murinde2000).

12 Derpanopoulos, Frantz, Geddes and Wright (Reference Derpanopoulos, Frantz, Geddes and Wright2016); Powell and Thyne (Reference Powell and Thyne2011); Thyne and Powell (Reference Thyne and Powell2016); Varol (Reference Varol2011).

13 Marinov and Goemans (Reference Marinov and Goemans2014).

15 Barro (Reference Barro1991).

16 Alesina and Perotti (Reference Alesina and Perotti1996); Gupta (Reference Gupta1990); Venieris and Gupta (Reference Venieris and Gupta1986).

17 Note that these studies vary by metrics included in the indices, method of aggregation, and outcome variable of interest.

18 The list of failed assassinations are from Jones and Olken (Reference Jones and Olken2009). Coup attempts are those in category 2 in the CSP Coup d’etat dataset.

19 Chin, Carter and Wright (Reference Chin, Carter and Wright2021).

20 Defined by Center for Systemic Peace as the “occurrence of subversion of the constitutional order by a ruling (usually elected) executive and the imposition of an autocratic regime.”

22 Plausible market indices such as the MSCI World Index and the S&P/IFC Emerging Markets Investable Composite Index only begin in 1976 and 1995, respectively.

23 It is appropriate to use the standard normal distribution to calculate test statistics because the length of the estimation window is sufficiently long (250 trading days).

24 Robustness checks using exponential GARCH, threshold GARCH, FIGARCH, and GARCH(1,1) controlling for structural breaks can be found in Figure A.10, Figure A.11, Figure A.12, and Figure A.13, respectively.

25 Treating this twelve day period as a single day CARs results in a positive abnormal return of 58 percent, a fluctuation that seems qualitatively unreasonable.

26 Based on Center for System Peace Polity IV polity score of 6. Values of 6–10 are defined as democracies.

27 One exception is the assassination of William Mckinley in which the stock market didn’t fully recover for 963 days, or almost 4 calendar years. However, this was likely caused by the Panic of 1901, which began when the stock market crashed on May 17th, 1901, and not by McKinley’s death (although the assassination may have exacerbated the panic).

28 Overholt (Reference Overholt1986); Traywick (Reference Traywick2014).

29 Overholt (Reference Overholt1986).

30 Lee (Reference Lee2009).

31 Villegas (Reference Villegas1987).

32 Indeed, corporate investors in the 2013 MIGA World Investment and Political Risk ranked civil disturbances as the fourth most concerning type of political risk.

33 The set of resignations includes all those listed in either the Coup d’etat Events Handbook or the Archigos Version 4.1 data set with available financial data. In practice, this is the 2011 Egyptian Revolution and the list of resignations in Table 5.

34 These results hold when controlling for emerging market index fluctuations.

35 North and Weingast (Reference North and Weingast1989); Przeworski and Wallerstein (Reference Przeworski and Wallerstein1982); Svensson (Reference Svensson1998).

36 As defined by the Polity project.

37 Based on matching our cases with codings from The Ideology of Heads of Government (HOG) database, as well as surveys of news reports on the day of each event. In all cases, no clear economic ideological shift can be identified.

38 Greater political risk is associated with higher within-country financial volatility. As our synthetic control portfolio contains data from countries at both high and low levels of general political risk, some countries in the synthetic control reference market have higher levels of baseline financial volatility than an event country, while others have lower levels of baseline volatility. Note, however, that this does not impact the main event study estimates, as the relevant comparison is the financial returns on the event day and within-country financial volatility in the period preceding the event.

39 See “Synthetic Control Portfolio” in the Appendix for mathematical formalization.

40 See section 8 in MacKinlay (Reference MacKinlay1997) for more details.

41 The Wilcoxon rank test is a non-parametric statistical technique that can be used to compare differences between matched samples.

42 Chin, Carter and Wright (Reference Chin, Carter and Wright2021).

43 The Turkish coup attempt led to negative event-day CARs of approximately −7 percent. See Figure A2 for a visual depiction.

