Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T06:48:24.352Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Underground Wealth of Nations: On the Capitalist Origins of Silver Mining, A.D. 1150–1450. By Jeannette Graulau. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2019. xvi + 373 pp. Illustrations, tables, appendixes, notes, bibliography, index. Hardcover, $85.00. ISBN: 978-0-300-21822-0.

Review products

The Underground Wealth of Nations: On the Capitalist Origins of Silver Mining, A.D. 1150–1450. By Jeannette Graulau. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2019. xvi + 373 pp. Illustrations, tables, appendixes, notes, bibliography, index. Hardcover, $85.00. ISBN: 978-0-300-21822-0.

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 January 2022

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Book Reviews
Copyright
Copyright © The President and Fellows of Harvard College 2022

Economic historians have long recognized Europe's early modern bullion crisis as the origin of capitalist mining corporations to supply the treasuries of nascent states. Yet, as Jeannette Graulau contends in The Underground Wealth of Nations, the proliferation of the term argentifodina (silver mine) in twelfth-century legal documents signals the appearance of capitalist silver mining much earlier. In tracing how “capital digged, usurped, and claimed the bowels of the earth in search of metallic wealth,” Graulau's ambitious book seeks to “build an economic theory of mining” decoupled from the history of minting and challenges Marxist theories to demonstrate another avenue of medieval capitalist development (pp. xii, xiv).

The book opens persuasively with a consideration of the geological (chapter 1) and geographical (chapter 2) preconditions for the rise of capitalist mining before turning to case studies of medieval mining corporations (chapters 3 and 4). This Braudelian organization highlights time and space as the structure for groups—feudal lords and capitalists—to enact a “radical separation of mining profits from the landowner . . . to shareholding mining corporations” (p. 223). Graulau argues that good geology was not enough to turn ore into the underground wealth of nations—a play on Adam Smith's seminal The Wealth of Nations. Capitalist mining succeeded where alpine geography set “the laws of motion” to attract capital: riparian connections to major markets, trade routes, and other mining regions; proximity to agricultural resources and timber to support burgeoning mining towns; and fewer disruptions from political and environmental calamities (p. 9). Here, capital-starved landlords and local rulers were receptive to offers from highly mobile groups of skilled miners, experts, and merchant-financiers to lease mineral rights and grant civic privileges in exchange for rents and royalties. Therefore, a core region of capitalist development arose in the Alps, Carpathians, Tuscan Apennines, and Sardinia. The colonization of these mining regions by German, Flemish, Italian, and other free and semi-free miners resulted in uniform corporate practices across the Latin West, including shareholder and administrative structure, methods of extraction and smelting, and accounting. The legal instruments devised to define and regulate mining corporations, Graulau asserts, granted them an unprecedented level of autonomy from lords and ecclesiastical authorities and ruptured the feudal lord-serf relationship long before the agrarian wage laborer did. This incipient bourgeoisie eventually monopolized the mining economy, alienating laborers from the fruits of their efforts and divesting feudal lords of the profits from their lands.

By contrast, relative geographical isolation, instability caused by droughts, floods, famine, disease, or war, and “ferocious” lords who refused to relinquish mineral rights to private interests condemned other mineralogically rich regions to feudal mining practices (p. 180). According to Graulau, conditions were not as amenable to capital in the Ottoman Balkans, England, Andalusia, Liao and Mongol China, Languedoc, and Japan. The Ottoman's centralizing impulse deprived Balkan silver mines of the legal autonomy necessary for capitalist corporations to take root; in Devonshire, England, the Crown's regalian rights and distance from major trade routes and entrepots inhibited capitalist growth; the reconquista's violence halted corporate development in Andalusia; and in China, dependence upon forced labor prevented the shift from feudal to accumulation mode. In this quest to explain the feudal mode's persistence in the East (chapters 5 and 6), the book goes astray.

Graulau admits that biased sources and a paucity of archaeological evidence make assessing mining development outside the Latin West fraught and inconclusive, a limitation that makes these glimpses of non-European mining operations unconvincing. The devotion of so much space to the East/West question is perplexing. This reader would have preferred Graulau to “plow back into the subsoil” of the case studies to flesh out the negotiations and contingencies of interactions among lords, mining corporations, local officials, and laborers over a long span of silver mining booms and busts (p. 204). How did metalworking guilds, mints, and other corporate entities that relied on the products of silver mining impinge on this capitalist development? How did theories of metallogenesis and humanity's relationship to nature shape debates about the pursuit of underground wealth (are metals God's gifts or Satan's temptations), for what purposes, and to what extent, all of which influenced economic thinking and behavior? How did participation in religious devotions and support from ecclesiastical authorities assist the development of capitalist mining and validate it as providential, as Graulau tantalizingly teases in the conclusion?

Business historians and economists will appreciate Graulau's explanation of the costs associated with industrial mining (especially fuel and drainage), the processes and technologies for extracting and smelting silver ores, the geographical distribution of European mines, and attention to the corporate structure and the parallel bureaucracy to regulate them, all helpfully visualized in charts. Yet as neither an economist nor a medievalist, this reader often felt excluded by inconsistent translations of foreign phrases and unelaborated references to other scholars. A discussion of how feudal lords and mining capitalists regarded risk and uncertainty and the specific contexts in which landlords made decisions to lease their mineral rights to private investors would elucidate why the joint-stock company found fertile ground to grow in central Europe when and where it did. Additionally, more attention to shareholder composition—urban and rural aristocrats, merchant-financiers, and miner elites—would have mitigated the reductive dichotomy of regressive feudal lords in conflict with progressive capitalist mining corporations and recognized individual agency. Economists and economic historians might forgive the lack of synchronic specificity and undefined abstractions like “feudalism” and “capitalism” as tolerable omissions in a pioneering work, but it makes the book more teleological than transtemporal and therefore less helpful to graduate students and nonspecialist historians. This slip into Marc Bloch's “idol of origins” is regrettable, as historians should take Graulau's assertion of a medieval capitalist silver mining seriously. At the very least, the first four chapters ought to serve as a preliminary survey for other scholars to mine and refine.