44 Girardi and Bowles (Reference Girardi and Bowles2018).

References

Abadie, Alberto, Diamond, Alexis, and Hainmueller, Jens. 2010. “Synthetic Control Methods for Comparative Case Studies: Estimating the Effect of Californias Tobacco Control Program.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 105 (490): 493505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abadie, Alberto, and Gardeazabal, Javier. 2003. “The Economic Costs of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country.” American Economic Review 93 (1): 113132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aisen, Ari, and Veiga, Francisco José. 2013. “How Does Political Instability Affect Economic Growth?European Journal of Political Economy 29: 151167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., and Perotti, R.. 1996. “Income Distribution, Political Instability, and Investment.” European Economic Review 40 (6): 12031228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., Özler, S., Roubini, N., and Swagel, P.. 1996. “Political Instability and Economic Growth.” Journal of Economic Growth 1 (2): 189211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, Scott R., Bloom, Nicholas, and Davis, Steven J.. 2016. “Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 (4): 15931636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, Robert J. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2): 407443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boutchkova, Maria, Doshi, Hitesh, Durnev, Art, and Molchanov, Alexander. 2012. “Precarious Politics and Return Volatility.” The Review of Financial Studies 25 (4): 11111154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. Y., Lo, A. W., and MacKinlay, A. C.. 1997. The Econometrics of Financial Markets. Vol. 1. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chin, John J., Carter, David B., and Wright, Joseph G.. 2021. “The Varieties of Coups D’etat: Introducing the Colpus Dataset.” International Studies Quarterly 65 (4):10401051.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, Benjamin H., Domanski, Dietrich, Fender, Ingo, and Shin, Hyun Song. 2017. “Global liquidity: A Selective Review.” Annual Review of Economics 9: 587612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DellaVigna, S., and La Ferrara, D. E.. 2010. “Detecting Illegal Arms Trade.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 2 (4): 2657.Google Scholar
Derpanopoulos, G., Frantz, E., Geddes, B., and Wright, J.. 2016. “Are Coups Good for Democracy.” Research and Politics 3 (1): 17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Devereux, M. B., and Wen, J. F.. 1998. “Political Instability, Capital Taxation, and Growth.” European Economic Review 42 (9): 16351651.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dube, A., Kaplan, E., and Naidu, S.. 2011. “Coups, Corporations, and Classified Information.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (3): 13751409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faccio, M. 2006. “Politically Connected Firms.” The American Economic Review 96 (1): 369386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, Eugene F. 1965. “The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices.” The Journal of Business 38 (1): 34105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R. 2001. “Estimating the Value of Political Connections.” The American Economic Review 91 (4): 10951102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fosu, Augustin Kwasi. 1992. “Political Instability and Economic Growth: Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 40 (4): 829841.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Girardi, Daniele, and Bowles, Samuel. 2018. “Institution Shocks And Economic Outcomes: Allende’s Election, Pinochet’s Coup and the Santiago Stock Market.” Journal of Development Economics 134: 1627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldman, E., Rocholl, J., and So, J.. 2009. “Do Politically Connected Boards Affect Firm Value?Review of Financial Studies 22 (6): 23312360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guidolin, M., and La Ferrara, E.. 2007. “Diamonds Are Forever, Wars Are Not: Is Conflict Bad for Private Firms?The American Economic Review 97 (5): 19781993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, Dipak K. 1990. The Economics of Political Violence: The Effect of Political Instability on Economic Growth. Santa Barbara, CA: Praeger.Google Scholar
Irshad, Hira. 2017. “Relationship Among Political Instability, Stock Market Returns and Stock Market Volatility.” Studies in Business and Economics 12 (2): 7099.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Nathan M., and Schmith, Scott. 2005. “Market Responses to Politics The Rise of Lula and the Decline of the Brazilian Stock Market.” Comparative Political Studies 38 (10): 12451270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, B. F., and Olken, B. A.. 2009. “Hit or Miss? The Effect of Assassinations on Institutions and War.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (2): 5587.Google Scholar
Jong-A-Pin, Richard. 2009. “On the Measurement of Political Instability and Its Impact on Economic Growth.” European Journal of Political Economy 25 (1): 1529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koepke, Robin. 2019. “What Drives Capital Flows to Emerging Markets? A Survey of the Empirical Literature.” Journal of Economic Surveys 33 (2): 516540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le, Quan Vu, and Zak, Paul J.. 2006. “Political Risk and Capital Flight.” Journal of International Money and Finance 25 (2): 308329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leblang, David, and Mukherjee, Bumba. 2005. “Government Partisanship, Elections, and the Stock Market: Examining American and British Stock Returns, 1930–2000.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (4): 780802.Google Scholar
Lee, Terence. 2009. “The Armed Forces and Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Explaining the Role of the Military in 1986 Philippines and 1998 Indonesia.” Comparative Political Studies 42 (5): 640669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lehkonen, Heikki, and Heimonen, Kari. 2015. “Democracy, Political Risks and Stock Market Performance.” Journal of International Money and Finance 59: 7799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lensink, Robert, Hermes, Niels, and Murinde, Victor. 2000. “Capital Flight and Political Risk.” Journal of international Money and Finance 19 (1): 7392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, Li, and Zhang, Tao. 2015. “Economic Policy Uncertainty and Stock Market Volatility.” Finance Research Letters 15: 99105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Londregan, J. B., and Poole, K. T.. 1990. “Poverty, the Coup Trap, and the Seizure of Executive Power.” World Politics 42 (02): 151183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKinlay, A. C. 1997. “Event Studies in Economics and Finance.” Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1): 1339.Google Scholar
Marinov, Nikolay, and Goemans, Hein. 2014. “Coups and Democracy.” British Journal of Political Science 44 (4): 799825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyersson, Erik. 2016. “Political Man on Horseback: Coups and Development.” Stockholm Institute for Transition Economics (SITE) 5: 127.Google Scholar
Needler, M. C. 1966. “Political Development and Military Intervention in Latin America.” The American Political Science Review 60 (3): 616626.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” The Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 803832.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice. 2012. “Financial Flows, Financial Crises, and Global Imbalances.” Journal of International Money and Finance 31 (3): 469480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Overholt, William H. 1986. “The Rise and Fall of Ferdinand Marcos.” Asian Survey 26 (11): 11371163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Jonathan M., and Thyne, Clayton L.. 2011. “Global Instances of Coups from 1950 to 2010: A New Dataset.” Journal of Peace Research 48 (2): 249259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, and Wallerstein, Michael. 1982. “The Structure of Class Conflict in Democratic Capitalist Societies.” American Political Science Review 76 (2): 215238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roe, M. J., and Siegel, J. I.. 2011. “Political Instability: Effects on Financial Development, Roots in the Severity of Economic Inequality.” Journal of Comparative Economics 39 (3), 279309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1965. “Proof That Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly.” Industrial Management Review 6: 4150.Google Scholar
Svensson, J. 1998. “Investment, Property Rights and Political Instability: Theory and Evidence.” European Economic Review 42 (7): 13171341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thyne, Clayton L., and Powell, Jonathan M.. 2016. “Coup d?état or Coup d’Autocracy? How Coups Impact Democratization, 1950–2008.” Foreign Policy Analysis 12 (2): 192213.Google Scholar
Traywick, Catherine. 2014. “Shoes, Jewels, and Monets: The Immense Ill-Gotten Wealth of Imelda Marcos.” Foreign Policy. https://foreignpolicy.com/2014/01/16/shoes-jewels-and-monets-the-immense-ill-gotten-wealth-of-imelda-marcos/ Google Scholar
Varol, Ozan O. 2011. “The Democratic Coup d'état.” Harvard Journal of International Law 53 (2): 291356.Google Scholar
Venieris, Yiannis P., and Gupta, Dipak K.. 1986. “Income Distribution and Sociopolitical Instability as Determinants of Savings: A Cross-Sectional Model.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (4): 873883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Villegas, Bernardo M. 1987. “The Philippines in 1986: Democratic Reconstruction in the Post-Marcos Era.” Asian Survey 27 (2): 194205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank Group Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency. 2011. World Investment and Political Risk 2011. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.Google Scholar
World Bank Group Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency. 2012. World Investment and Political Risk 2012. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.Google Scholar
World Bank Group Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency. 2013. World Investment and Political Risk 2013. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. List of stock indices

Figure 1

Table 2. Regime changes

Figure 2

Figure 1. Absolute value of daily returns.

Figure 3

Figure 2. Mean of volatility estimates from GARCH(1,1) models.

Figure 4

Table 3. Abnormal returns following coups

Figure 5

Table 4. Abnormal returns following assassinations

Figure 6

Table 5. Abnormal returns following resignations

Figure 7

Table 6. Abnormal returns following authoritarian regime changes

Figure 8

Table 7. Abnormal returns following democratic regime changes

Figure 9

Figure 3. Abnormal returns surrounding the 2002 Venezuelan coup attempt.

Figure 10

Figure 4. Mean cumulative abnormal returns by type of regime change.

Figure 11

Table 8. Non-parametric tests of the impact of regime changes